Article contents
Why Was Specie Scarce in Colonial Economies? An Analysis of the Canadian Currency, 1796–1830
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 03 March 2009
Abstract
Colonial economies suffered from a scarcity of specie that traditionally has been attributed to a chronic external drain. An analysis of the Canadian currency in the early nineteenth century suggests that the explanation for the specie scarcity lies in the multi-coin monetary standard imposed by the currency laws. Gresham's Law accurately predicts the coins that circulated in Canada, and it is concluded that the colonists suffered from a lack of quality rather than quantity of specie.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The Economic History Association 1984
References
1 Hammond, Bray, Banks and Politics in America from the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton, 1957), p. 1. The most recent variation of this hypothesis suggests that the absence of coins of small denominations was a particularly significant stimulus to the emergence of paper currency.Google Scholar See Hanson, John R. II, “Small Notes in the American Colonies,” Explorations in Economic History 17 (10, 1980), 411–20. A very brief survey of Australian monetary history suggests that the “scarcity of specie” is also a part of that literature.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Steven speaks of a colony “denuded of coin”; Steven, M. J. E., “The Changing Pattern of Commerce” in Economic Growth of Australia, 1788–1821, Abbott, G. J. and Nairn, N. J., eds. (Melbourne, 1969) p. 302.Google Scholar See also Jackson, R. V., Australian Economic Development in the Nineteenth Century (Canberra, 1977).Google Scholar
2 This theory has taken its most sophisticated form in the monetary approach to the balance of payments; however, as Frenkel and Johnson note, its roots can be traced to the writings of Gervaise and Hume. See Frenkel, Jacob A. and Johnson, H. G. “The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments: Essential Concepts and Historical Origins” in The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments, Frenkel, J. A. and Johnson, H. G., eds. (Toronto, 1976).Google Scholar
3 See Neufeld, E. P., ed., Money and Banking in Canada (Toronto, 1964; reprint ed., Toronto, 1967), p. 1.Google Scholar
4 See Craig, Gerald M., Upper Canada: the Formative Years (Toronto, 1963) for a general history of Upper Canada from 1791 to 1841,Google Scholar and Ouellet, Fernand, Lower Canada (Toronto, 1980) for the same for Lower Canada.Google Scholar
5 Census of Canada, 1870–71, 4 (Ottawa, 1876).Google Scholar
6 Stevenson, James, “The War of 1812 in connection with the Army Bill Act,” Transactions of the Literary and Historical Society of Quebec, 21 (1891–1892).Google Scholar
7 McIvor, Craig, Canadian Monetary Banking and Fiscal Development (Toronto, 1961), p. 20.Google Scholar
8 See Shortt, Adam, “The Early History of Canadian Banking,” Journal of the Canadian Bankers' Association, pt. 4, “The First Banks in Lower Canada” (July 1897), 341–60; pt. 5, “The First Banks in Upper Canada,” (Oct., 1897), 1–21.Google Scholar
9 Canada, Lower, House of Assembly, Journals (1831); Upper Canada, House of Assembly, Journals (1831).Google Scholar
10 Shortt, “The Early History,” pt. 3 (April, 1897), 246.Google Scholar
11 Cited in Stevenson, James, “The Currency of Canada After the Capitulation” in Transactions of the Literary and Historical Society of Quebec, 12 (1877), 121.Google Scholar
12 Cited in Castell-Hopkins, J., Canada: An Encyclopedia of the Country (Toronto, 1898), p. 461.Google Scholar
13 p. 461.
14 Upper Canada, House of Assembly, Journals (17 March 1817), in Report of the Bureau of Archives of Ontario (1913), p. 378.Google Scholar
15 “The want of such an establishment (a bank) was severely felt before the war, and there is hardly any doubt but that the same inconvenience will very shortly occur, whereas a well-regulated bank would obviate all these difficulties by keeping up a circulating medium to meet every public demand,” cited in Castell-Hopkins, Encyclopedia, p. 463.Google Scholar
16 Upper Canada, House of Assembly, Journals (6 April 1821), in Report of the Bureau of Archives of Ontario (1913), p. 450.Google Scholar
17 Fetter, Frank Whitson, “Some Neglected Aspects of Gresham's Law,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 46 (05 1932). Fetter's analysis applies Gresham's Law to a monetary system in which many different coins circulate. In a recent article linking Gresham's Law and the literature on currency substitution, Gresham's Law is applied to a monetary system where the “good” money is coins and the “bad” money is paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar See Flynn, Dennis O. and Roper, Don, “Gresham's Law and the Modern Theory of the Demand for Money,” Eastern Economic Journal, 8 (07 1982).Google Scholar
18 Fetter, , “Gresham's Law,” p. 493.Google Scholar
19 Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna, A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (Princeton, 1963), p. 27.Google Scholar
20 A point made by Sumner, William G., A History of American Currency (New York, 1874; reprint ed., New York, 1968), p. 13.Google Scholar
21 Note that this problem arises when the receivers of coins cannot immediately distinguish a counterfeit or clipped coin from a good coin. See Akerlof, George, “The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84 (08 1970), 488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
22 Officer, Lawrence H., “Dollar-Sterling Mint Parity and Exchange Rates, 1791–1834,” this Journal, 43 (09, 1983), 592.Google Scholar
23 See Upper Canada, Statutes, 7 Geo. IV c 4.Google Scholar
24 Shortt, Adam, “The History of Canadian Currency Banking and Exchange,” Journal of the Canadian Bankers' Association, 10 (07 1902), p. 272. “The British coins, which alone were accepted in payment for (Commissariat) bills, bore a corresponding premium. The soldiers, who were paid in half crowns at the rate of 2s. 9d. currency, immediately disposed of them at the nearest shop for 3s. in current money or goods. The merchants in turn immediately conveyed the coins to the Government chest, whence they had just emerged, for the purchase of Government exchange.”Google Scholar
25 Lower Canada, House of Assembly, Journals, vol.25 (1816), Appendix G.Google Scholar
26 Britain, Great, Parliament, “Appendix to the Final Report of the Decimal Coinage Commissioner, 1859,” in Monetary Policy: Decimal Coinage, vol. 2 (Shannon, 1970), p. 45. Louis XV reigned from 1715 to 1774.Google Scholar
27 Upper Canada, House of Assembly, “Report of the Select Committee on the State of the Currency,” Journals (1830), Appendix, p. 22.Google Scholar
28 p. 29.
29 Lower Canada, House of Assembly, Journals, 33 (1823–1824), 288.Google Scholar
30 Cited in Upper Canada, “Report of the Select Committee on the Currency,” p. 37.Google Scholar
31 Supple, B. E., “Currency and Commerce in the Early Seventeenth Century” Economic History Review, 10 (12 1957), 244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
32 Innis, H. A. and Lower, A. R. M., Select Documents in Canadian Economic History (Toronto, 1933), p. 388.Google Scholar
33 Breckenridge, Roeliff Morton, The Canadian Banking System 1817–1890 (New York, 1895), and Shortt, “Canadian Banking.”Google Scholar
34 Craig, Upper Canada, p. 161.Google Scholar
35 Neufeld, Money and Banking, p. 1.Google Scholar
36 Neufeld, E. P., The Financial System of Canada (Toronto, 1972), p. 39.Google Scholar
37 Hume, David, “Of the Balance of Trade,” in Rotwein, E., ed., David Hume: Writings on Economics (London, 1955).Google Scholar
38 British Military Records, Records of the Commissariat (1800) P.A.C. R.G.8 Series C., vol. 321, roll 97, p. 81.Google Scholar
39 See, for example, Easterbrook, W. T. and Aitken, H. G. J., Canadian Economic History (Toronto, 1956),Google Scholar and Watkins, M. H., “A Staple Theory of Economic Growth,” Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29 (05 1963), 141–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
40 Innis, H. A., The Cod Fisheries: The History of an International Economy (Toronto, 1954),Google Scholar and The Fur Trade in Canada: An Introduction to Canadian Economic History (Toronto, 1956).Google Scholar
41 Innis, The Fur Trade, p. 383.Google Scholar
42 See Marr, William L. and Paterson, Donald G., Canada: An Economic History (Toronto, 1980),Google Scholar and in the United States, Lindstrom, Diane, Economic Development in the Philadelphia Region (New York, 1978).Google Scholar
43 Miller, Harry E., Banking Theories in the United States Before 1860 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1927; reprint ed., Clifton, New Jersey, 1972), p. 48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
44 Hume, “The Balance of Trade,” p. 61.Google Scholar
- 17
- Cited by