Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T21:24:00.314Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The future of evolutionary economics is in a vision from the past

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 August 2014

J. W. STOELHORST*
Affiliation:
Amsterdam Business School, University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam, Netherlands

Abstract

This essay comments on discussions of the future of evolutionary economics by Winter (2014) and Witt (2014). I agree with their assessment of evolutionary economics as a theoretically fragmented field that has had little success in effecting a paradigm shift in mainstream economics. However, I question if such a paradigm shift should be the primary goal of evolutionary economists. I argue that evolutionary economists could increase their impact if they would be willing and able to recast themselves as evolutionary social scientists. This was the vision for economics that Veblen held out more than a century ago. I lay out the theoretical building blocks for realizing this vision available today.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aldrich, H. E., Hodgson, G. M., Hull, D. L., Knudsen, T., Mokyr, J., and Vanberg, V. (2008), ‘In Defence of Generalized Darwinism’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 18: 577596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Barkow, J. H., Cosmides, L., and Tooby, J. (1992), The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2011), A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Boyd, R. and Richerson, P. J. (1985), Culture and the Evolutionary Process, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, D. T. (1960), ‘Blind Variation and Selective Retention in Creative Thought as in Other Knowledge Processes’, Psychological Review, 67: 380400.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Campbell, D. T. (1994), ‘How Individual and Face-to-Face Group Selection Undermine Firm Selection in Organizational Evolution’, in Baum, J. A. and Singh, J. V. (eds.), Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 2338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R. and March, J. G. ([1963] 1992), A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (2nd edn.), Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Dennett, D. C. (1995), Darwin's Dangerous Idea: Evolution and the Meanings of Life, London: Allen Lane.Google Scholar
Dolfsma, W. and Leydesdorff, L. (2010), ‘The Citation Field of Evolutionary Economics’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20: 645664.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dopfer, K. and Potts, J. (2004), ‘Evolutionary Realism: A New Ontology for Economics’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 11: 195212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dosi, G. (1982), ‘Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories’, Research Policy, 11 (3): 147160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, A. J. (2007), ‘Beyond Foraging: Behavioral Science and The Future of Institutional Economics’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 3: 265291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanusch, H. and Pyka, A. (2007), Elgar Companion to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2001), ‘On the Ontological Foundations of Evolutionary Economics’, in Dopfer, K. (ed.), Evolutionary Economics, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 89139.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2002), ‘Darwinism in Economics: From Analogy to Ontology’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12: 259281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2004), The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2013), From Pleasure Machines to Moral Communities: An Evolutionary Economics Without Homo Economicus, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. and Knudsen, T. (2006), ‘Why we Need a Generalized Darwinism and why a Generalized Darwinism is Not Enough’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 61: 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. and Knudsen, T. (2010), Darwin's Conjecture: The Search for General Principles of Social and Economic Evolution, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M., Järvinen, J., and Lamberg, J.-A. (2013), ‘The Structure and Evolution of Evolutionary Research: A Bibliometric Analysis of the “Evolutionary” Literature in Management, Economics and Sociology’, Paper presented at the 25th Annual EAEPE Conference, Paris, 7–9 November.Google Scholar
Levit, G., Hossfeld, U., and Witt, U. (2011), ‘Can Darwinism be “Generalized” and of what use Would this be?’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 21: 545562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. and Szathmary, E. (1997), The Major Transitions in Evolution, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayr, E. (1961), ‘Cause and Effect in Biology’, Science, 134: 15011506.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nelson, R. R. (1995), ‘Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change’, Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 4890.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press (Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Penrose, E. T. (1952), ‘Biological Analogies in the Theory of the Firm’, American Economic Review, 42: 804819.Google Scholar
Penrose, E. T. ([1959] 1995), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, 3rd edn., Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plotkin, H. C. (1994), Darwin Machines and the Nature of Knowledge, Harmondsworth: Penguin.Google Scholar
Richerson, P. J. and Boyd, R. (2005), Not by Genes Alone: How Culture Transformed Human Evolution, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Robbins, L. (1932), An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Rutherford, M. H. (1998), ‘Veblen's Evolutionary Programme: A Promise Unfulfilled’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 22: 463–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Silva, S. T. and Texeira, A. A. C. (2009), ‘On the Divergence of Evolutionary Research Paths in the past 50 Years: A Comprehensive Bibliometric Account’, Journal of Evolutionary Research, 19: 605642.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1957), Models of Man: Social and Rational. Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Sober, E. and Wilson, D. S. (1998), Unto others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. (2005), ‘The Naturalist Perspective on Universal Darwinism: An Application to the Evolutionary Theory of the Firm’, in Finch, J. and Orillard, M. (eds.), Complexity and the Economy: Implications for Economic Policy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 127147.Google Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. (2008a), ‘The Explanatory Logic and Ontological Commitments of Generalized Darwinism’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 15: 343363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. (2008b), ‘Generalized Darwinism from the Bottom up: An Evolutionary View of Socio-Economic Behavior and Organization’, in Elsner, W. and Hanappi, H. (eds.), Advances in Evolutionary Institutional Economics: Evolutionary Modules, Non-Knowledge, and Strategy, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 3558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. (2014), ‘Economic Growth as a Darwinian Process’ [unpublished manuscript].Google Scholar
Stoelhorst, J. W. and Richerson, P. J. (2013), ‘A Naturalistic Theory of Economic Organization’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 90: S45S56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinbergen, N. (1963), ‘On Aims and Methods in Ethology’, Zeitschrift für Tierpsychologie, 20: 410433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. (1898), ‘Why is Economics not an Evolutionary Science?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12: 373–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Vromen, J. J. (2004), ‘Conjectural Revisionary Economic Ontology: Outline of an Ambitious Research Agenda for Evolutionary Economics’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 11: 213247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, D. S. and Gowdy, J. (2013), ‘Evolution as a General Theoretical Framework for Economics and Public Policy’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 90: S3S10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, E. O. (1978), On Human Nature, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google ScholarPubMed
Winter, S. G. (2014), ‘The Future of Evolutionary Economics: Can we Break out of the Beachhead?’, Journal of Institutional Economics (published online), doi: 10.1017/S1744137414000277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, U. (2003), The Evolving Economy: Essays on the Evolutionary Approach to Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, U. (2004), ‘On the Proper Interpretation of “Evolution” in Economics and its Implications for Production Theory’, Journal of Economic Methodology, 11: 125146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, U. (2008), ‘What is Specific About Evolutionary Economics?’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 18: 547575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, U. (2014), ‘The Future of Evolutionary Economics: Why the Modalities of Explanations Matter’, Journal of Institutional Economics (published online), doi: 10.1017/S1744137414000253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar