Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:47:52.959Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Voters Don't Care Much About Incumbency

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 October 2014

Adam R. Brown*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Brigham Young University, 745 Kimball Tower, Provo, UT 84602, USA; e-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

US House incumbents enjoy profound electoral advantages, yet existing research has not asked whether individual voters actually prefer incumbents over newcomers, other things being equal. Instead, existing research has focused on showing that other things are not equal by emphasizing the structural advantages that incumbents enjoy. Political scientists, economists, and pundits have frequently speculated that voters either reward or punish incumbency, even when structural advantages are ignored. A randomized survey experiment administered in two waves to 1,976 respondents suggests that voters respond only minimally—if at all—to incumbency status once the structural advantages are held constant. Voters do not exhibit a strong general preference either for or against incumbency.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Experimental Research Section of the American Political Science Association 2014 

Prior to the 2010 Congressional elections, pundits and reporters at countless media outlets warned of a powerful anti-incumbent mood with the potential to send many representatives packing. In the end, however, 85% of the US House incumbents who sought reelection won—a rate only slightly lower than average.Footnote 1 Nevertheless, good media narratives die hard, and two years later reporters were still talking about an “anti-incumbent mood” persisting into 2012.Footnote 2 Some pundits even claimed a generalized preference among voters for challengers over incumbents; “undecideds usually break against the incumbent,” asserted one, without providing evidence.Footnote 3

Of course, existing political science research provides little reason to be surprised by high reelection rates. Rather, academic research shows that Congressional incumbents enjoy clear electoral advantages. But in explaining the origins of this advantage, scholars have focused almost exclusively on the structural advantages of incumbency without considering voter-level effects. That is, existing research has not typically asked whether individual voters actually like or dislike incumbents, other things being equal. Instead, existing research has (correctly) stressed that other things are not equal by showing how incumbents can use the perks of office to build their name recognition, deter strong challengers, and ultimately win more votes.

Several scholars have speculated over the years in their published work that voters might actually prefer incumbents over challengers (e.g., Ansolabehere et al. Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart2000; Campbell and Miller Reference Campbell and Miller1957; Cover Reference Cover1977; Fatas et al. Reference Fatas, Neugebauer and Tamborero2007; Ferejohn Reference Ferejohn1977; Samuelson and Zeckhauser Reference Samuelson and Zeckhauser1988)—speculations at odds with the media narrative that voters generally oppose incumbency—but these speculations remain mostly untested. Since incumbents enjoy such great structural advantages, the best way to identify whether voters prefer (or oppose) incumbents qua incumbents is through randomized experimentation. The experimental results reported here suggest that voters react only minimally, if at all, to incumbency status.

THINKING ABOUT VOTERS AND INCUMBENTS

There is no question that Congressional incumbents enjoy profound electoral advantages. Only twice since 1976 have fewer than 90% of House incumbents who sought reelection won it.Footnote 4 Typically, incumbents win by large margins. Researchers seeking to explain these trends have generally pointed to structural factors, which can be grouped into four broad categories. First, incumbents can exploit the resources of office for electoral goals—activities that Mayhew (Reference Mayhew1974) called “advertising,” “credit claiming,” and “position taking.” These activities enable incumbents to cultivate an apolitical appeal, one that helps them remain personally popular within their respective districts even if their political party—or Congress itself—is less popular (Fenno Reference Fenno and Ornstein1975; Fiorina Reference Fiorina1977; Parker and Davidson Reference Parker and Davidson1979).

Second, incumbents enjoy a sizeable financial advantage (Cho and Gimpel Reference Cho and Gimpel2007; Jacobson Reference Jacobson2013, pp. 51–59), largely because many access-minded donors prefer to give to incumbents rather than to improbable challengers (Francia et al. Reference Francia, Green, Herrnson, Powell and Wilcox2003). Third, a “scare-off” effect enhances any other structural advantages of incumbency; the most capable challengers strategically choose not to waste their energy battling entrenched incumbents (Cox and Katz Reference Cox and Katz1996; Jacobson and Kernell Reference Jacobson and Kernell1983; Stone et al. Reference Stone, Maisel and Maestas2004). Fourth, it may simply be that incumbents are more skilled politicians than their challengers; after all, elections serve as filters that reward political competence, and one thing incumbents have in common is that they have made it through that filter at least once in the past (Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita Reference Ashworth and Bueno de Mesquita2008; McCurly and Mondak Reference McCurly and Mondak1995; Mondak Reference Mondak1995a, Reference Mondak1995b; Zaller Reference Zaller and Geer1998).

As insightful as existing research has been, however, it has not asked what voters think about incumbents qua incumbents. Voters rarely have enough information to behave the way democratic theorists might like, but they compensate somewhat by relying on information shortcuts (Lupia and McCubbins Reference Lupia and McCubbins1998). Since partisanship and incumbency are often the only two shortcuts available on the ballot itself, we might expect voters to make use of both of these. Evidence dating back decades shows that voters use the partisanship shortcut (e.g., Campbell et al. Reference Campbell, Converse, Miller and Stokes1960), a finding that this study confirmsFootnote 5 ; the incumbency shortcut remains underexplored.

Those political scientists who have written on the topic have generally supposed that incumbency labels may work in favor of incumbents. Campbell and Miller (Reference Campbell and Miller1957, p. 305) long ago suggested that voters might prefer candidates merely because of “their designation as incumbents” on the ballot. In the midst of the Southern realignment, Ferejohn (Reference Ferejohn1977) and Cover (Reference Cover1977) supposed that declining party loyalty might render incumbency an increasingly important voting cue. Ansolabehere et al. (Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart2000) echoed this logic, writing that “incumbency may simply act as a voting cue, a label which voters rely on because party has become less relevant.”

None of these scholars tested their suspicions, but experimental evidence from other fields lends support. For example, economists have uncovered evidence of a “status quo bias” in political decision-making generally: “People will only switch to a new policy if they strictly prefer it to the old one” (Fatas et al. Reference Fatas, Neugebauer and Tamborero2007). Faced with a choice between preserving the status quo and switching to an unknown alternative (cf. Ferejohn Reference Ferejohn1986), these experiments suggest that people will choose continuity. Similarly, Samuelson and Zeckhauser (Reference Samuelson and Zeckhauser1988, p. 8) extrapolated from their own experimental results to predict that this status quo bias could lead voters “to elect an incumbent to still another term in office.” Specifically, they conjectured that status quo bias alone could shift what might otherwise be a perfectly divided 50–50 vote into a 59–41 vote sending an incumbent back to Washington (Samuelson and Zeckhauser Reference Samuelson and Zeckhauser1988, p. 9).

Of course, incumbency might evoke a negative response from voters, especially in the case of long-term incumbents. The media narratives quoted above assume as much. Observational research has found some evidence of “incumbency fatigue” hurting the vote shares of long-time Congressional incumbents (Carson et al. Reference Carson, Jenkins, Rohde and Souva2001; Lin and Guillen Reference Lin and Guillen1999). Structural forces such as rising challenger quality contribute to this incumbency fatigue (Carson Reference Carson2005), but if media pundits are to be believed, there is also a voter-level fatigue effect.

Consider also the role of partisanship. When Gallup reported in June 2010 that only 32% of voters felt that “most members” of Congress deserved reelection, reporters quickly raised the specter of an anti-incumbent wave.Footnote 6 What they failed to note, however, was the partisan pattern among respondents. Among Republicans, only 16% felt “most members” deserved reelection; among Democrats, whose party controlled Congress, the rate rose to 53%. Apparently, voters were mentally changing the question from asking about “most members” to asking about “most majority (Democratic) members.” Surely, Gallup would have found an even wider partisan gap if it had asked separately whether “most Republican members” and “most Democratic members” deserve reelection. Because voters typically prefer candidates from their own party, regardless of incumbency status, we might expect the effects of incumbency on voter preferences to diminish when candidate partisanship is disclosed.

This discussion leads to the following three questions. We prefer the language of “questions” rather than “hypotheses” due to the relative weakness of our theoretical priors:

  • Question 1: Do voters prefer incumbents over challengers (other things equal)?

  • Question 2: Does lengthier incumbency render voters less supportive of incumbents?

  • Question 3: Do any effects of incumbency diminish when each candidate's partisanship is known?

EXPERIMENTAL CONDITIONS

We already know from observational research that incumbents outperform challengers on election day.Footnote 7 Observational studies cannot disentangle the structural advantages of incumbency from voters' raw feelings about incumbency itself, but randomized experimentation can. The null hypothesis is simply that voters do not care about incumbency status, other things being equal. Whether the opposite is true has not been fully assessed. Kam and Zechmeister (Reference Kam and Zechmeister2013) recently published suggestive evidence that incumbency can serve as a shortcut, although they did not attempt to estimate its strength. A more direct test comes from Klein and Baum (Reference Klein and Baum2001), who randomly manipulated whether they informed survey respondents of candidates' partisanship and incumbency status prior to asking for their vote choice; since they worked in the context of a real election, however, it is possible that voters had this information even if the researchers did not provide it. The experiment reported here takes a different approach.

In November 2012, a nationally representative sample of 997 respondents to the online Cooperative Congressional Election Study (hereafter “CCES”) completed a simple survey experiment related to these questions. The questions were piloted three months earlier to 979 online respondents recruited from July 16–29, 2012, using Amazon's Mechanical Turk service (hereafter “MTurk”).Footnote 8 The question wording was the same in both waves. As with previous MTurk studies (Berinsky et al. Reference Berinsky, Huber and Lenz2012), the MTurk demographics differ markedly from the more representative CCES sample. (See Table A1 in the supplemental appendix.) Although neither sample is perfectly representative of American voters, they provide two large-N tests that ultimately produce the same general findings.

Respondents were presented with brief profiles of two fictional Congressional candidates, Steven Redden and Ray Kepler. The candidates were characterized as actual candidates running against each other in another state, who had purportedly had their names changed for purposes of the survey. To distract from the study's purpose, each profile contained static information about the candidate's family, career, residency, campaign, and endorsements. Respondents indicated their preferred candidate along a seven-point scale labeled “Definitely Steven Redden” at one end and “Definitely Ray Kepler” at the other. Figure 1 presents the question wording and formatting.

Figure 1 Question Wording

The candidate profiles varied randomly along two dimensions.Footnote 9 First, references to candidate partisanship varied. One group saw the partisan descriptions shown in Figure 1 (but without italics), another group saw the partisanship reversed, and the third group saw no mention of partisanship at all. Second, references to incumbency varied. Those in the control group saw no reference to incumbency. Those in the treatment groups saw a brief paragraph inserted into the middle of Kepler's profile—only Kepler's, never Redden's—characterizing him as an incumbent. To answer Question 1, the Incumbency: No length treatment read, “Kepler is the current Representative. He is seeking reelection to another term.” To answer Question 2, the Incumbency: 2 years and Incumbency: 22 years treatments read, “Kepler has served in Congress for the past (2 or 22) years. He is seeking reelection to another term.”

Respondents were randomly assigned into these three partisan conditions and four incumbency conditions, producing 12 groups. Table 1 shows the average vote choice (along the seven-point scale) and the number of respondents in each group.Footnote 10 Because assignment was random, it is unnecessary to include control variables or survey weights in the analysis that follows. Moreover, it appears the randomization “worked”; assignment to these conditions does not correlate meaningfully with respondent age, partisanship, education, or gender in either wave (see Tables A2 and A3 in the supplemental appendix).Footnote 11

Table 1 Means (and Respondents) by Treatment Group

Note: Figures shown are the mean vote choice score along the seven-point scale within each cell. Parentheses indicate the number of respondents per cell.

The difficulty with vignette experiments is that the treatment language can be so subtle that respondents fail to notice it (Mutz Reference Mutz2011, p. 84). To guard against this possibility, the MTurk pilot included a manipulation check. After indicating their preferred candidate, respondents were shown a new screen asking three factual questions about the candidates. The first question asked which candidate had spent more money on the race, the second one asked which candidate was the incumbent, and the third question asked which candidate was the Republican. Overall, 89% of respondents answered at least two of the three questions correctly, and 63% answered all three correctly. Accuracy rates were high across all experimental conditions,Footnote 12 even though respondents generally completed the survey very quickly.Footnote 13 The MTurk pilot shows that the experimental manipulations, although subtle, effectively attracted respondents' notice.

FINDINGS

The dependent variable is the respondent's preferred candidate, coded from 1 (firm support for Redden) through 7 (firm support for Kepler).Footnote 14 The incumbency treatments described above were applied only to Kepler. Thus, a positive coefficient on one of the incumbency treatment dummies indicates that respondents reacted favorably to incumbency status; a negative coefficient indicates that respondents reacted negatively to incumbency status. When assessing Question 3, we also include a dichotomous partisan condition variable indicating whether candidate partisanship was stated.

Tables 2 and 3 present four specifications, each of which is estimated three times: once on CCES, once on MTurk, and once on pooled respondents. Models 1a–1c in Table 2 provide the most direct answer to Question 1; with all incumbency treatments pooled into a single dichotomous indicator, we find no evidence that voters react to incumbency. Models 2a–2c assess Question 3 by interacting this incumbency dummy with partisan condition. Neither the incumbency dummies nor their interactions have meaningful effects.

Table 2 Effects of Incumbency on Vote Preference

Notes: †p ≤ 0.10, *p ≤ 0.05, **p ≤ 0.01 (two-tailed).

The dependent variable is a seven-point vote choice indicator modeled using ordinary least squares. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

Table 3 Effects of Incumbency Length on Vote Preference

Notes: †p ≤ 0.10, *p ≤ 0.05, **p ≤ 0.01 (two-tailed).

The dependent variable is a seven-point vote choice indicator modeled using ordinary least squares. Robust standard errors are in parentheses.

Table 3 breaks out the incumbency treatments to assess Question 2. Although the 2 years treatment attains statistical significance in Model 3b, the lack of meaningful incumbency effects elsewhere in Models 3a–3c suggests this lone finding is a fluke. Moreover, the 2 years coefficient is statistically indistinguishable from the 22 years coefficient in all six models shown in Table 3, suggesting a negative answer to Question 2. Models 4a–4c add interactions with partisan condition. Again, neither the incumbency dummies nor their interactions have meaningful effects. An exception is the 22 years treatment in Model 4b, although a broader glance at Table 3 suggests that this too is a fluke.

In all 12 models, incumbency dummies (and their interactions with partisan condition) have substantively small coefficients that are usually indistinguishable from zero.Footnote 15 For perspective, consider the effect of partisanship. When Kepler is randomly assigned the respondent's partisanship, we expect the respondent's vote preference to move by 1.3 or 1.4 points along the seven-point scale (see Table A6 in the supplemental appendix). This large, unsurprising partisan effect reveals just how inconsequential are the estimated effects of incumbency.Footnote 16

Table 4 explores the data from one additional angle, considering each possible combination of respondent and candidate partisanship.Footnote 17 Each coefficient shown is the result of a separate difference-of-means test on the dependent variable; in each test, all three incumbency treatments are pooled into one treatment group and compared with the control group. This is perhaps the best overall way to identify a voter-level incumbency effect; if anything, we should see Republican respondents rewarding Republican incumbents for their longevity and despising Democratic incumbents for their resilience. Democratic respondents, of course, would do the reverse. Instead, we continue to see nothing. With 18 tests reported here, we should not be surprised that one produced a result significant at the 0.05 level. Taken as a whole, though, Table 4 offers little evidence that voters care about incumbency—not even when respondent and candidate partisanship are taken into account.

Table 4 Difference of Mean Tests By Partisan Subgroup

Notes: †p ≤ 0.10, *p ≤ 0.05, **p ≤ 0.01 (two-tailed).

Each cell reports the difference in the mean evaluation of the incumbent candidate between respondents who saw one candidate described as an incumbent (the treatment group) and respondents who did not (the control group). A positive value indicates that respondents reacted favorably to incumbency.

CONCLUSIONS

Researchers have conjectured that voters favor incumbents over challengers, even with the structural advantages of incumbency held constant (e.g., Ansolabehere et al. Reference Ansolabehere, Snyder and Stewart2000; Campbell and Miller Reference Campbell and Miller1957; Cover Reference Cover1977; Fatas et al. Reference Fatas, Neugebauer and Tamborero2007; Ferejohn Reference Ferejohn1977; Samuelson and Zeckhauser Reference Samuelson and Zeckhauser1988). Media narratives, on the other hand, often speak of incumbency as a liability, a position supported by observational evidence of “incumbency fatigue” (Carson Reference Carson2005; Carson et al. Reference Carson, Jenkins, Rohde and Souva2001; Lin and Guillen Reference Lin and Guillen1999).

The results presented here work against both propositions. Voters seem to care little whether a candidate is an incumbent, a challenger, or pursuing an open seat. No design is perfect, and this study has its limitations. It may be that 2012 was an unusual year, with a fleeting anti-incumbent mood offsetting a background pro-incumbent sentiment. It may also be that respondents behaved differently within the experimental context than they would in a real voting situation. Nevertheless, to the extent that incumbents enjoy electoral advantages, these results suggest we can credit structural factors rather than voter preferences as the source. Jacobson (Reference Jacobson2013, p. 147) was apparently correct: “Voters are not strongly attracted by incumbency per se.” Whether states choose to write the word “incumbent” on their ballot—and whether candidates choose to write “incumbent” on their yard signs—seems to have little effect on election results.

SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL

To view supplementary material for this paper, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S2052263014000062.

Footnotes

1 Of the 396 incumbents who sought reelection, 4 lost in primaries and 54 lost in November, an 85% reelection rate (Jacobson Reference Jacobson2013, p. 31). Of the 39 retirements, 17 left to run for another office (usually Senate or Governor), leaving 22 retirements that may have been strategic decisions to avoid a certain defeat. Even if we count these 22 retirements as defeated incumbents, however, the reelection rate is still a respectable 338 out of 418, or 81%.

2 For example, see “2012 is definitely an anti-incumbent year,” published by the Washington Post on March 14, 2012, at < http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/the-fix/post/2012-is-definitely-an-anti-incumbent-year/2012/03/14/gIQAGF4rBS_blog.html>.

3 From Sean Trende at Real Clear Politics (see http://www.realclearpolitics.com/articles/2010/10/07/ the_democrats_dead_cat_bounce_107476.html). See also Michael Barone at The Washington Examiner (http://www.washingtonexaminer.com/politics/House-Democrats-head-for-a-thumping-at-the-polls-1004124-99388554.html).

4 In 1992 (88%) and 2010 (85%); see Jacobson (Reference Jacobson2013, p. 31).

5 See Table A6 in the supplemental appendix.

6 For examples, see “[Gallup] Polls Reflect Anti-Incumbent Mood,” from the Caucus at The New York Times, posted June 8, 2010 at < http://thecaucus.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/06/08/polls-reflect-anti-incumbent-mood/>; “Voters' Support for Members of Congress is at an All-Time Low, [Washington Post–ABC News] Poll Finds” June 8, 2010, Washington Post.

7 Among the earliest studies of this sort were Abramowitz (Reference Abramowitz1975), Ferejohn (Reference Ferejohn1977), and Nelson (Reference Nelson1978). Good overviews are in Jacobson (Reference Jacobson2013) and Herrnson (Reference Herrnson2008).

8 Only MTurk users from the United States were included. Each participant received $0.21 in compensation.

9 For MTurk users only, profiles varied along a third dimension: the order of the candidate profiles. Because it made no difference which profile appeared at left, this dimension was omitted from the CCES wave.

10 Respondents had a one-third probability of assignment to any of the three partisan conditions. CCES respondents had a one-quarter probability of assignment to any of the four incumbency conditions; MTurk respondents had a one-third probability of assignment to the control or “no length” conditions, and a one-sixth probability of assignment to the “2 years” or “22 years” conditions.

11 A hotelling vector of means test could not be rejected at p < 0.05, suggesting that the mean values for these demographic variables are statistically indistinguishable across these groups.

12 For incumbency, 89% correctly chose “I don't know” in the incumbency control condition, and 73% correctly chose Kepler in the treatment conditions. For partisanship, 76% correctly chose “I don't know” in the partisanship control condition, and 88% correctly identified the Republican candidate when partisanship was explicitly mentioned.

13 The MTurk study involved a consent screen, the treatment question, the three manipulation check questions, and four demographic questions, with each step displayed on a separate screen. Still, the median respondent spent only 75 seconds on the survey, with the 25th and 75th percentiles at 60 and 94 seconds respectively. Even among those who spent 42 seconds or less on the survey (the 5th percentile), 64% answered at least two of the manipulation checks correctly. The MTurk study served as a pilot to test the protocol before placing the experiment on the costlier CCES, where similar metrics were not included for financial reasons.

14 Strictly speaking, this is an ordinal variable. We present ordered probit results in the supplemental appendix (Tables A4 and A5), but the analysis here relies on OLS for its ease of interpretation.

15 Incumbency coefficients based on the CCES data are mostly positive (and insignificant), while coefficients from the MTurk data are mostly negative (and insignificant). Although coefficients from both datasets are generally statistically indistinguishable from zero, they are sometimes statistically distinguishable from one another. In pooled models (1c and 2c) given in Table 2, interacting the incumbency dummy with CCES dummy reveals that the two datasets produce statistically different treatment effects (0.01 < p < 0.05). Similarly, in pooled models (3c and 4c) given in Table 3, interacting the incumbency dummies with CCES dummy reveals statistically different coefficients for Incumbency: 2 years (0.01 < p < 0.05) and Incumbency: 22 years (0.05 < p < 0.10), but not for Incumbency: No length. In all pooled models, including these interactions renders CCES dummy insignificant. It is not clear what drives this difference between CCES and the MTurk data, as the CCES dummy interaction remains significant when controlling for the key indicators that make MTurk samples unique—age, partisanship, gender, and education.

16 The non-effects of incumbency persist when demographic controls are included or when the MTurk analysis is limited to those who answered all three manipulation checks correctly.

17 Independent respondents omitted due to sample size. Leaners coded as partisans.

References

REFERENCES

Abramowitz, A. I. 1975. Name Familiarity, Reputation, and the Incumbency Effect in a Congressional Election. Western Political Quarterly 28 (December): 668–84.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M. Jr., and Stewart, C. III 2000. Old Voters, New Voters, and the Personal Vote: Using Redistricting to Measure the Incumbency Advantage. American Journal of Political Science 44 (January): 1734.Google Scholar
Ashworth, S. and Bueno de Mesquita, E. 2008. Electoral Selection, Strategic Challenger Entry, and the Incumbency Advantage. Journal of Politics 70 (October): 1006–25.Google Scholar
Berinsky, A. J., Huber, G. A., and Lenz, G. S. 2012. Evaluating Online Labor Markets for Experimental Research: Amazon.com's Mechanical Turk. Political Analysis 20: 351–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, A., Converse, P. E., Miller, W. E., and Stokes, D. E. 1960. The American Voter. New York, NY: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Campbell, A., and Miller, W. E. 1957. The Motivational Basis of Straight and Split Ticket Voting. American Political Science Review 51 (June): 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carson, J. L. 2005. Strategy, Selection, and Candidate Competition in US House and Senate Elections. Journal of Politics 67 (February): 128.Google Scholar
Carson, J. L., Jenkins, J. A., Rohde, D. W., and Souva, M. A. 2001. The Impact of National Tides and District-Level Effects on Electoral Outcomes: The US Congressional Elections of 1862. American Journal of Political Science 45 (October): 887–98.Google Scholar
Cho, W. K. T., and Gimpel, J. G. 2007. Prospecting for (Campaign) Gold. American Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 255–68.Google Scholar
Cover, A. D. 1977. One Good Term Deserves Another: The Advantage of Incumbency in Congressional Elections. American Journal of Political Science 21 (September): 523–41.Google Scholar
Cox, G. W., and Katz, J. N. 1996. Why Did the Incumbency Advantage in US House Elections Grow? American Journal of Political Science 40 (May): 478–97.Google Scholar
Fatas, E., Neugebauer, T., and Tamborero, P. 2007. How Politicians Make Decisions: A Political Choice Experiment. Journal of Economics 92 (2): 167–96.Google Scholar
Fenno, R. F. Jr. 1975. If, as Ralph Nader Says, Congress If the Broken Branch, How Come We Love Our Congressmen so Much? In Congress in Change: Evolution and Reform eds. Ornstein, N. J.. New York, NY: Praeger, 277–87.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. A. 1977. On the Decline of Competition in Congressional Elections. American Political Science Review 71 (March): 166–76.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. A. 1986. Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control. Public Choice 50 (Fall): 525.Google Scholar
Fiorina, M. P. 1977. The Case of the Vanishing Marginals: The Bureaucracy Did It. American Political Science Review 71 (March): 177–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francia, P. L., Green, J. C., Herrnson, P. S., Powell, L. W., and Wilcox, C. 2003. The Financiers of Congressional Elections: Investors, Ideologues, and Intimates. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Herrnson, P. S. 2008. Congressional Elections: Campaigning at Home and in Washington. Washington DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Jacobson, G. C. 2013. The Politics of Congressional Elections. 8th ed. Boston, MA: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Jacobson, G. C., and Kernell, S. 1983. Strategy and Choice in Congressional Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Kam, C. D., and Zechmeister, E. J. 2013. Name Recognition and Candidate Support. American Journal of Political Science 57 (October): 971–86.Google Scholar
Klein, D., and Baum, L. 2001. Ballot Information and Voting Decisions in Judicial Elections. Political Research Quarterly 54 (December): 709–28.Google Scholar
Lin, T.-min, and Guillen, M. 1999. The Rising Hazards of Party Incumbency: A Discrete Renewal Analysis. Political Analysis 7: 3157.Google Scholar
Lupia, A., and McCubbins, M. D. 1998. The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need to Know? Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, D. R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McCurly, C., and Mondak, J. J. 1995. Inspected by # 1184063113: The Influence of Incumbents' Competence and Integrity in US House Elections. American Journal of Political Science 39 (November): 864–85.Google Scholar
Mondak, J. J. 1995a. Competence, Integrity, and Electoral Success of Congressional Incumbents. Journal of Politics 57 (November): 1043–69.Google Scholar
Mondak, J. J. 1995b. Elections as Filters: Term Limits and the Composition of the US House. Political Research Quarterly 48 (December): 701–27.Google Scholar
Mutz, D. C. 2011. Population-Based Survey Experiments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, C. J. 1978. The Effect of Incumbency on Voting in Congressional Elections, 1964–1974. Political Science Quarterly 4 (Winter): 665–78.Google Scholar
Parker, G. R., and Davidson, R. H. 1979. Why Do Americans Love Their Congressmen so Much More than Their Congress? Legislative Studies Quarterly 4 (February): 5361.Google Scholar
Samuelson, W., and Zeckhauser, R. 1988. Status Quo Bias in Decision-Making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1 (1): 759.Google Scholar
Stone, W. J., Maisel, S. L., and Maestas, C. D. 2004. Quality Counts: Extending the Strategic Politician Model of Incumbent Deterrence. American Journal of Political Science 48 (July): 479–95.Google Scholar
Zaller, J. 1998. Politicians As Prize Fighters: Electoral Selection and Incumbency Advantage. In Party Politics and Politicians ed. Geer, J.. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 125–85.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Question Wording

Figure 1

Table 1 Means (and Respondents) by Treatment Group

Figure 2

Table 2 Effects of Incumbency on Vote Preference

Figure 3

Table 3 Effects of Incumbency Length on Vote Preference

Figure 4

Table 4 Difference of Mean Tests By Partisan Subgroup

Supplementary material: File

Brown Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Brown Supplementary Material(File)
File 193.5 KB