Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T22:59:14.175Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Economic Model of Trade Credit

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2009

Extract

In considering trade credit, we need to ask three questions:

1. Why do nonfinancial firms commonly participate in the process of financial intermediation by extending credit to their customers?

2. What explains differences in credit periods between firms and industries as well as over time for specific firms and industries?

3. How do changing monetary conditions affect the credit that firms extend to their customers?

To answer these questions, we first identify two reasons for credit sales: the first we might call a financing motive, and the second a transactions motive. The transactions motive can readily be understood—it costs something to match the time pattern of payment for goods with the time pattern of receipt of goods. Buyers benefit if bills are allowed to accumulate for periodic payment. Furthermore, trade credit gives buyers time to plan for the payment of unexpected purchases, enables them to forecast future cash outlays with greater certainty, and simplifies their cash management. To the extent that buyers benefit, sellers have an opportunity to sell credit. It is likely that, to a large extent, the aggregate stock of trade credit is explained by the transactions motive.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © School of Business Administration, University of Washington 1974

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1]Beranek, William. Analysis for Financial Decisions. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, 1963.Google Scholar
[2]Brechling, F., and Lipsey, R.. “Trade Credit and Monetary Policy.” Economic Journal, vol. 73, December 1963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3]Brosky, John J. “The Implicit Cost of Trade Credit and Theory of Optimal Terms of Sale.” Occasional Paper, Credit Research Foundation, Inc., April 1969.Google Scholar
[4]Cagan, P.Changes in the Cyclical Behavior of Interest Rates.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 48, August 1966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[5]Christian, J., and Mazek, W.. “Corporate Debt Structure and the Differential Effects of Monetary Policy.” The Southern Economic Journal, vol. 35, April 1969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Friedland, Seymour. The Economics of Corporate Finance. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1966.Google Scholar
[7]Jaffee, D. M. Credit Rationing and the Commercial Loan Market. Unpublished Ph.D. diss., M.I.T., 1968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8]Jaffee, D. M., and Modigliani, F.. “A Theory and Test of Credit Rationing.” The American Economic Review, vol. 59, no. 5, December 1969.Google Scholar
[9]Laffer, Arthur B.Trade Credit and the Money Market.” The Journal of Political Economy, March/April 1970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10]Lindsay, R., and Sametz, A.. Financial Management, An Analytical Approach, rev. ed.Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, 1967.Google Scholar
[11]Meltzer, A. H.Mercantile Credit, Monetary Policy and Size of Firms.” Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 42, no. 4, November 1960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[12]Nadiri, M. I.The Determinants of Trade Credit in the U. S. Total Manufacturing Sector.” Econometrica, vol. 37, no. 3, July 1969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13]Seiden, Martin H.The Quality of Trade Credit. Occasional Paper 87, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1964.Google Scholar
[14]Silber, W., and Polakoff, M.. “The Differential Effects of Tight Money: An Econometric Study.” Journal of Finance, vol. 25, no. 1, March 1970.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[15]Wrightsman, Dwayne. “Optimal Credit Terms for Accounts Receivable.” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, Summer 1969.Google Scholar