Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T15:51:32.207Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fiscal Crisis and the Decline of Spain (Castile)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Dennis O. Flynn
Affiliation:
Faculty of the Department of Economics, University of the Pacific, Stockton, California 95211.

Abstract

Earl J. Hamilton's multiple theses on the price revolution, the decline of Spain, and the birth of capitalism have all placed American silver (and gold) at the forefront. This essay supports Hamilton's emphasis on the impact of New World treasure on the decline of Castile, but from a different angle. Mining profits rather than the quantity of imports supported the empire. When the profits dwindled, as was inevitable, international superiority was begrudgingly surrendered to the emerging powers of the north.

Type
Papers Presented at the Forty-First Annual Meeting of the Economic History Association
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Hamilton, Earl J., “The Decline of Spain,” Economic History Review, 8 (11 1937), 168–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 An overlapping literature on sixteenth-century price inflation reveals the same dichotomy: Hamilton's monetary view versus the so-called real explanations of others. For elimination of the chronology-related criticism of Hamilton's thesis, see Flynn, Dennis O., “A New Perspective on the Spanish Price Revolution: The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments,” Erplorations in Economic History, 15 (10 1978), 388406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 This section focuses on mine profits. The same model is used to explain the cause of the Price Revolution in Flynn, Dennis O., “Sixteenth Century Inflation from a Production Point of View,” in Inflation through the Ages: Economic, Social, Psychological and Historical Aspects (Brooklyn, forthcoming).Google Scholar

4 Nef, John U., “Silver Production in Central Europe,” Journal of Political Economy, 49 (08 1941), 576.Google Scholar

5 Perroy, Edouard (1955)Google Scholar as quoted in Wallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World Economy in the Sixteenth Century (New York, 1974), p. 41n.Google Scholar

6 Vilar, Pierre, Oro y moneda en Ia historia 1450–1920, 3rd ed. (Barcelona, 1974), pp. 8587.Google Scholar

7 For a demonstration that the exchange value of silver money reflects the value of silver in the bullion market, see Flynn, Dennis O. and Roper, Don, “Greshans's Law and the Modern Theory of the Demand for Money,” Eastern Economic Journal (1982, forthcoming).Google Scholar

8 Hamilton, Earl J., American Treasure and the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501–1650 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1934), p. 34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Jara, Alvaro, “Economía minera e historia económica hispana-americana,” in Tres ensayos sobre economia minera hispano-americana (Santiago, 1966), p. 37.Google Scholar

10 Iwao, Seiichi, “Japanese Gold and Silver in the World History,” in International Symposium on History of Eastern and Western Cultural Contacts (Tokyo, 1959), p. 63.Google Scholar

11 Nef, “Silver Production,” p. 589; Vilar, Oro y moneda, pp. 235–36;Google ScholarHoszowski, Stanislaw, “Europe Centrale et Révolution des Prix,” Annales ESC, 16 (0506 1961), p. 453.Google Scholar

12 Vilar, Oro y moneda, p. 23. Recent evidence indicates that Spanish-American silver production did not decline, as previously thought, in the seventeenth century, although a falling percentage of government revenues flowed to Castile. TePaske, John J. and Klein, Herbert S., Past and Present, no. 90 (February 1981), pp. 116–35. Such evidence does not contradict this essay. One would not expect production to halt once super-profits were squeezed out in the New World any more than one would expect business volume to decline in Atlantic City casinos now that entry into the industry has eliminated economic profits. Profitability is the issue, not output.Google Scholar

13 Braudel, Fernand, The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II, vol. 1, trans. Reynolds, Sian (New York, 1972), p. 536.Google Scholar

14 Hauser, Henri, “The European Financial Crisis of 1559.” Journal of Economic and Business History, 2 (19291930), 244.Google Scholar

15 Parker, Geoffrey, “Spain, Her Enemies and the Revolt of the Netherlands 1559–1648,Past and Present, no. 49 (11 1970), p. 76.Google Scholar

16 Haring, Charles H., The Spanish Empire in America, 3rd ed. (New York, 1963), p. 278.Google Scholar

17 Castillo, Alvaro, “Dette flottante et dette consolidée en Espagne de 1557 à 1600,” Annales ESC (1963), p. 755.Google Scholar

18 Parker, “Spain, Her Enemies,” pp. 8485.Google Scholar

19 Ibid., p. 86.

20 Braudel, , The Mediterranean, vol. 1, p. 533.Google Scholar

21 Koenigsberger, Helmut G., “The Empire of Charles V in Europe,” in The New Cambridge Modern History, vol. 2 (Cambridge, 1958), pp. 275, 312.Google Scholar

22 Castillo, Alvaro, “Los juros de Castilla: Apogeo y fin de un instrumento de crédito,” Hispania, 23 (1963), p. 52.Google Scholar

23 Vilar, Oro y moneda, p. 203.Google Scholar

24 Parker, Geoffrey, “War and Economic Change: the Economic Costs of the Dutch Revolt,” in Spain and the Netherlands, 1559–1659: Ten Studies, ed. Parker, G. (Glasgow, 1979), p. 188.Google Scholar

25 Wilson, Charles H., “The Historical Study of Economic Growth and Decline in Early Modern History,” in The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. 5 (Cambridge, 1977), p. 29.Google Scholar “It is doubtful whether any state of the day could have borne a debt equivalent to between ten and fifteenyears' full revenue…” Parker, Geoffrey, “The Emergence of Modern Finance in Europe 1500–1730,” in The Fontana Economic History of Europe, vol. 2, ed. Cipolla, C. M. (Glasgow, 1974), p. 570.Google Scholar

26 Kamen, Henry, “The Decline of Spain: A Historical Myth?Past and Present, no. 81 (11 1978), p. 25.Google Scholar

27 Ibid. Others also emphasize late seventeenth-century Castilian problems, even going so far as to state that the “decline of Spain in the early seventeenth century never happened.” Gordon, Michael D., “The Decline of Spain,” Journal of Modern History, 47 (1975), p. 98.Google Scholar J. I. Israel attacks Gordon and Kamen for denying that Spain declined in the early seventeenth century. Israel locates abrupt decline in industry and agriculture in the traditional period 1595–1621. “Debate: The Decline of Spain: A Historical Myth,” Past and Present, no. 91 (May 1981), pp. 170–80. Kamen reiterates his view of underlying domestic weakness throughout Spain's sixteenth century in “A Rejoinder,” Past and Present, no. 91 (May 1981), pp. 181–85. The argument of this paper is consistent with either view.Google Scholar

28 Elliott, John H., “The Decline of Spain,” Past and Present, no. 20 (11 1961), p. 54.Google Scholar

29 Ibid., p. 62. The lack of a productive base within Spain is also stressed by Carande, Ramón, Carlos V y sus banqueros, vol. 1, 2nd ed. (Madrid, 1965), p. 340.Google Scholar

30 Oiler, Jorge Nadal, “La revolución de los precioso Espanoles en ci siglo XVI,” Hispania, 19 (1959), pp. 523–24.Google Scholar

31 Kamen, “The Decline of Spain: A Historical Myth?” pp. 35, 41.Google Scholar

32 Ibid., p. 34.

33 Pike, Ruth, “The Genoese in Seville and the Opening of the New World,” this JOURNAL, 22 (09 1962), 356.Google Scholar

34 Elliott, J. H., Imperial Spain 1469–1716, Pelican, ed. (Middlesex, 1975), p. 291.Google Scholar

35 Parker, “War and Economic Change,” p. 188.Google Scholar

36 Kamen, Henry, “The Decline of Castile: the Last Crisis,” Economic History Review, 17 (08 1964), 69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

37 North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert P., The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (Cambridge, 1973), p. 129.Google Scholar North and Thomas base their statement on pre-Philip II figures provided by Vives, Jaime Vicens, An Economic History of Spain (Princeton, 1969), p. 382:Google Scholar 267,000 ducats from the Castilian alcabala tax; 350,000–400,000 from the Indies; 4 million from the Low Countries. Compare these with figures typical of the late 1500s: 6.2 million ducats Castilian taxes; 1.6 million in papal concessions collected by the Crown; 2 million in American silver. (Elliott, Imperial Spain, p. 286).Google Scholar

38 Parker, “Spain, Her Enemies,” pp. 85, 89, 92.Google Scholar

39 Koenigsberger, Helmut G., “Western Europe and the Power of Spain,” in The New Cambridge Modern History, vol. 3 (Cambridge, 1968), p. 272.Google Scholar

40 Parker, “Spain, Her Enemies”, p. 75.Google Scholar

41 Flynn, Dennis O., “Spanish American Silver and Western Trade with the Orient,” Mediterranean V Conference: Papers and Proceedings (Bar flan, Israel, 08 1980).Google Scholar

42 Boxer, C. R., as quoted in Parker, “War and Economic Change”, p. 189.Google Scholar

43 Ibid., p. 188.

44 Kamen, “The Decline of Spain: A Historical Myth?” p. 46.Google Scholar