Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-lvwk9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-10-06T09:53:12.813Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Test of Hirschman’s Hiding Hand Principle in World Bank-Financed Hydropower Projects

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2023

Godwin Olasehinde-Williams*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Istanbul Ticaret University, Istanbul, Turkey
Glenn P. Jenkins
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Queen’s University, Kingston, ON, Canada
*
Corresponding author: Godwin Olasehinde-Williams; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study is an attempt to determine whether the need to get hydropower project appraisals perfectly right during the pre-construction phase, so as to prevent significant overruns along with benefit shortfalls, should supersede the need to deliver projects at the earliest possible time so as to meet the needs of the people. To achieve the study objective, we test whether the Hiding Hand principle is predominantly benevolent or malevolent. We argue that if the Hiding Hand is benevolent, then project stakeholders are better off focusing on the quick delivery of power projects; however, if it is malevolent, then more attention should be given to perfecting project appraisals. It transpires from the statistical analysis that the Benevolent Hiding Hand dominates the Malevolent Hiding Hand in the selected World Bank-financed hydropower projects (33% v. 21%), and that ultimately, 75% of the projects were even more successful than anticipated—while 25% of the projects failed. Our findings further show that while a total loss of 2.335 billion USD in the sampled dams was caused by the Malevolent Hiding Hand, 11.259 billion USD was gained as a result of the Benevolent Hiding Hand. The predominance of the Benevolent Hiding Hand justifies placing some weight on proceeding with hydropower projects that show significant promise even if all the implantation risks are not fully quantified at the appraisal stage, especially in developing countries.

Type
Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis

1. Introduction

Countries, especially developing ones, are vulnerable to the effects of delay in the construction of infrastructural projects (Braeckman & Guthrie, Reference Braeckman and Guthrie2015). With regard to power infrastructure, these countries are often plagued by an inadequate electricity service coupled with continuously growing demand that worsens the situation. For instance, the lack of access to grid-connected electricity costs the African continent about 2% of its gross domestic product annually (Gil et al., Reference Gil, Stafford and Musonda2019). Consequently, an adequate, reliable power supply has a significantly high economic value. Yet, project financiers, especially in these developing countries, tend to be extremely cautious during the pre-construction phase when project appraisal is being carried out. Project financiers are often worried about the ability of project managers to identify, formulate, prepare, and carry out projects effectively such that cost and time overruns are minimized. The general sentiment is that most developing nations lack the required institutional capacity and manpower to effectively execute infrastructural projects (Rondinelli, Reference Rondinelli1976; Kacou et al., Reference Kacou, Ika and Munro2022). To avoid these challenges, project financiers, in an attempt to perfect project planning, apply a lot of caution during the pre-construction phase. This ultimately leads to project delays with vast socio-economic implications, especially for developing countries.

The question this study attempts to answer is whether the need to get project appraisal perfectly right during the pre-construction phase so as to prevent significant overruns and benefit shortfalls supersedes the need to deliver projects at the earliest possible time so as to meet the needs of the people. The objective may alternatively be interpreted as an attempt to determine whether placing some weight on proceeding with hydro-projects with significant promise is a good idea, even if all the implantation risks are not fully quantified at the appraisal stage. According to Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015), if it were possible to identify all the difficulties and costs associated with a project ab initio, then no project would ever be good enough for approval. The author thus suggests that it is preferable for project stakeholders not to know all the possible problems because of the need to get things started. If they knew all the details, they would not be bold enough to start the much-needed projects. The author argues that while decision makers tend to be over-optimistic about project benefits and costs, they also tend to underestimate their own problem-solving abilities during project implementation; this he called the principle of the Hiding Hand. The Hiding Hand principle has a unique way of making risk lovers out of risk averters, and once risky projects are embarked upon, unanticipated challenges that might arise during project implementation are dealt with through human ingenuity. Moreover, as project managers gain experience, they develop improved ability to appraise projects effectively. The Hiding Hand thus provides a transition mechanism through which project managers learn to undertake risky projects, and the faster the transition, the quicker the learning process (Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016). Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) views this principle of the Hiding Hand as a relatively general occurrence which cuts across project types and geographical locations.

As stated by Flyvbjerg and Sunstein (Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016), there are two explanations for the Hiding Hand. The first is the “pseudo-imitation” explanation, which suggests that project planners often present new projects either as perfect replicas of past successful projects or as requiring straightforward application of previously successfully employed techniques. This has been termed a one-size-fits-all approach (Shenhar & Dvir, Reference Shenhar and Dvir2007; Ika, Reference Ika2012; Ika & Hodgson, Reference Ika and Hodgson2014; Ika & Söderlund, Reference Ika and Söderlund2016). Consequently, project handlers underestimate the uniqueness of specific projects. The second explanation is labeled the “pseudo-comprehensive-program,” which attaches equal value to all aspects of a project, considers their interconnectedness, and treats the project as a piece of a larger program. This explanation is associated with the Hiding Hand because it tricks policymakers into assuming that experts know it all, causing all blame of project failure to be placed on failure to adhere to the instructions of experts rather than on the weaknesses of the advice given by experts. Thus, project planners are tricked into executing projects with difficulties that will only become visible over time.

Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) highlights the ingenuity displayed at the start of operations of the Karnaphuli Paper Mill in Bangladesh as an example of the principle of the Hiding Hand. At the time, 85% of the bamboo forests that were to serve as the source of paper pulp died. While this resulted in extra costs and unexpected difficulties, out of human creativity, alternative sources for paper pulp were found and the raw material base was diversified. According to Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015), if the project planners had known about the likelihood of this problem, the project would probably not have been approved, and the thousands of jobs created by the project would have been lost. With respect to hydropower projects, another example is the Chukha Hydel dam located in Bhutan. Due to additional engineering costs required to deal with unanticipated geological problems, the project suffered a severe real cost overrun to the tune of 159%. In spite of the huge overrun, the project still generated economic benefits in excess of its cost (Dhakal & Jenkins, Reference Dhakal and Jenkins2013; Jenkins et al., Reference Jenkins, Olasehinde-Williams and Baurzhan2022). Following the logic of Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015), if project planners suspected that such geological problems would occur, they most likely would not have approved the project. Consequently, the significant economic benefits attached to the dam would have been forgone. A related study by Ika and Feeny (Reference Ika and Feeny2022) reveals that approximately 60% of a sample of 2800 World Bank-financed projects suffered optimism bias and this lowered the likelihood of satisfactory project performance by 17–20%. The ratio of projects that eventually turned out as unsatisfactory (17–20%) to that of those that experienced optimism bias (60%) suggests to a degree that the Benevolent Hiding Hand exists in World Bank-financed projects. This is because at least 40% of projects that experienced optimism bias eventually ended up being satisfactory.

The principle of Hiding Hand, if true, has far-reaching implications for power projects, especially those being constructed in developing countries. For one, it means that decision makers can afford to prioritize the high economic value associated with the speedy delivery of power projects rather than focus on perfecting project appraisals. It is worthy of mention that this study is not in any way suggesting that the quality of project appraisals should be compromised. The objective is to discourage planners from completely discarding, out of extreme caution, projects with significant numbers of unknowns, particularly in cases where the economic value is potentially very high.

It has however been suggested that the principle of the Hiding Hand enjoys relatively wide acceptance only because of its political convenience and not because of its strength in describing human behavior (Flyvbjerg, Reference Flyvbjerg2016). Flyvbjerg and Sunstein (Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016) argue that the Hiding Hand of Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015), which is benevolent in nature, has an evil twin which they named the Malevolent Hiding Hand. The authors claim that the Malevolent Hiding Hand hides potential difficulties as well as limitations to human ingenuity from project stakeholders. Three reasons were put forward by Flyvbjerg and Sunstein (Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016) for the Malevolent Hiding Hand. The first is ignorance due to limited knowledge about potential difficulties (Hayek, Reference Hayek1945; Dorner, Reference Dorner1997). The second is politico-economic factor. Here, project supporters deliberately downplay potential problems and costs and intentionally exaggerate potential benefits and creativity so as to improve the chances of approval of particular projects (Wachs, Reference Wachs1990; Flyvbjerg et al., Reference Flyvbjerg, Holm and Buhl2002; Flyvbjerg, Reference Flyvbjerg2005). The third and the most important, according to Flyvbjerg and Sunstein (Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016), is the psychological factor. Proponents of the Malevolent Hiding Hand believe the psychological factor explanation on its own is sufficient reason for the occurrence of the Malevolent Hiding Hand (see Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2011). As opposed to the case with the Benevolent Hiding Hand, here, project managers tend to be over-optimistic in their assessment of potential difficulties and costs, as well as in their assessment of potential benefits and creativity. This unrealistic optimism at the pre-construction phase eventually results in significant cost overruns, time overruns, benefit underruns, and unexpected hardships along the way. This problem is referred to as the Planning Fallacy (Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016). Thus, the conclusion reached by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) is that ignorance is not beneficial under any circumstance, as it encourages the execution of bad projects that should not have been approved for implementation. It therefore goes without saying that if the Malevolent Hiding Hand is the more prevalent twin, prioritizing the speedy delivery of power projects at the expense of perfecting project appraisals may be counterproductive.

Despite the fact that support for both the Benevolent and the Malevolent Hiding Hand principles exists (Picciotto, Reference Picciotto, Rodwin and Schön1994b; Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2015; Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016), empirical evidence confirming either of the two as the most realistic explanation for how projects work is still limited in extant literature. This study thus contributes to the body of knowledge by empirically examining whether the Hiding Hand is benevolent or malevolent in hydropower projects financed by the World Bank. The rest of this study is structured in the following manner: Section 2 is the literature review, Section 3 describes the data used for statistical analysis, Section 4 describes the methodological approach followed, and the last section is the conclusion.

2. Literature review

2.1. The Benevolent Hiding Hand

Ika (Reference Ika2018) summarizes the Benevolent Hiding Hand from Hirschman’s perspective as the ability of project managers to see projects through to the end in spite of problems, difficulties, challenges, or obstacles encountered along the way. As reported by Alacevich (Reference Alacevich and Hirschman2015), Hirschman’s interviews with agrarian officers revealed that it was common to underestimate potential problems as well as problem-solving abilities. Singer (Reference Singer1969), in a similar manner, states that there is always a tendency to underestimate costs, overestimate benefits, and ignore potential difficulties when starting a project. Overall, the Benevolent Hiding Hand is seen as a form of invisible hand that beneficially hides difficulties from project managers (Alacevich, Reference Alacevich and Hirschman2015), in which the success of projects evolves from near misses (Gladwell, Reference Gladwell2013) or a process of stumbling into success (Adelman, Reference Adelman2013; Ika & Söderlund, Reference Ika and Söderlund2016, p. 937). According to Sunstein (Reference Sunstein2015), the Hiding Hand has the ability to lead planners to the achievement of outcomes as good as or even better than what was originally intended when such projects would have probably been discarded if the obstacles that would be encountered had been accurately identified ab initio. The Beneficial Hiding Hand therefore suggests that the lack of foresight often serves as a blessing in disguise when there is uncertainty (Picciotto, Reference Picciotto2015). Adelman (Reference Adelman2013) thus posits that by the acknowledgement of the existence of the Benevolent Hiding Hand, risk averters could be probed to take on more risks.

Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967) further explains that the underestimation of creativity in the face of difficulties is even more pronounced in developing countries due to lack of sufficient confidence in creativity. The Benevolent Hiding Hand was identified in a number of development projects such as the livestock and pasture project in Uruguay, the San Lorenzo irrigation project in Peru, and the Karnaphuli Paper Mill project. The Hoosac Tunnel was cited by Ika (Reference Ika2018) as an example of projects that would probably have been discarded if the planners had known the true extent of problems that lay ahead. Other examples of projects that exhibited the Benevolent Hiding Hand during construction include the Fort Taurus project (see Shenhar & Dvir, Reference Shenhar and Dvir2007), the Rideau Canal project (see Ika & Söderlund, Reference Ika and Söderlund2016), and the Sydney Opera House project (see Flyvbjerg and Sunstein Reference Flyvbjerg2016). According to Picciotto (Reference Picciotto1994a), the Hiding Hand principle lends credence to the daily experiences of project officers. The author observes that the conclusions reached by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) have become mainstream and can be regarded as classic.

2.2. The Malevolent Hiding Hand/Planning Fallacy

It has been suggested that the optimistic nature of Hirschman’s claim that human ingenuity always succeeds in solving unanticipated problems is simply a product of his personal life experiences; his bias towards hope, rather than empirical evidence, is therefore the foundation of the claims made in his scholarly work (Offe, Reference Offe2013). Gasper (Reference Gasper1986) disagrees with the Benevolent Hiding Hand by claiming that at best, it only occurs in special cases and is therefore not the norm. Cracknell (Reference Cracknell1984) also questions the reliability of the Benevolent Hiding Hand by stating that it does not align with the experiences of the Overseas Development Office of the United Kingdom. Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) argues that the Benevolent Hiding Hand is only popular because of its political convenience rather than its ability to describe human behavior. There are also claims that the principle of the Benevolent Hiding Hand is a deceptive one because it pushes people to engage in activities they ordinarily would not have involved themselves in, and project promoters are known to take advantage of this (Adelman, Reference Adelman2013; Ika & Söderlund, Reference Ika and Söderlund2016). Another fundamental criticism of Hirschman’s work is on methodological grounds. The very limited sample size of 11 out of 300 projects considered in his analysis has been questioned for not being representative enough; the case study approach and the qualitative analysis preferred in his studies are all regarded as methodological limitations to his work (Adelman, Reference Adelman2013; Flyvbjerg, Reference Flyvbjerg2016; Ika & Söderlund, Reference Ika and Söderlund2016).

The existence of projects which the Benevolent Hiding Hand failed to rescue are well-documented (Hirschman, Reference Hirschman2015; Ika, Reference Ika2018). In such cases, underestimated creativity was not enough to cover underestimated challenges. In cases such as these, the Malevolent Hiding Hand or the Planning Fallacy, which is regarded as the evil twin of Hirschman’s Benevolent Hiding Hand, is said to be at play (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2015; Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016). The Malevolent Hiding Hand suggests that the creative ability talked about by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) either does not exist, occurs too late to be effective, or is not sufficient to deal with the challenges experienced. As explained by Flyvbjerg and Sunstein (Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016), while the Benevolent Hiding Hand is characterized by an optimistic underestimation of possible difficulties as well as a pessimistic underestimation of problem-solving capabilities, the Malevolent Hiding Hand is instead characterized by both an optimistic underestimation of possible difficulties and an optimistic overestimation of problem-solving capabilities. It is assumed that it is this double optimism that eventually results in project failures (Ika, Reference Ika2018). The Malevolent Hiding Hand has been identified in various forms in literature. For instance, Streeten (Reference Streeten, Meier and Seers1984) discusses it from the perspective of the principle of a hiding fist. Picciotto (Reference Picciotto, Rodwin and Schön1994b) suggests the existence of a second kind of Hiding Hand which leads to failure of projects. Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2009) identifies the presence of a Malevolent Hiding Hand that is driven by ignorance, power, and psychology. Kahneman (Reference Kahneman2011) aligns with the existence of the Malevolent Hiding Hand that could solely be explained by psychological factors.

More recently, behavioral sciences have shown that people tend to be overly optimistic when managing projects; this is termed the Planning Fallacy caused by optimism bias (Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016). This has been established as another means of viewing the Malevolent Hiding Hand as it reflects the blindness to possible challenges often caused by unrealistic optimism (Flyvbjerg & Sunstein, Reference Flyvbjerg and Sunstein2016). The Malevolent Hiding Hand and the Planning Fallacy are therefore often used interchangeably. The Planning Fallacy is however not without its own criticisms. For instance, the absence of sufficient empirical backing for its existence has been pointed out (Love & Ahiaga-Dagbui, Reference Love and Ahiaga-Dagbui2018). It has also been questioned on methodological grounds as the data used in establishing the Planning Fallacy by Flyvbjerg et al. (Reference Flyvbjerg, Holm and Buhl2002) were cherry-picked (Love & Ahiaga-Dagbui, Reference Love and Ahiaga-Dagbui2018). Love et al. (Reference Love, Ika and Ahiaga-Dagbui2019) argue against the Planning Fallacy by pointing out that projects generally suffer from optimism as well as pessimism biases.

2.3. Is the Hiding Hand benevolent or malevolent?

The question a handful of researchers have so far attempted to answer is whether the Hiding Hand is benevolent or malevolent. A major criticism of Hirschman’s work is his inability to empirically substantiate his claims, especially with regard to which was the more prevalent of the two Hiding Hands (Krugman, Reference Krugman1994). To the best of the authors’ knowledge, only two papers have so far attempted to empirically test the Hiding Hand principle. The study by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) is the first attempt to statistically test the Hiding Hand principle. The study is conducted on a sample of 2062 infrastructural projects constructed between 1927 and 2013. The conclusion reached by this study is that the principle of the Benevolent Hiding Hand as described by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) does not exist, and as a matter of fact, its opposite, the Malevolent Hiding Hand, is what is typically at play. The study by Ika (Reference Ika2018), written as a rejoinder to Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016), is the second attempt made to empirically test the Hiding Hand principle. The study considers a sample of 161 World Bank-financed projects across the world and employs a project management approach in which project management performance is compared with deliverable performance. The key finding of the study is that contrary to the conclusion reached by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016), the Benevolent Hiding Hand is more common than the Malevolent Hiding Hand.

3. Data

The hydropower projects financed by the World Bank from 1975 to 2015 were originally selected for this study. However, multipurpose and pumped storage dams were dropped from the sample because of the high degree of complexity required in the determination of their benefits. Thus, the sample size was reduced to 57 World Bank-financed hydropower projects. Moreover, information needed to calculate the ex-ante and ex-post economic net present values (NPVs) were available for only 43 out of these 57 projects. This analysis therefore considers the experience of these 43 World Bank-financed hydro dam projects completed between 1977 and 2015 for which both ex-ante and ex-post evaluation information is available. All the projects as well as their specifications are listed in Table A1 of the Appendix. For each of these projects, cost overruns and benefit overruns are estimated. Geographically, 8 of the projects are located in Sub-Saharan Africa, 12 of the projects are sited in Latin America and the Caribbean, 3 can be found in South Asia, 14 are in East Asia and the Pacific, while 6 are in Europe and Central Asia. As shown in Table 1, 23 of the projects suffered significant cost overruns, while 19 experienced significant benefit overruns. Significant overrun refers to cases where overruns exceed 10% of pre-construction estimates.

Table 1. Higher than estimated costs.

Note: (1) P*, P-value of the test with null hypothesis that benefit overrun is larger than cost overrun, using Welch’s test. (2) corr, correlation; CO, cost overrun; PSD, project start date.

To determine the size of each project’s real cost overrun, the estimated nominal and real costs as well as the actual nominal and real costs are first calculated. The estimated nominal costs are extracted from the Staff Appraisal Reports (SARs) and Implementation and Completion Reports (ICRs) made available by the World Bank for each of the projects. Following Bacon and Besant-Jones (Reference Bacon and Besant-Jones1998), Awojobi and Jenkins (Reference Awojobi and Jenkins2015), and Baurzhan et al. (Reference Baurzhan, Jenkins and Olasehinde-Williams2021), the estimated real cost is taken as the difference between the estimated nominal cost and the amount set aside as price contingency. The actual nominal costs are extracted from the ICRs of the World Bank, while the actual real costs are the deflated actual nominal costs. The procedure for extracting the actual real costs from the actual nominal costs is as follows. To begin with, the actual nominal cost is spread across the duration of the project construction in the following manner:

(1) $$ {\mathrm{Y}}_{\mathrm{i}}=\frac{1}{2+\mathrm{p}}\left[\left(\mathrm{s}+1\right){\left(\frac{\mathrm{i}}{\mathrm{I}}\right)}^{\mathrm{s}}\left(\mathrm{p}+\unicode{x03C0} \mathrm{sin}\left(\unicode{x03C0} {\left(\frac{\mathrm{i}}{\mathrm{I}}\right)}^{\mathrm{s}+1}\right)\right)\right] $$

where $ {Y}_i $ refers to the share of project capital expenditure apportioned to the ith construction year. S is the cost lay-out curve skewness. P represents the flatness of the curve.

The foreign and domestic components of the annual nominal costs are then separated. The domestic currency value of the domestic component is obtained by converting from U.S. dollars to the local currency equivalent, using the prevalent exchange rate. The values obtained are further deflated using the prevalent domestic price index. The U.S. dollar equivalent is again recalculated for the project start year. On the other hand, the foreign component is deflated using the prevalent U.S. price index. The total actual real cost is computed as follows:

(2) $$ \mathrm{Actual}\ \mathrm{real}\ \mathrm{cost}={\sum}_{i=0}^T\frac{C_i^{n\$}\ast FCX}{I_{o,i}^F}+\frac{1}{E_0^m}{\sum}_{i=0}^T\frac{C_i^{n\$}\ast \left(1- FCX\right)\ast {E}_i^m}{I_{0,i}^D} $$

where $ {C}_i^{n\$} $ is the actual nominal cost, FCX is the foreign component, $ {I}^F $ is the foreign price index, and $ {I}^D $ is the domestic price index. Finally, cost overrun is computed as the ratio of actual real costs to the estimated real cost.

(3) $$ \mathrm{Cost}\ \mathrm{overrun}\;\left(\mathrm{CO}\right)=\frac{C_a}{C_e} $$

The benefits of the hydropower projects are calculated as the value of the avoided generation costs of fossil fuel-powered plants that would be required to be built and operated to supply the same volume of electricity as would be supplied by the hydro dam (Zuker & Jenkins, Reference Zuker and Jenkins1984; Baurzhan et al., Reference Baurzhan, Jenkins and Olasehinde-Williams2021; Jenkins et al., Reference Jenkins, Olasehinde-Williams and Baurzhan2022). These avoided costs were estimated based on the exact technologies and their degree of displacement specified by the World Bank at the time of appraisal. Although this approach does not capture all the economic benefits associated with hydropower projects, it is regarded as a good proxy for the benefits generated by hydroelectricity generation (Awojobi & Jenkins, Reference Awojobi and Jenkins2015). Other benefits associated with hydropower projects such as supply of potable water, irrigation, flood control, and carbon emissions reduction are excluded from our analysis due to the level of complexity required in their computation.

The estimated real economic benefits of the projects are reverse-engineered from the economic internal rate of returns reported in the SARs and ICRs provided by the World Bank for each of the projects. This is the same approach adopted by Jenkins et al. (Reference Jenkins, Olasehinde-Williams and Baurzhan2022) for calculating ex-ante real benefits of hydropower projects. The actual real economic benefits of the projects are calculated as described by Zuker and Jenkins (Reference Zuker and Jenkins1984) and Baurzhan et al. (Reference Baurzhan, Jenkins and Olasehinde-Williams2021). Standard thermal plants as specified by the World Bank system planner were identified the next best alternative to hydro dams for electricity supply. We therefore measure project benefits using the construction and operation costs of fossil fuel power plants capable of generating same amount of electricity. This occurs in two steps. First, cost savings from the avoided fixed annual capital cost of the alternative thermal plant are estimated. Second, the marginal running costs avoided by not operating the alternative thermal plant are also estimated.

The actual real benefits produced by each of the projects are calculated as follows:

(4) $$ \mathrm{Actual}\ \mathrm{real}\ \mathrm{benefit}={\sum}_{t=0}^{Z+40}\left\{\left|k\frac{r{\left(1+r\right)}^N}{{\left(1+r\right)}^N-1} IC\right.|+ VOM+\left({f}_t{p}_t\right){G}_t\right\}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-t} $$

where Z is the actual completion period. 40 years is the project life cycle. k is the capital cost. N is the economic life of the next best alternative source of electricity supply. IC is the installed capacity. VOM is the operating and maintenance cost. ft is the fuel requirement per time t. Pt is the fuel price per time t. G is the equivalent electricity supply from hydropower source per time t.

Benefit overruns are then measured as the ratio of actual to the estimated benefits.

(5) $$ \mathrm{Benefit}\ \mathrm{overrun}\;\left(\mathrm{BO}\right)=\frac{B_a}{B_e} $$

Finally, the economic NPV of each dam is calculated by taking the difference between the actual real project benefit and actual real project cost on a yearly basis. This difference is first spread over time as a stream of net economic benefits; it is then discounted to project start year. The economic NPVs obtained from these calculations are all expressed in the 2016 prices to ensure comparability.

4. Methodological approach and statistical findings

4.1. The Flyvbjerg ( Reference Flyvbjerg2016) approach

In an attempt to statistically test the Hiding Hand hypothesis, Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) came up with two claims that summarize the hypothesis based on his interpretation of the conclusions reached by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015). The first claim is that if the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle were true, then benefit overruns associated with the project would outweigh the cost overruns experienced during its construction. This would indicate that although project executors may have initially underestimated potential problems at the start of the project, they must have likewise underestimated skill sets available to them for solving these problems. Moreover, if the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle were true, then the average benefit overrun for the projects sampled would exceed the average cost overrun for the same set of projects. We may thus easily infer from this claim by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) that the Planning Fallacy or the Malevolent Hiding Hand principle would be more prevalent if benefit overruns were not as widespread as cost overruns and if average benefit overruns were smaller than average cost overruns.

The second claim made by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) is that if the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle were true, then we would expect to see a significant decline over time in cost risks and benefit risks. These reductions in risks should at least be noticeable in the medium to long run even if not visible in the short run. After all, lessons learnt over time should ordinarily lead to improvements in performance over time (Schön, Reference Schön1994; Flyvbjerg, Reference Flyvbjerg2016). The implication of this second claim is that if there is no visible decline (increase) in cost overruns (benefit overruns) over time, then the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle has no statistical support.

Table 1 reports the results obtained from testing the first claim. The results show that the average weighted/unweighted cost overrun estimates (1.52/1.55) are well below the weighted/unweighted average benefit overrun estimates (1.89/1.81). The conclusion reached using the Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) approach is that the Benevolent Hiding Hand dominates the Malevolent Hiding Hand in the World Bank-financed hydropower projects. This outcome is supported at 10% significance level by the one-sided Welch’s test. According to Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016), if the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle were true, then cost overruns should decline over time across projects and benefit overruns should increase over time across projects; this is the second claim. For this hypothesis to be true, the correlation between time (proxied by project start date) and cost overrun must be negative and the correlation between time and benefit overrun must be positive. The correlation coefficient of −0.11 reported in the last row of Table 1 confirms the presence of a negative relationship between cost overrun and time, albeit relatively weak. Also, as recorded in the last row of Table 2, the correlation coefficient between time and benefit overrun is 0.22. This indicates that the relationship between time and benefit overrun is positive, although relatively weak.

Table 2. Higher than estimated benefits.

Note: P*, P-value of the test with null hypothesis that benefit overrun is larger than cost overrun, using Welch’s test. (2) BO, benefit overrun; corr, correlation, PSD, project start date.

Our statistical findings on the two claims made by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) lend credence to the conclusion reached on World Bank-financed projects by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015), and more recently by Ika and Feeny (Reference Ika and Feeny2022) who argued that while project stakeholders are often over-optimistic in their assessment of project risks, benefits, and likelihood of success, they also often underestimate their own abilities to solve problems that arise during project construction.

4.2. The modified Ika ( Reference Ika2018) approach

At first glance, using the Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) approach, one may be tempted to conclude that the Benevolent Hiding Hand principle holds as claimed by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) in World Bank-financed hydropower projects. Caution is however required as the Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) approach has been criticized on a number of grounds by Ika (Reference Ika2018). The first criticism of the approach is its failure to take into consideration the differences between developmental and infrastructural projects. The second criticism is the failure of the approach to take into account the centrality of unintended consequences. The third criticism is that the approach narrowly tests the validity of the Hiding Hand Principle only through cost–benefit calculations. The fourth criticism of the approach is its lack of a project management perspective that takes creativity into account. The approach therefore does not provide any information on the innovations that take place during the process of transforming inputs into outputs (Ika, Reference Ika2015). The final and most relevant limitation of the approach as pointed out by Ika (Reference Ika2018) is on methodological grounds. Ika (Reference Ika2018) argues that as opposed to the unreliable first-year benefits used by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016), ex-post and full life-cycle project costs and benefits should have been used. This would have considered all the unexpected responses caused by setbacks during project construction. This approach would thus be able to correctly test the Hiding Hand principle. We solve this problem by following the methodological approach described by Baurzhan et al. (Reference Baurzhan, Jenkins and Olasehinde-Williams2021) for calculating benefit overruns.

As an alternative to Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016), Ika (Reference Ika2018) follows a project management approach. Ika (Reference Ika2018), following De Wit (Reference De Wit1988), makes a distinction between projects deemed to be short-term management successes and those deemed to be long-term management successes. While the former is predominantly concerned with a project’s management process, the latter is mainly concerned with the project’s fitness for use, and consequently, the project’s final impact. Ika (Reference Ika2015) refers to the long-term management success as deliverable success. In summary, project management successes on one hand are measures of efficiency while deliverable successes are measures of effectiveness (see Ika, Reference Ika2009). These successes are regarded as two sides of a coin in which project management successes could either result in deliverable successes or in deliverable failures (see Ika, Reference Ika2015; Ika & Donnelly, Reference Ika and Donnelly2017). Against this backdrop, Ika (Reference Ika2018) creates a 2 × 2 matrix within which project management performance is compared with deliverable performance.

We modify this project management approach of Ika (Reference Ika2018) by adopting a cost–benefit approach in our interpretation of deliverable performance. We define deliverable success as the ability to generate net economic benefits (projects with positive economic NPVs). This is because such projects have been able to produce benefits that significantly exceed their associated costs. In cost–benefit analysis, the ability to generate positive economic NPV is a key criterion for deciding whether a project is successful or not. Consequently, the top-left quadrant of the matrix contains projects regarded as all-round successes. These are projects that were not only completed within estimated costs but also generated positive net economic present values. In the top-right quadrant of the matrix are projects that are classified as project management failures with significant deliverable successes. For this study, these projects are those that suffered considerable cost overruns (project management difficulties) but still managed to generate positive economic NPVs over their life cycles (deliverable successes). Projects in this category are those that exhibit the Benevolent Hiding Hand.

The bottom-left quadrant of the matrix contains projects that are termed outright failures. The projects within this category are those that could not be built within estimated costs (project management failure) and also could not generate positive economic NPVs (deliverable failure). These are projects with significant cost overruns and benefit shortfalls. These projects are those that exhibit the Planning Fallacy (the Malevolent Hiding Hand). At the bottom-right quadrant are projects regarded as project management successes but deliverable failures. These projects in our case are those that were delivered within budget but fell short of delivering the expected benefits (projects without significant cost overruns but with negative economic NPVs).

Results reported in Table 3 confirm that the Benevolent Hiding Hand dominates the Malevolent Hiding Hand in World Bank-financed hydropower projects. Fourteen out of the 43 projects examined (33%) fall into the Benevolent Hiding Hand quadrant. On the other hand, 9 of the 43 projects (21%) fall into the Planning Fallacy quadrant. Our study findings based on the modified Ika (Reference Ika2018) approach therefore suggest that the chances that a World Bank-financed dam will experience the Benevolent Hiding Hand is significantly higher than the chances that it will suffer from the Malevolent Hiding Hand. While these results generally align with the conclusion of Ika (Reference Ika2018) that the Benevolent Hiding Hand dominates the Malevolent Hiding Hand, there are a few differences. In our case, the Benevolent Hiding Hand occurred in 33% of the projects as opposed to the 13% recorded by Ika (Reference Ika2018). Also, in our case, the Malevolent Hiding Hand occurred in 21% of the projects as opposed to the 3.1% documented by Ika (Reference Ika2018). This is perhaps due to the more homogeneous nature of the sample used in our analysis, as well as the distinct method of estimating project benefits employed in our study.

Table 3. Project management performance versus deliverable performance.

Note: (1) CO, cost overrun. (2) NPV is measured in US$M, 2016 price level.

Moreover, the results show that due to the Malevolent Hiding Hand, 2.335 billion USD was lost (value of negative economic NPV)Footnote 1 by these World Bank-financed dams. However, in addition to the 11.221 billion USD gained (value of positive economic NPV) from projects that were all-round successes, an additional amount of 11.259 billion USD was gained as a result of the ingenuity of the project managers (Benevolent Hiding Hand).

5. Conclusion

Whether the Hiding Hand principle of Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) is predominantly benevolent or malevolent has been the focus of academic debate in recent times. The keen interest in this topic is as a result of its potential effect on project decision-making. This study extends this debate by analyzing whether the need to get project appraisal perfectly right during the pre-construction phase of power dams so as to prevent significant overruns supersedes the need to deliver power projects at the earliest possible time so as to meet the needs of the people. We posit that if the Hiding Hand is benevolent, then project managers are better off focusing on quick delivery of power projects, but if it is malevolent, then more attention should be given to perfecting project appraisals. Our study is a specific attempt to determine whether the Hiding Hand is benevolent or malevolent in hydropower projects financed by the World Bank, using the approach established by Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) and a modification of the approach introduced by Ika (Reference Ika2018).

Statistical findings based on the Flyvbjerg (Reference Flyvbjerg2016) approach lead to the conclusion that the Benevolent Hiding Hand dominates the Malevolent Hiding Hand in the selected World Bank-financed hydropower projects. First, we found that the average weighted/unweighted cost overrun estimates (1.52/1.55) are well below the weighted/unweighted average benefit overrun estimates (1.89/1.81). We also detected the presence of a negative relationship between cost overrun and time, an indication that cost overrun declines with time. Statistical findings based on the modified Ika (Reference Ika2018) approach further confirm the previous outcomes. The Benevolent Hiding Hand occurred in 33% of the cases, while the Malevolent Hiding Hand occurred in 21% of the cases. Our findings further showed that while a total loss of 2.335 billion USD in the sampled dams was caused by the Malevolent Hiding Hand, 11.259 billion USD was gained as a result of the Benevolent Hiding Hand.

It is also worthy of mention that although the Benevolent Hiding Hand is not typical as suggested by Hirschman (Reference Hirschman1967, Reference Hirschman2015) since it occurred in only 33% of the cases, 75% of the cases examined ended up being successful (addition of outright successes and success due to the Benevolent Hiding Hand). The project development and management implication of our finding are clear. The predominance of the Benevolent Hiding Hand justifies placing some weight on proceeding with hydro-projects with significant promise, even if all the implantation risks are not fully quantified at the appraisal stage. This is especially true for developing countries. As stated earlier, most developing countries suffer from inadequate electricity service coupled with continuously growing demand that worsens the situation. Thus, very high economic value is attached to power generation in these countries, whereas project implementation delays impose huge socio-economic costs.

Caution is however advised since sampling on the basis of data availability, as we have done, may lead to the generation of conservative results. There is no doubt that projects financed by organizations such as the World Bank will be appraised at a higher than normal professional standard. It may be because the cost–benefit analysis is done well that the benevolent hand is able to exercise such a relatively strong positive influence in addressing the remaining events that arise due to uncertainties. Poorly appraised projects, or cost–benefit analysis whose outcomes are foreordained, might very well create outcomes where the existence of the Malevolent Hiding Hand dominates. In such cases, the underestimated creativity associated with the Benevolent Hiding Hand may not be large enough to cover the remaining events that arise due to uncertainties. Thus, cost overruns and benefit shortfalls in the project population could be larger than in the sample used for our analysis. However, the solution to this problem is for increased professionalism in the conduct of the cost–benefit analysis of these proposed projects. As it has been discussed by Jenkins et al. (Reference Jenkins, Olasehinde-Williams and Baurzhan2022), a simple rule of increasing the estimation of the costs through reference-based forecasting while ignoring the likely distribution of the benefits is not a solution to this problem. That proposed solution leads to the abandonment of many projects at the appraisal stage that if implemented would have generated significant positive NPVs. Moreover, the fact that other associated benefits of hydropower projects such as supply of potable water, irrigation, flood control, and carbon emissions reduction are excluded from our analysis also indicates that the presence of the Benevolent Hiding Hand might have been underestimated in the sample of projects used in this study.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to Migara Jayawardena for assisting us in launching this project. The authors are grateful to Saule Baurzhan and Owotomiwa Olubamiro for the assistance rendered in the preparation of the databases used for statistical analysis. The authors are also grateful to two anonymous reviewers for very useful insights provided on an earlier draft of this manuscript. The research from which the study data are obtained was funded by the World Bank’s independent Evaluation Group. The authors however take full responsibility for all conclusions reached and any errors found in the article. Views reflected and conclusions provided by this article should neither be attributed to the World Bank nor any of its staff.

Competing interest

The authors declare none.

Appendix

Table A1. The 43 hydro dams used for statistical analysis.

Footnotes

1 Economic NPVs are calculated as of the date project approval was given but then adjusted to 2016 price level.

References

Adelman, J. 2013. Worldly Philosopher: The Odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alacevich, M. (2015). “Albert Hirschman Observed. Afterword.” In Hirschman, A. O. (Ed.), Development Projects Observed (3rd ed.). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Awojobi, O. and Jenkins, G. P.. 2015. “Were the Hydro Dams Financed by the World Bank from 1976 to 2005 Worthwhile?Energy Policy, 86: 222232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacon, R. W. and Besant-Jones, J. E.. 1998. “Estimating Construction Costs and Schedules: Experience with Power Generation Projects in Developing Countries.” Energy Policy, 26(4): 317333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baurzhan, S., Jenkins, G. P., and Olasehinde-Williams, G. O.. 2021. “The Economic Performance of Hydropower Dams Supported by the World Bank Group, 1975–2015.” Energies, 14(9): 2673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braeckman, J. P. and Guthrie, P. 2015. “Loss of Value: Effects of Delay on Hydropower Stakeholders.” In Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers-Engineering Sustainability (Vol. 169, No. 6): pp. 253264). London: Thomas Telford Ltd.Google Scholar
Cracknell, B. 1984. “Learning Lessons from Experience: The Role of Evaluation in the Administration of the UK Aid Programme.” Public Administration and Development, 4(1): 1520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Wit, A. 1988. “Measurement of Project Success.” International Journal of Project Management, 6(3): 164170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhakal, D. N. S. and Jenkins, G. P.. 2013. “Risk Sharing in Hydropower Development: Case Study of the Chukha Hydel Project in Bhutan.” Water Policy, 15(S1): 109125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorner, D. 1997. The Logic of Failure: Recognizing and Avoiding Error In Complex Situations. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B. 2005. “Design by Deception: The Politics of Megaproject Approval.” Harvard Design Magazine, Spring/Summer, 22: 5059.Google Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B. 2016. “The Fallacy of Beneficial Ignorance: A Test of Hirschman’s Hiding Hand.” World Development, 84: 176189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B. and Sunstein, C. R.. 2016. “The Principle of the Malevolent Hiding Hand; or, the Planning Fallacy Writ Large.” Social Research, 83(4): 9791004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B., Holm, M. S., and Buhl, S.. 2002. “Underestimating Costs in Public Works Projects: Error or Lie?Journal of the American Planning Association, 68(3): 279295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flyvbjerg, B. (2009). Survival of the unfittest: why the worst infrastructure gets built–and what we can do about it. Oxford review of economic policy, 25(3), 344-367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gasper, D. 1986. “Programme Appraisal and Evaluation: The Hiding Hand and Other Stories.” Public Administration and Development, 6(4): 467474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gil, N., Stafford, A., and Musonda, I. (Eds.). 2019. Duality by Design: The Global Race to Build Africa’s Infrastructure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gladwell, M. 2013. “The Gift of Doubt: Albert O. Hirschman and the Power of Failure.” The New Yorker, 24.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” The American Economic Review, 35(4): 519530.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1967. Development Projects Observed. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 2015. Development Projects Observed, Third Edition Published as a Brookings Classic with a New Foreword by Cass R. Sunstein and a New Afterword by Michele Alacevich. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Ika, L. A. (2009). Project success as a topic in project management journals. Project management journal, 40(4), 6-19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. 2012. “Project Management for Development in Africa: Why Projects are Failing and What Can Be Done About It.” Project Management Journal, 43(4): 2741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. (2015). Opening the black box of project management: Does World Bank project supervision influence project impact?. International Journal of Project Management, 33(5), 1111-1123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. 2018. “Beneficial or Detrimental Ignorance: The Straw Man Fallacy of Flyvbjerg’s Test of Hirschman’s Hiding Hand.” World Development, 103: 369382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. and Donnelly, J.. 2017. “Success Conditions for International Development Capacity Building Projects.” International Journal of Project Management, 35(1): 4463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. and Hodgson, D.. 2014. “Learning from International Development Projects: Blending Critical Project Studies and Critical Development Studies.” International Journal of Project Management, 32(7): 11821196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. and Feeny, S. 2022. “Optimism Bias and World Bank Project Performance.” The Journal of Development Studies, 58(12): 26042623.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ika, L. A. and Söderlund, J.. 2016. “Rethinking Revisited: Insights from an Early Rethinker.” International Journal of Managing Projects in Business, 9(4): 931954.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, G., Olasehinde-Williams, G., and Baurzhan, S.. 2022. “Is There a Net Economic Loss from Employing Reference Class Forecasting in the Appraisal of Hydropower Projects?Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 159: 112218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. 2011. Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
Kacou, K. P., Ika, L. A., and Munro, L. T.. 2022. “Fifty Years of Capacity Building: Taking Stock and Moving Research Forward 1.” Public Administration and Development, 42(4): 215232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, P. 1994. The Fall and Rise of Development Economics. Rethinking the Development Experience: Essays Provoked by the Work of Albert O. Hirschman: 3958. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Love, P. E. and Ahiaga-Dagbui, D. D.. 2018. “Debunking Fake News in a Post-Truth Era: The Plausible Untruths of Cost Underestimation in Transport Infrastructure Projects.” Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 113: 357368.Google Scholar
Love, P. E., Ika, L. A., and Ahiaga-Dagbui, D. D.. 2019. “On De-Bunking ‘Fake News’ in a Post Truth Era: Why Does the Planning Fallacy Explanation for Cost Overruns Fall Short?Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, 126: 397408.Google Scholar
Offe, C. 2013. “Getting Ahead by Trespassing-Jeremy Adelman, Worldly Philosopher. The Odyssey of Albert O. Hirschman (Princeton, Princeton University Press 2013).” European Journal of Sociology/Archives Européennes de Sociologie, 54(3): 583591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Picciotto, R. 1994a. Visibility and Disappointment: The New Role of Development Evaluation. Rethinking the Development Experience: Essays Provoked by the Work of Albert O. Hirschman: 210230. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Picciotto, R. (1994b). “Marseille Discussion: Learning Via the Hiding Hand.” In Appendix A of Rodwin, Lloyd and Schön, Donald A. (Eds.) Rethinking the Development Experience: Essays Provoked by the Work of Albert O. Hirschman: 301304. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Picciotto, R. 2015. “Hirschman’s Ideas as Evaluation Tools.” Journal of Multidisciplinary Evaluation, 11(24): 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rondinelli, D. A. 1976. “Why Development Projects Fail: Problems of Project Management in Developing Countries.” Project Management Quarterly, 7: 1015.Google Scholar
Schön, D. A. 1994. Hirschman’s Elusive Theory of Social Learning. Rethinking the Development Experience: Essays Provoked by the Work of Albert O. Hirschman: 6795. Washington DC and Cambridge, MA: The Brookings Institution and The Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.Google Scholar
Shenhar, A. J. and Dvir, D.. 2007. Reinventing Project Management: The Diamond Approach to Successful Growth and Innovation. Brighton, Massachusetts: Harvard Business Review Press.Google Scholar
Singer, H. W. 1969. “Albert O. Hirschman: Development Projects Observed.” Institute of Development Studies Bulletin, 1(3): 2225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streeten, Paul P., 1984, “Comment,” in Meier, Gerald M. and Seers, Dudley, eds., Pioneers in Development (New York: World Bank and Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. 2015. “Albert Hirschman’s Hiding Hand.” In Foreword to Albert O. Hirschman. Development Projects Observed (3rd ed.). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Wachs, M. 1990. “Ethics and Advocacy in Forecasting for Public Policy.” Business & Professional Ethics Journal, 9: 141157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zuker, R. C. and Jenkins, G. P.. 1984. Blue Gold: Hydro-Electric Rent in Canada. Ottawa: Economic Council of Canada.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Higher than estimated costs.

Figure 1

Table 2. Higher than estimated benefits.

Figure 2

Table 3. Project management performance versus deliverable performance.

Figure 3

Table A1. The 43 hydro dams used for statistical analysis.