Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T17:39:41.209Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Assessing the potential of new institutional economics to explain institutional change: the case of road management liberalization in the Nordic countries

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 April 2008

JOHN GROENEWEGEN*
Affiliation:
Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands
MARTIN DE JONG*
Affiliation:
Delft University of Technology, The Netherlands
*
Correspondence to: Delft University of Technology, Postbus 5, 2600 AA Delft, The Netherlands. Email: [email protected]
Correspondence to: Delft University of Technology, Postbus 5, 2600 AA Delft, The Netherlands. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

Like other network industries, construction and maintenance of transport infrastructure have also seen a recent trend towards liberalization, deregulation, re-regulation, and sometimes privatization. With respect to institutional arrangements, this change implies that previously vertically integrated state-owned enterprises have been replaced by ‘more market’, meaning private ownership and contracts together with regulation by an independent government agency. When economists discuss institutions, this is preferably done in terms of efficiency and equilibrium. We discuss Williamson's Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) and Aoki's Comparative Institutional Analysis (CIA) as being two representative approaches of New Institutional Economics in which efficiency and equilibrium are central. What is the applicability of these two approaches to explain institutional change? The case of road management in Nordic countries provides the empirical evidence. We will draw conclusions as to the strengths and weaknesses of the two approaches and add suggestions to complement the efficiency approach, which allow for a more detailed level of analysis, in which also issues of political power are included.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Angervuori, T. (2005), ‘Road maintenance organizing in Finland’, Report on the Visit from the Iceland Representative, Helsinki.Google Scholar
Angervuori, T. and Altamirano, M. A. (2006), ‘Case study interview with the Maintenance Procurement Director Uusimaa Region (Helsinki)’, in M. A. Altamirano, ‘Cross-national benchmark of road infrastructures: performance indicators and innovative contract arrangements’, draft dissertation Delft University of Technology.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2000), Information, Corporate Governance and Institutional Diversity: Competitiveness in Japan, the USA and the Transitional Economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. (2001), Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. (2007), ‘Endogenizing institutions and institutional changes’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 3 (1): 131.Google Scholar
Campbell, J., Hollingsworth, J. R., and Lindberg, L. (eds) (1991), The Governance of the American Economy, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Denzau, A. T. and North, D. C. (1994), ‘Shared mental models: ideologies and institutions’, Kyklos, 47: 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiori, S. (2002), ‘Alternative visions of change in Douglass North's new institutionalism’, Journal of Economic Issues, 32 (4): 10251044.Google Scholar
Fligstein, N. (2001), The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First Century Capitalist Societies, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R. and Suddaby, R. (2006), ‘Institutional entrepreneurship in mature fields: the big five accounting firms’, Academy of Management Review, 49 (1): 2748.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, J., Kerstholt, F., and Nagelkerke, A. (1995) ‘On integrating new and old institutionalism: Douglass North building bridges’, Journal of Economic Issues, 29 (2): 467475.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, J. and Vromen, J. (1997), ‘Theory of the firm revisited: new and neo-institutional perspectives’, in Magnusson, Lars and Ottoson, Jan (eds), Economics and Path Dependency, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, pp. 3357.Google Scholar
Hall, P. (1993), Governing the Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1998), ‘The approach of institutional economics’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36 (1): 166192.Google Scholar
Jacoby, W. (2000), Imitation and Politics: Redesiging Modern Germany, Ithaca/London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
de Jong, M. (2002), ‘Surpassing the Swedish model of road management liberalization? Finland's use of patience and selectivity in adopting foreign models’, in de Jong, M., Lalenis, K., and Mamadouh, V., The Theory and Practice of Institutional Transplantation: Experiences with the Transfer of Policy Institutions, Dordrecht/London/Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Jong, M. de (2003), ‘Wegenonderhoud in Zweden en Finland’, in Heuvelhof, E. ten, de Jong, M., Kuit, M., and Stout, H. (eds), Infrastratego, Strategisch gedrag in infrastructuurgebonden nutssectoren, in Dutch, Utrecht: Lemma.Google Scholar
Masten, S. (1996), ‘Empirical research in transaction cost economics: challenges, progress, directions’, in Groenewegen, J. (ed.), Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond, Boston/London/Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic, pp. 4365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meseguer, C. (2004), ‘What role for learning? The diffusion of privatization in industrial and Latin American countries’, Journal of Public Policy, 24 (3): 499523.Google Scholar
Meseguer, C. (2006), ‘Rational learning and bounded learning in the diffusion of policy innovation’, Rationality and Society, 18 (1): 3566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (2005), Understanding the Process of Institutional Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pakkala, P. (2002), Innovative Project Delivery Methods for Infrastructure: An International Perspective, Helsinki: Finnish Road Enterprise.Google Scholar
Pakkala, P., de Jong, M., and Aijo, J. (2007), International overview of innovative contracting practices for roads, Helsinki: NGI-Foundation/Ramboll Finland/TU-Delft.Google Scholar
Richter, R. (2005), ‘The new institutional economics, its start, its meaning, its prospects’, The European Business Organization Law Review, 6: 161200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sabatier, P. A. and Jenkins Smith, H. C. (1993), Policy Change and Learning: An Advocacy Coalition Approach, New York: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Seo, M. and Creed, D. (2002), ‘Institutional contradictions, praxis, and institutional change: a dialectical perspective’, Academy of Management Review, 27 (2): 222247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Westney, D. E. (1987), Imitation and Innovation: The Transfer of Western Organizational Patterns in Meiji-Japan, London/Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1991), ‘Strategizing, economizing, and economic organization’, Strategic Management Journal, 12: 7594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1998), ‘Transaction cost economics: how it works: where it is headed’, Economist, 146 (1): 2358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 595613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zouboulakis, M. (2005) On the evolutionary character of North's idea of institutional change, Journal of Institutional Economics, 1: 139153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar