Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-pwrkn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-10-01T17:18:51.068Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Roundtable on Rick Doner, Gregory Noble, and John Ravenhill, The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia

Review products

Roundtable on Rick Doner, Gregory Noble, and John Ravenhill, The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 March 2023

Roselyn Hsueh*
Affiliation:
Temple University, USA
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Book Review Roundtable
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the East Asia Institute

For scholars and practitioners of development, the perennial questions are the “to what extent, with what, and why” of state capacity. In their recent book, The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia, Richard F. Doner, Gregory W. Noble, and John Ravenhill (Reference Doner, Noble and Ravenhill2021) examine industrial upgrading in automotive sectors in seven Asian countries to answer these important questions. To understand the extent and scope of automotive industrialization, they distinguish between extensive versus intensive growth. The former represents assembly efforts coordinated largely by foreign direct investment (FDI). In contrast, intensive growth is measured by indigenous capacity to design whole vehicles and produce value-added components and parts. The authors contend that an interplay of constrained natural resource endowments, external threats, and domestic political pressures explains cross-national variation in institutional strength for industrial diffusion and learning.

DNR find that Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, and the Philippines have pursued extensive growth with relative success without attaining intensive growth. The knowledge and technological requirements for the assembly of completely knocked down kits (in partnership with foreign investors and foreign automakers) are high, but not nearly as high as those for design. In contrast, China, South Korea, and Taiwan are strong performers in intensive growth. China assembles domestically branded cars and component parts for export. In 2019 China ranked third in volume of components exports, followed by Korea at number six. Taiwan placed twenty-second, behind Thailand at 13. Korea ranked eighth, followed by China at number nine in the production of passenger cars. Thailand (18) and Indonesia (22) produced more cars together domestically than Taiwan (30). But Taiwan's competitive advantage lies in value-added automotive components and parts, an indicator of intensive growth.

By these measures, China outperforms all of its Asian neighbors except Korea in an integrated auto industry. A closer look reveals that China's intensive growth, similar to Taiwan's, varies by assembly versus components and parts. What are the cross-national and within country differences in industrial capacity that may not be fully captured by the ordinal and binary differentiation between intensive versus extensive growth? Importantly, in the context of external and internal pressures, what factors motivate the state's choices of sectors and subsectors to mobilize limited state capacity and resources, and the types of institutions that emerge to tackle distinct technological challenges? To answer these questions, I introduce a unified theoretical framework (in Hsueh Reference Hsueh2022) that identifies the multidimensional impacts of sectors.

The Strategic Value Framework reconceptualizes existing developmental state and liberal models of development and advances extant scholarship by identifying objective and intersubjective factors at play at the sectoral level of analysis. To begin with, extending Doner, Ritchie, and Slater (Reference Doner, Ritchie and Slater2005), Stubbs (Reference Stubbs1999), and other scholars, and building on Hsueh (Reference Hsueh2011), Hsueh (Reference Hsueh2022) contends that how state elites perceive the strategic value of sectors in response to economic and political pressures shapes the state goals and methods driving the mobilization of limited state capacity and resources. Beyond that, sectoral structures and organization of institutions determine the details of the actual methods employed. Drawing from such scholars as Kitschelt (Reference Kitschelt1991) and Shafer (Reference Shafer1994), I conceptualize a sector's technological complexity as varying by not just degree but also type (e.g., complex interactive versus linear technology; low versus high asset specificity; and local versus global learning). Political interests and power asymmetries as a function of the existing organization of institutions at the sector level further constrain the methods of the state (Campbell and Lindberg Reference Campbell and Lindberg1990; Hollingsworth, Schmitter, and Streeck Reference Hollingsworth, Schmitter and Streeck1994).

The Strategic Value Framework identifies ideational, structural, and institutional dimensions of sectors and the extent and scope of the role of the state in development in the context of global economic integration. Contrary to conventional wisdom that China has pursued a similar model of development as the East Asian developmental state, Hsueh (Reference Hsueh2011) demonstrates that China has departed from the globalization and industrialization strategies pursued by South Korea and Taiwan. External security threats, internal state–society relations, and ready markets in the allied west during the Cold War influenced the then-autocratic regimes of East Asia to invest initially in import substitution policies and then later export-oriented industrialization by restricting FDI (Haggard and Cheng Reference Haggard, Cheng and Deyo1987; Haggard Reference Haggard1990).

The Chinese state, in contrast, during the waning days of the Cold War and integrating into the global economy at the height of neoliberalism, has courted FDI eager to tap into Chinese markets with deliberately calibrated rules on market entry, business scope, investment level, and property rights arrangements, which varied by sector. In parallel, in the decades following the 1978 Open Door policy, the Chinese government has introduced market competition and decentralized to local authorities economic decision-making in industries not directly connected to national security imperatives but important for regional development. In the decentralized context of non-strategic sectors, joint ventures between provisional and municipal governments, private entrepreneurs, and foreign automakers have enabled state sponsored Chinese automakers to master the assembly and design of whole vehicles (Hsueh Reference Hsueh2011).

Structured comparative sectoral analysis further reveals that China has attained less indigenous capacity in value-added automotive components and parts marked by complex interactive technology and local learning sustainable primarily via a public research and development (R&D) infrastructure. Such institutions are less well developed in the decentralized sectors of the Chinese economy perceived less strategic by the central state due to their lower contribution to the national technology base and application for national security. Conversely, in the dual-use sectors perceived strategic for the country's authoritarian legitimacy and rule, such as telecommunications services and manufacturing, centralized state planning and R&D, in addition to the intentional utilization of FDI and public-private partnerships, are the institutional foundations of indigenous development in China. Thus are the centralized market coordination and state-owned and state-sponsored companies dominant in next generation (5G) network technologies and Internet commerce and other platform industries.

Examining the multidimensional impacts of sectors through historical process tracing from sectoral origins and comparing variation across countries and sectors within them, Hsueh (Reference Hsueh2022) uncovers the ways in which dominant sectoral patterns of market governance in India and Russia vary fundamentally from China. The emergent national configurations of sectoral models of globalization and development challenge dominant perspectives today on the impacts of open economy politics and subnational geography. Rather, extending DNR's seminal scholarship, the Strategic Value Framework identifies objective and intersubjective dimensions of sectors and demonstrates the mechanisms which connect the intersecting relationship between state goals and methods and national and intracountry sectoral variation in development. Findings suggest these are the institutional foundations of capitalism in the contemporary politics of the Global South.

References

Campbell, John L., and Lindberg, Leon N.. 1990. “Property Rights and the Organization of Economic Activity by the State.” American Sociological Review 55 (5): 634647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doner, Richard F., Noble, Gregory W., and Ravenhill, John. 2021. The Political Economy of Automotive Industrialization in East Asia. New York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doner, Richard F., Ritchie, Bryan, and Slater, Dan. 2005. “Systemic Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative Perspective.” International Organization 59 (2): 327361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, Stephan. 1990. Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Cheng, Tun-jen. 1987. “State and Foreign Capital in the East Asian NICs.” In The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, edited by Deyo, Frederic. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hollingsworth, J. Rogers, Schmitter, Philippe C., and Streeck, Wolfgang. 1994. Governing Capitalist Economies: Performance and Control of Economic Sectors. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hsueh, Roselyn. 2011. China's Regulatory State: A New Strategy for Globalization. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsueh, Roselyn. 2022. Micro-institutional Foundations of Capitalism: Sectoral Pathways to Globalization in China, India, and Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kitschelt, Herbert. 1991. “Industrial Governance Structures, Innovation Strategies, and the Case of Japan: Sectoral or Cross-National Comparative Analysis?” International Organization 45 (4): 453493.Google Scholar
Shafer, Michael. 1994. Winners and Losers: How Sectors Shape the Developmental Prospects of States. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Stubbs, Richard. 1999. “War and Economic Development: Export-Oriented Industrialization in East and Southeast Asia.” Comparative Politics 31: 337–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar