Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-04T10:03:18.008Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Alternative Institutional Approach to Rules, Organizations, and Development

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 May 2022

John Joseph Wallis*
Affiliation:
Professor, Department of Economics, University of Maryland, 3114 Tydings Hall, 7343 Preinkert Dr., College Park, MD 20742. E-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

In the middle of the nineteenth century, a handful of societies began creating and enforcing impersonal rules, rules that treat everyone the same, on a broad scale. The existing institutional literatures, while appreciating the importance of impersonal rules for the rule of law, have not understood how they contribute to economic and political development through rules that are enforced but not followed: default rules. The conceptual importance of impersonal default rules is drawn out and then applied to better understand both economic and political development in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.

Type
Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The seeds for this paper were planted many years ago in conversations with Doug North and Barry Weingast, to whom I am always grateful. Steve Webb helped those ideas mature. The specifics of this paper blossomed in conversations with Peter Murrell, Felipe Safie, Christopher Morris, and Brian Kogelman, particularly the day that Peter and Felipe pointed out that my ideas about political parties were much more important than I recognized. Doug Allen, Eric Alston, Lee Alston, Price Fishback, Ron Harris, Sumner LaCroix, Naomi Lamoreaux, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal gave me great comments on earlier drafts, as did the editors, Dan Bogart and Eric Hilt. All of these people and their work have shaped my ideas. Jean-Laurent bears particular responsibility for challenging me to distinguish my ideas on institutions from the existing literature, which this paper starts to do. Naomi and I have been working on a long, slow, steady project on the history of American democracy, which has framed my thinking for the last decade. Thank you all. The mistakes are, obviously, mine.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty. New York: Penguin Press, 2019.Google Scholar
Alston, Eric, Alston, Lee J., Mueller, Bernardo, and Nonnemacher, Tomas. Institutional and Organizational Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Ian, and Gertner, Robert. “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules.Yale Law Journal 99, no. 1 (1989): 87130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailyn, Bernard. The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Bednar, Jeanna. “Robust Institutional Design: What Makes Some Institutions More Adaptable and Resilient to Changes in Their Environment than Others?” In Complexity and Evolution: Toward a New Synthesis for Economics, edited by David, S. Wilson and Kirman, Alan. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2016.Google Scholar
Bednar, Jenna, and Page, Scott E.. “Can Game(s) Theory Explain Culture? The Emergence of Cultural Behavior within Multiple Games.Rationality and Society 19, no. 1 (2007): 6597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Sheri. Democracy and Dictatorship in Europe: From the Ancien Régime to the Present Day. New York: Oxford University Press, 2019.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa E.Merchant Law in a Merchant Court: Rethinking the Code’s Search for Immanent Business Norms.University of Pennsylvania Law Review 144, no. 5 (1996): 1765–821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa E.Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation Through Rules, Norms, and Institutions.Michigan Law Review 99, no. 7 (2001): 1724–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa E.Beyond Relational Contracts: Social Capital and Network Governance in Procurement Contracts.Journal of Legal Analysis 7, no. 2 (2015): 561621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, Stephen, and Joseph Wallis, John. “Growing, Shrinking, and Long Run Economic Performance: Historical Perspectives on Economic Development.” NBER Working Paper No. w23343, Cambridge, MA and CEPR Discussion Paper No. 11973, Washington, DC, April 2017.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L.Rational Actors, Equilibrium, and Social Institutions.” In Explaining Social Institutions, edited by Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai, 5794. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political Parties in Victorian England. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, Robert A., ed. Political Opposition in Western Democracies. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966a.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A.Preface.” In Political Opposition in Western Democracies, edited by Robert, A. Dahl, xixix. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966b.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W.. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.American Sociological Review 48, no. 2 (1983): 147–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. The Rules of Sociological Method. Edited with an introduction by Steven Lukes. Translated by Halle, W. D.. New York: Free Press, 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, Maurice. Political Parties. New York: Science Press, 1951/1954.Google Scholar
Feenstra, Robert C., Inklaar, Robert, and Timmer, Marcel P.. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.American Economic Review 105, no. 10 (2015): 3150–82. Available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert, and Roberts, John, eds. The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemans, Hein, Skrede Gleditsch, Kristian, and Chiozza, Giacomo. “Introducing Archigos: A Dataset of Political Leaders.Journal of Peace Research 46, no. 2 (2009): 269–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Marrk. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 3 (1985): 481–510. Organizational Institutionalism, 2nd edition. Washington, DC: Sage, 2017.Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannah, Leslie. “A Global Corporate Census: Publicly Traded and Close Companies in 1910.Economic History Review 68, no. 2 (2015): 548–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, H. L. A. The Concept of Law, 3rd edition. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1961/1994/2012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph. The Secret of Our Success: How Culture Is Driving Human Evolution, Domesticating Our Species, and Making Us Smarter. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph. The WIERDest People in the World: How the West Became Psychologically Peculiar and Particularly Prosperous. New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux, 2020.Google Scholar
Hicken, Allen. Building Party Systems in Developing Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoppit, Julian. Britain’s Political Economies: Parliament and Economic Life, 1660–1800. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968/2006.Google Scholar
Korobkin, Russell. “Status Quo Bias and Contract Default Rules.” Cornell Law Review 83, no. 3 (1997–1998): 608–87.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R., and Wallis, John Joseph, eds. Organizations, Civil Society, and the Roots of Development. Chicago: NBER/University of Chicago Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.. “Making Rules Impersonal.” Manuscript, paper presented at the EHA meetings in Atlanta, 2019.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.. “Economic Crisis, General Laws, and the Mid-Nineteenth-Century Transformation of American Political Economy.Journal of the Early Republic 41, no. 3 (2021): 403–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, David. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1969/2002.Google Scholar
Lipset, Seymour M., and Rokkan, Stein. “Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction.” In Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives, edited by Seymour, M. Lipset and Rokkan, Stein, 164. New York: The Free Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott, ed. Party Systems in Latin America: Institutionalization, Decay, and Collapse. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott, and Scully, Timothy R.. Building Democratic Institutions : Party Systems in Latin America. Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Meyer, John W., and Rowan, Brian. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony.American Journal of Sociology 83, no. 2 (1977): 340–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moreno-Luzón, Javier. “Political Clientelism, Elites, and Caciquismo in Restoration Spain (1875–1923).European History Quarterly 37, no. 3 (2007): 417–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C.Institutions and Economic Theory.American Economist 36, no. 1 (1992): 36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., Joseph Wallis, John, and Weingast, Barry R.. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Riedl, Rachel Beatty. Authoritarian Origins of Democratic Party Systems in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis. Colchester: ECPR Press, 1976/2005.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. Party Government. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, 1942/2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searle, John. The Construction of Social Reality. New York: The Free Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Searle, John. Making the Social World. New York: Oxford University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selznick, Philip. “Foundations of the Theory of Organization.” American Sociological Review 13, no. 1 (1948): 2535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selznick, Philip. Leadership in Administration. Evanston, IL: Harper & Row. Reprinted 1984, Berkeley: University of California Press, 1957.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A.Rational Choice Institutionalism.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, edited by Rhodes, R. A. W., Binder, Sarah, and Bert, A. Rockman, 2339. New York: Oxford University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. Coercion, Capital, and European States: 990–1992. Hoboken, NJ: Blackwell Publishing, 1993.Google Scholar
Wallis, John Joseph.The Concept of Systematic Corruption in American Economic and Political History.” In Corruption and Reform, edited by Edward, L. Glaeser and Goldin, Claudia, 2362. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallis, John Joseph. “Leviathan Denied: Rules, Organizations, and Governments.” Unpublished manuscript, 2022.Google Scholar
Ziblatt, Daniel. Conservative Parties and the Birth of Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar