Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T10:16:49.343Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Monetary Movements and Market Structure—Forces for Contraction in Fourteenth-and Fifteenth-Century England

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Harry A. Miskimin
Affiliation:
Yale University

Extract

That the Black Death of 1348–1349 disrupted the economies of Europe during the later middle ages is not open to doubt. That the economic effects of the plague varied from sector to sector is perhaps equally indubitable. The diversity of its impact upon various economic sectors reveals itself both in contemporary evidence and in the fiery controversies generated by modern economic historians, each basing his argument on conflicting statistics or inferences drawn, often without careful regard, from disparate sectors. It is thus not accidental that even the most cursory review of the literature concerning the period after the plague will unearth a surprising lack of agreement among the specialists.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1964

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Lopez, R. S. and Miskimin, H. A., “The Economic Depression of the Renaissance,” Economic History Review, 2d series, XIV (1962), 408–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Cipolla, C. M., Lopez, R. S., and Miskimin, H. A., “Economic Depression of the Renaissance?Economic History Review, 2d series, XVI (1964), 519–29.Google Scholar

3 Kosminsky, E. A., “Peut-on considerer le xiv et le xv siècles comme l'époque de la decadence de l'économie européenne?” Studi in onore di Armando Sapori (Milan: Istituto Editoriale Cisalpino, 1957), I, 550–69.Google Scholar

4 Bloch, M., “Le Problème de l'or au Moyen Age,” Annales d'histoire économique et sociale, V (1933), 134Google Scholar. Lombard, M., “L'or musulman du viie au xie siècle,” Annales, Économies, Sociétés, Civilisations, II (1947)Google Scholar.

5 Postan, M. M., “Rapport,” Rapports du ixe congrès international des sciences historiques (Paris: Annand Colin, 1950), I, 231Google Scholar.

6 Postan, “Rapport,” 231.

7 Postan, “Rapport,” passim, and Note,” Economic History Review, 2d series, XII (1959), 7782.Google Scholar

8 Postan, “Note,” 80.

9 Robinson, W. C., “Money, Population and Economic Change in Late Medieval. Europe,” Economic History Review, 2d series, XII (1959), 6376CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 Postan, “Note,” 79.

11 Russell, J. C., British Medieval Population (Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 1948)Google Scholar.

12 Nef, J. U., “Mining and Metallurgy in Medieval Civilisation,” The Cambridge Economic History (Cambridge [Engl.]: Cambridge University Press, 1952), II, 430–92.Google Scholar

13 Ruding, R., Annals of the Coinage of Britain and Its Dependencies (2d ed.; London, 1819), II, 136.Google Scholar

14 Ibid., 139.

15 Ibid., 155.

16 Ibid., 173.

17 Ibid., 180.

18 Ibid., 185.

19 Ibid., 187.

20 Ibid., 194.

21 Ibid., 202.

22 Ibid., 205.

23 Ibid., 207.

24 Ibid., 209.

25 Ibid., 210.

26 Ibid., 218.

27 Ibid., 222, 225.

28 Ibid., 298.

29 Ibid., 334.

30 Ibid., 339.

31 Ibid., 227.

32 SirCraig, John, The Mint: A History of the London Mint from A. D. 287 to 1948 (Cambridge [Engl.]: Cambridge University Press, 1953), p. 85.Google Scholar

33 Ruding, Annals, II, 205.

34 Ibid., 210–11.

35 Ibid., 233.

36 Ibid., 236, 251, 271, 333.

37 Ibid., 220.

38 Ibid., 228.

39 Ibid., 242–43.

40 Power, E. E., “The Wool Trade in the Fifteenth Century,” in Power, E. E. and Postan, M. M., Studies in English Trade in the Fifteenth Century (London: George Routledge & Sons, Ltd., 1933), p. 80.Google Scholar

41 Ruding, Annals, II, 256, 260–61, 271. de Roover, R., “La Balance commerciale entre les Pays-Bas et l'ltalie au quinsieme siècle,” Revue Beige de Philologie et d'Histoire, XXXVII (1959), 384Google Scholar.

42 Ruding, Annals, II, 277.

43 Ibid., 340–41.

44 Crump, C. G. and Johnson, C., “Tables of Bullion Coined under Edward I, II, III,” The Numismatic Chronicle, 4th series, XIII (1913), 200–45Google Scholar.

45 Miskimin, H. A., Money, Prices, and Foreign Exchange in Fourteenth Century France (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1963), p. 97.Google Scholar

46 McKisack, May, The Fourteenth Century, 1307–1399 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1959), p. 331Google Scholar.

47 Brown, E. H. Phelps and Hopkins, Sheila V., “Seven Centuries of the Prices of Consumables, Compared with Builders' Wage-rates,” reprinted from Economica (1956) in Carus-Wilson, E. M., Essays in Economic Historyx (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1962), II, 179–96.Google Scholar

48 Lopez and Miskimin, “Economic Depression,” p. 411.

49 Brown and Hopkins, “Seven Centuries of Prices,” p. 182.

50 Rogers, James E. Thorold, A History of Agriculture and Prices in England (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1866), I, 245Google Scholar.

51 Ibid., 320–21.

52 Ibid., 560, 567.

53 Ibid., 667–77. M. M. Postan, “The Trade of Medieval Europe: The North,” The Cambridge Economic History, II, 207.

54 Rogers, Agriculture and Prices, I, 669. F. G. Davenport, in “The Decay of Villeinage in East Anglia,” Essays in Economic History, II, 115, indicates that on one manor in 1378, 1,722 out of 3,219 work-weeks had ceased to be available. McKisack (The Fourteenth Century, pp. 333, 347) suggests population declined faster than cultivated land.

55 Ibid., pp. 337–38.

56 The indices are derived from Rogers, Agriculture and Prices, I.

57 Postan, “Trade of Medieval Europe,” pp. 209–10.

58 McKisack, The Fourteenth Century, pp. 340, 346.

59 Pratt, Geneviève, “Albi et la peste noire,” Annales du Midi, LXIV (1952), 1525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

60 Baldwin, F. E., Sumptuary Legislation and Personal Regulation in England (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1926), pp. 4647.Google Scholar

61 Ibid., pp. 47–50.

62 Ibid., pp. 50–51.

63 Norris, Herbert, Costume and Fashion (London: J. M. Dent and Sons Ltd., 1927), II, 204Google Scholar.

64 Ibid., pp. 204–6.

65 Ibid., pp. 281–83.

66 Ibid., pp. 247–52. Chaucer, Geoffrey, “The Parson's Tale,” The Canterbury Tales (Robinson, F. N., ed., The Poems of Chaucer, Houghton Mifflin Co.)Google Scholar, line 415 ff.

67 Rogers, Agriculture and Prices, I, 641.

68 James, M. K., “The Fluctuations of the Anglo-Gascon Wine Trade During the Fourteenth Century,” Economic History Review, 2d series, IV (1951), 170–96.Google Scholar

69 Postan, “Trade of Medieval Europe,” pp. 192–93. Rogers, Agriculture and Prices, I, 593.

70 de Roover, Raymond, The Rise and Decline of the Medici Bank, 1397–1494 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1963), p. 285.Google Scholar