Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T09:00:51.578Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The division of labor in the firm: Agency, near-decomposability and the Babbage principle

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2007

ANDREAS REINSTALLER*
Affiliation:
Austrian Institute of Economic Research
*
*Correspondence to: Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), POB 91, 1103 Vienna, Austria. Email: [email protected].

Abstract:

This paper devises a simulation model that combines insights from the evolutionary perspective on the division of labor with ideas from the labor process literature. It characterizes technical change and the development of a near-decomposable production process as the outcome of technological search and of organizational problem solving, where the conflict between workers and firms over the organization of work plays a central role. It is argued that a near-decomposable organization of the production process also allows management to tighten its control over workers. Consequently, more extensive divisions of labor within a firm develop where the power of workers to oppose decisions by the management is low. In these scenarios the performance of firms is also highest. The model is used to interpret historical evidence about different development paths in technical change in the UK and the US at the beginning of the twentieth century.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

This paper has enormously benefited from discussions with Bulat Sanditov and Koen Frenken. Mike Dietrich, Werner Hölzl and the three referees of this journal also provided a number of comments that helped improve the quality of this paper.

References

Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. (1972), ‘Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization’, American Economic Review, 62: 772795.Google Scholar
Altenberg, L. (1995), ‘Genome Growth and the Evolution of the Genotype-Phenotype Map’, in Banzhaf, W. and Eckman, F. H. (eds), Evolution and Biocomputation, Berlin & Heidelberg, Springer-Verlag, pp. 205259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, E. and Rosenberg, N. (1968), ‘The Enfield Arsenal in Theory and History’, Economic Journal, 78: 827842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. B. (1993), ‘On Designing economic Agents that Behave like Human Agents’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3: 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beniger, J. R. (1986), The Control Revolution, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bhimani, A. (1994), ‘Accounting and the Emergence of Economic Man’, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 19: 637674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. (1985), ‘The Production process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models’, American Economic Review, 75: 1636.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and H. Gintis (1993), ‘The Revenge of Homo Economicus: Contested Exchange and the Revival of Political Economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7: 83102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braverman, H. (1974), Labor and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century, Monthly Review Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandler, A. D. (1962), Strategy and Structure, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Clawson, D. (1980), Bureaucracy and the Labor Process: The Transformation of US Industry, 18601920, New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Coombs, R. (1978), ‘Labour and Monopoly Capital’, New Left Review, I/107: 7996.Google Scholar
David, P. A. (1975), Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elbaum, B. and W. H. Lazonick (1984), ‘The Decline of the British Economy: An Institutional Perspective’, Journal of Economic History, 44: 567583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frenken, K., Marengo, L. and Valente, M. (1999), ‘Interdependencies, Near-Decomposability and Adaption’, in Brenner, T. (ed.), Computational Techniques for Modelling Learning in Economics, Boston: Kluwer, pp. 145165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, H. (1976), ‘The Nature of the Labor Exchange and the Theory of Capitalist Production’, Review of Radical Political Economics, 8: 3654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopper, T. and Armstrong, P. (1991), ‘Cost Accounting, Controlling, Labour and the Rise of Conglomerates’, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 16: 405438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H., (1992), ‘Specific and General Knowledge, and Organizational Structure’, in Werin, L. and Wijkander, H. (eds), Contract Economics, Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 251274.Google Scholar
Kauffman, S. A. (1993), The Origins of Order, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, R. (2002), ‘Modularity in Technology and Organization’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 49: 1937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, W. H. (1981), ‘Production Relations, Labor Productivity, and choice of Technique: British and US Cotton Spinning’, Journal of Economic History, 41: 491516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, W. H. (1983), ‘Industrial Organization and Technological Change: The Decline of the British Cotton Industry’, Business History Review, 57: 195236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, W. H. (1990), Competitive Advantage on the Shop Floor, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lazonick, W. H. and Brush, T. (1985), ‘The “Horndahl Effect” in Early US Manufacturing’, Explorations in Economic History, 22: 5396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, W. H. and O'Sullivan, M. (1997), ‘Big Business and Skill Formation in the Wealthiest Nations: The Organizational Revolution in the Twentieth Century’, in Chandler, A. D., Amatori, F., and Takashi, H. (eds), Big Business and the Wealth of Nations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 497521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levenstein, M. (1991), ‘The Use of Cost Measures: The Dow Chemical Company 1890–1914’, in Temin, P. (ed.), Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the Use of information, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 71112.Google Scholar
Litterer, J. A. (1963), ‘Systematic Management: Design for Organizational Recoupling in American Manufacturing Firms’, Business History Review, 37: 369391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marengo, L., Dosi, G., Legrenzi, P. and Pasquali, C. (2000), ‘The Structure of Problem Solving and the Structure of Organizations’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9: 757788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marengo, L. and G. Dosi (2005), ‘Division of Labor, Organizational Coordination and Market Mechanisms in Collective Problem-Solving’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 58: 303326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marglin, S. (1974), ‘What do Bosses do? The Origins and Function of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production’, Review of Radical Political Economy, 6: 60112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, D. (1987), The Fall of the House of Labor, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, P. and O'Leary, T. (1987), ‘Accounting and the Construction of the Governable Person’, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 12: 235265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Boston: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Noble, D. F. (1977), America by Design, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Olmstead, A. L. and Rhode, P. (1993), ‘Induced Innovation in American Agriculture: A Reconsideration’, Journal of Political Economy, 101: 100118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinstaller, A. and Hölzl, W. (2004), ‘Complementarity Constraints and Induced Innovation: Some Evidence from the First IT Regime’, in Foster, J. and Hölzl, W. (eds), Applied Evolutionary Economics and Complex Systems, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 133–54.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, N. (1965), ‘Adam Smith on the Division of Labor: Two Views or One?’, Economica, 32: 127139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, N. (1994), ‘Babbage: Pioneer Economist’, in Rosenberg, N., Exploring the Black Box, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saviotti, P. and Metcalfe, J. S. (1984), ‘A Theoretical Approach to the Construction of Technological Output Indicators’, Research Policy, 13: 141151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. and Ando, A. (1961), ‘Aggregation of Variables in Dynamic Systems’, Econometrica, 29, 111138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. (1996), ‘The Architecture of Complexity’, in Simon, H., The Sciences of the Artificial, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 183216.Google Scholar
Simon, H. (2002), ‘Near Decomposability and the Speed of Evolution’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 11: 587599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, G. P. and Altenberg, L. (1996), ‘Perspective: Complex Adaptations and the Evolution of Evolvability’, Evolution, 50: 967976.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yates, J. (1989), Control through Communication: The Rise of System in American Management, Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar