Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T06:17:36.424Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Development of Nazi Monetary Policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 February 2011

Martin Wolfe
Affiliation:
University of Pennsylvania

Extract

The Nazis dealt rather cautiously with the German monetary system during die first two years of dieir regime. Hitler was particularly sensitive to questions of “confidence,” and was glad to saddle Schacht with the responsibility of keeping die monetary system from blowing up in die face of die new government. But by the end of 1934, diere were signs that the Nazis were beginning to take Germany out of die stream of what Goering contemptuously called “the so-called free play of economic forces.”

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1955

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Gumpert, Julius, “Wehrwirtschaftslehre,” Finanzarchiv, VI (1938), 514–27Google Scholar; Simpson, Amos, The Position of Hjalmar Schacht in a Changing Germany, 1923-1939, (University of California dissertation, 1954), pp. 153–73Google Scholar.

2 Poole, Kenyon E., German Financial Policies, 1932-1939 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1939), pp. 16-19, 2629. Credit for inventing this technique belongs to the Von Schleicher regime; the work creation bill was unveiled a few days before the Nazis came to powerGoogle Scholar.

3 A.-I. , Berndt, debt Mir Vicr Jahrc Zeif! (2d ed.; Munich: N.S.D.A.P. Press, 1937), p. 104Google Scholar.

4 The “guns not butter” slogan was a morale item and not an indication of a serious tightening of belts. On the contrary, by 1938 per capita intake of consumer goods was probably at, or near, the 1928 prosperity level. Of course the expansion of heavy industry far outstripped that of consumer goods industry.—Klein, Burton, “Germany's Preparation for War: A Reexamination,American Economic Review, XXXVIII (March 1948), p. 63Google Scholar.

5 Moeller, Hero, “Wandlung der Geldtheorie,” finanzarchiv, VI (1938), 7Google Scholar.

6 Singer, H. W., “The German War Economy in the Light of German Economic Periodicals—IX,” Economic Journal, June-September 1943, p. 253Google Scholar.

7 Guillebaud, C. W., The Economic Recovery of Germany (London: Macmillan and Co., 1939). PP- 9396Google Scholar.

8 Another necessary element, of course, was exchange control, which made the private investor “helpless to choose or flee.”—Balogh, Thomas, “The National Economy of Germany,” Economic Journal, September 1938, p. 491Google Scholar.

9 Lurié, Samuel, Private Investment in a Controlled Economy: Germany, 1933-1939 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1947), pp. 47-54, 164, 218Google Scholar.

10 Toward the end of the war about 70 per cent of the assets of the German banking system were in the form of government securities, compared to 20 per cent before 1933.— The Economist, July 1, 1944, p. 19Google Scholar.

11 “Die ‘geräuschlose’ Finanzierung,” Die Wirtschajtskurve, May 1941, pp. 153–54Google Scholar.

12 Stucken, Rudolf, Deutsche Geld- und Kreidtpolitik, 1914 bis 1933 (id ed.; Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr, 1953), p. 164Google Scholar.

13 Nathan, Otto, Nazi War Finance and Banking (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1944), pp. 27ftGoogle Scholar.

14 Lindholm, Richard W., “German Finance in World War II,” American Economic Review, XXXVII (March 1947), p. 133Google Scholar.

15 Ellis, Howard S., Exchange Control in Central Europe (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1941), pp. 231–32Google Scholar.

16 Arnoult, Pierre, Let Finances de la France et I'occupation allemande (1940-1944) (Paris: Presses Universitaires, 1951), chs. 1 and 3Google Scholar.