Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T10:25:37.443Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Induced Theory of the Firm Under Risk: The Pure Mutual Fund

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2009

Extract

In two previous articles [11] and [12] a family of normative models of the individual's economic decision problem under risk was presented. At the same time, certain implications of these models with respect to individual behavior were deduced for a class of utility functions. This paper will show that these models also give rise to an induced theory of the formation and operation of firms under risk for the same class of utility functions.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1970

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1.Arrow, Kenneth, Aspects of the Theory of Bisk Bearing, Helsinki: Yrjö Jahnssonin Säätiö, 1965.Google Scholar
2.Bellman, Richard, Dynamic Programming, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957.Google ScholarPubMed
3.Bernoulli, Daniel, “Exposition of a New Theory in the Measurement of Risk,” transl. by Sommer, Louise, Econometrica, January 1954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
4.Breiman, Leo, “Investment Policies for Expanding Businesses Optimal in a Long-Run Sense,” Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, December 1960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
5.Breiman, Leo, “Optimal Gambling Systems for Favorable Games,” Fourth Berkeley Symposium on Probability and Mathematical Statistics, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1961.Google Scholar
6.Brown, George, unpublished notes, 1964.Google Scholar
7.Farrell, M. J., “The New Theories of the Consumption Function,” Economic Journal, December 1959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
8.Fisher, Irving, The Theory of Interest, New York: Macmillan, 1930.Google Scholar
9.Friedman, Milton, A Theory of the Consumption Function, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
10.Hakansson, Nils, “Optimal Investment and Consumption Strategies for a Class of Utility Functions” (Ph.D. Diss., University of California at Los Angeles, 1966); also, Working Paper No. 101, Western Management Science Institute, University of California at Los Angeles, June 1966.Google Scholar
11.Breiman, Leo, “Optimal Investment and Consumption Strategies Under Risk for a Class of Utility Functions,” Econometrica (forthcoming).Google Scholar
12.Breiman, Leo, “Optimal Investment and Consumption Strategies Under Risk, An Uncertain Lifetime, and Insurance,” International Economic Review, October 1969.Google Scholar
13.Hayes, Douglas, Investments: Analysis and Management, New York: Macmillan, 1961.Google Scholar
14.Latané, Henry, “Criteria for Choice Among Risky Ventures,” Journal of Political Economy, April 1959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
15.Modigliani, Franco, and Brumberg, R., “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data,” Post-Keynesian Economics, ed. Kurihara, K., New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press, 1954.Google Scholar
16.Modigliani, Franco, and Miller, Merton, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, June 1958.Google Scholar
17.Phelps, Edmund, “The Accumulation of Risky Capital: A Sequential Utility Analysis,” Econometrica, October 1962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18.Pratt, John, “Risk-Aversion in the Small and in the Large,” Econometrica, January-April 1964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19.Savage, Leonard, The Foundations of Statistics, New York: John Wiley, 1954.Google Scholar
20.von Bohm-Bawerk, Eugene, Positive Theory of Capital, transl. by Smart, William, New York: G. E. Stechert, 1923.Google Scholar
21.Von Neumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar, Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1947.Google Scholar