Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T17:25:59.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Exclusive Dealing and the Whiskey Trust, 1890–1895

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Werner Troesken
Affiliation:
Associate Professor of History and Economics, Department of History, University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh PA 15260. e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

This article uses the history of the Whiskey Trust to explore the competitive effects of vertical restraints such as exclusive dealing. The Whiskey Trust distilled alcoholic spirits and bribed distributors not to carry competing brands of spirits. For the Whiskey Trust, exclusive dealing was an ineffective predatory strategy. Despite the trust's market dominance and manifold predatory strategies, it failed to preempt entry. The trust failed, in part, because its rivals could vertically integrate at low cost. Competition disciplined the trust more effectively than did numerous antitrust suits.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Allen, Bruce T.Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure: The Case of Cement and Concrete.” Journal of Law and Economics 21, no. 1 (1971): 251–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bittlingmayer, George. “The Stock Market and Early Antitrust Enforcement.” Journal of Law and Economics 34, no. 1, part 1 (1993): 132.Google Scholar
Bork, Robert H.The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself. New York: The Free Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred D.The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge: Hardvard University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chicago Tribune, various issues, 18871898.Google Scholar
Clay, Karen, and Hamilton, Gillian. “The Creation of a Trust: American Tobacco from Formation to Dissolution.” Unpublished paper. Department of Economics. University of Toronto, 1997.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. “Barriers to Entry.” American Economic Review 72, no. 1 (1982): 4757.Google Scholar
DiLorenzo, Thomas J.The Origins of Antitrust: An Interest-Group Perspective.” International Review of Law and Economics 5, no. 2 (1985): 7390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiLorenzo, Thomas J., and High, Jack C.. “Antitrust and Competition, Historically Considered.” Economic Inquiry 26, no. 3 (1988): 423–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
East, Ernest E.The Distillers and Cattle Feeders,' Trust, 1887–1895.” Journal of the State Historical Society of the State of Illinois 47, no. 2 (1958): 101–24.Google Scholar
Elzinga, Kenneth G.Predatory Pricing: The Case of the Gunpowder Trust.” Journal of Law and Economics 13, no. 1 (1970): 223–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Claudia, Goldin, and Libecap, Gary, eds. The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to Political Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Grandy, Christopher. “Original Intent and the Sherman Antitrust Act: A Re-examination of the Consumer-Welfare Hypothesis.” this JOURNAL 53, no. 2 (1993): 359–76.Google Scholar
Granitz, Elizabeth and Klein, Benjamin. “Monopolization by ‘Raising Rivals’ Costs': The Standard Oil Case.” Journal of Law and Economics 34, no. 1 (1996): 148.Google Scholar
High, Jack C., and Coppin, Clayton A.. “Wiley and the Whiskey Industry: Strategic Behavior in the Passage of the Pure Food Act.” Business History Review 62, no. 2 (1988): 286309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, John A.Structural Change in American Manufacturing, 1850–1890.” this JOURNAL 43, no. 3 (1983): 433–59.Google Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N., and Parkman, Allen M.. “Spatial Competition and Vertical Integration: Cement and Concrete Revisited: Comment.” American Economic Review 77, no. 3 (1987): 750–53.Google Scholar
Kovaleff, Theodore P., ed. The Antitrust Impulse: An Economic, Legal and Historical Analysis, Volumes 1 and 2. New York and London: Columbia University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Krattenmaker, Thomas G. and Salop, Steven C.. “Competition and Cooperation in the Market for Exclusionary Rights.” American Economic Review 76, no. 1 (1986): 109–13.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.The Great Merger Movement in American Business, 1895–1904. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libecap, Gary D.The Rise of the Chicago Packers and the Origins of Meat Inspection and Antitrust.” Economic Inquiry 39, no. 2 (1992): 242–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopatka, John E., and Godek, Paul E.. “Another Look at Alcoa: Raising Rivals' Costs Does Not Improve the View.” Journal of Law and Economics 35, no. 2 (1992): 311–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marvel, Howard. “Exclusive Dealing.” Journal of Law and Economics 25, no. 1 (1982): 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masten, Scott E., and Snyder, Edward A.. “United States v. United Shoe Machinery Corporation: On the Merits.” Journal of Law and Economics 34, no. 1 part 1 (1993): 3370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Mathewson G., and Winter, Ralph A.. “The Competitive Effects of Vertical Agreements: Comment.” American Economic Review 77, no. 5 (1987): 1057–62.Google Scholar
McBride, Mark E.Spatial Competition and Vertical Integration; Cement and Concrete Revisited.” American Economic Review 43, no. 4 (1983): 1011–22.Google Scholar
McCraw, Thomas K.Regulation in Perspective: Historical Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
New York Times, various issues, 18871898.Google Scholar
Pindyck, Robert S., and Rubinfeld, Daniel L.. Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts. New York: McGraw Hill, 3rd Edition, 1991.Google Scholar
Porter, Robert H.A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886.” Bell Journal of Economics 14, no. 3 (1983): 301–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A.Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Salop, Steven C., and Scheffman, David T.. “Raising Rivals' Costs.” American Economic Review 73, no. 1 (1983): 267–71.Google Scholar
Sass, Tim R., and Saurman, David S.. “Mandated Exclusive Territories and Economic Efficiency: An Empirical Analysis of the Malt Beverage Industry.” Journal of Law and Economics 34, no. 1 part 1 (1993): 153–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J.The Economic Effects of the Antitrust Laws.” Journal of Law and Economics 9, no. 2 (1966): 225–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telser, Lester. “Cutthroat Competition and the Long Purse.” Journal of Law and Economics 9, no. 2 (1966): 259–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telser, Lester. A Theory of Efficient Cooperation and Competition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Troesken, Werner. “Antitrust Enforcement before the Sherman Act: The Break-Up of the Chicago Gas Trust Company.” Explorations in Economic History 32, no. 1 (1995):109-36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. House. Whiskey Trust Investigation, 52nd Cong., 2d sess., 1893, H. Rept. No. 2601.Google Scholar
U.S. House. Industrial Commission Reports, Vol. 1, Trusts. 56th Cong., 1st sess., 18891900, H. Doc. Vol. 93, No. 476, Pt. 1.Google Scholar
Zerbe, Richard. “The American Sugar Refining Company, 1887–1914: The Story of a Monopoly.” Journal of Law and Economics 12, no. 2 (1969): 355–79.Google Scholar