Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T07:21:49.106Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Benefit-cost analysis: government compensation vs. consumer tax model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 January 2015

Andrew Schmitz*
Affiliation:
University of Florida – Food and Resource Economics, Gainesville, Florida, USA
Dwayne J. Haynes
Affiliation:
University of Florida – Food and Resource Economics, Gainesville, Florida, USA
Troy G. Schmitz
Affiliation:
Arizona State University – Morrison School of Agribusiness and Resource Management, Mesa, Arizona, USA
*
Andrew Schmitz, University of Florida – Food and Resource Economics, 1130A McCarty Hall, Gainesville, Florida 32611, USA, e-mail: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

We provide a theoretical and empirical comparison of two historic production quota buyouts: the 2002 US Peanut Quota Buyout and the 2004 US Tobacco Quota Buyout. Producer compensation under the US Peanut Quota Buyout came from the treasury while the US Tobacco Buyout was paid for by a consumer tax (i.e., tobacco tax). Given these two buyouts, an important question arises: How does the method of compensation affect distribution and efficiency? Producers, consumers, and society favor a treasury buyout (TB) for several reasons. Producers are compensated considerably more under a TB, consumers are not burdened with the charge of funding the buyout, and society does not face additional efficiency losses due to the buyout.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2013

References

Alston, J. M., & Hurd, B. H. (1990). Some neglected social costs of government spending in farm programs. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72(1), 149156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dohlman, E., Foreman, L., & Da Pra, M. (2009). The post-buyout experience: Peanut and tobacco sectors adapt to policy reform. Economic Information Bulletin No. EIB-60, Economic Research Service, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C. Retrieved from http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/eib60/.Google Scholar
ERS/USDA. (2005). Tobacco situation and outlook report. Economic Research Service, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C. Google Scholar
Harberger, A. C. (1978). On the use of distributional weights in social cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 86(2), S87S120.Google Scholar
Just, R. E., Hueth, D. L., & Schmitz, A. (Editors). (2004). The welfare economics of public policy: A practical approach to project and policy evaluation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Moschini, G., & Sckokai, P. (1994). Efficiency of decoupled farm programs under distortionary taxation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 76(3), 362370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasour, E. C. Jr., (2005). The tobacco-quota buyout: More legal plunder, there is no economic, legal, or ethical reason to compensate those who have benefited from a government-enforced cartel. The Freeman, 55, 1. Retrieved from http://www.thefreemanonline.org/features/the-tobacco-quota-buyout-more-legal-plunder/. Google Scholar
Schmitz, A., & Zerbe, R. O. (Editors). (2008). Applied benefit-cost analysis. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Schmitz, T. G., & Schmitz, A. (2010). Benefit-cost analysis: Distributional considerations under producer quota buyouts. Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis, 1(1), Article 2.Google Scholar
Schmitz, T. G., & Schmitz, A. (2011). Compensation and the twin producer gains from production quotas. Theoretical Economic Letters, 1(3), 7072.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, A., Furtan, H., & Baylis, K. (2002). Agricultural policy. Agribusiness and rent-seeking behaviour. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Schmitz, A., Schmitz, T. G., & Rossi, F. (2006). Agricultural subsidies in developed countries: Impact on global welfare. Review of Agricultural Economics, 28(3), 416425.Google Scholar
Schmitz, T. G., Schmitz, A., & Haynes, D. (2012). Inflated production quota gains paid for by a consumption tax. Theoretical Economics Letters, 2(1), 6768.Google Scholar
Schmitz, A., Haynes, D. J., Schmitz, T. G., & Schmitz, E. D. (2013). The U.S. tobacco buyout: A partial and general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 45(3), Retrieved from http://purl.umn.edu/155414.Google Scholar
Serletis, G. S., & Fetzer, J. J. (2008). Modeling the impact of the US tobacco quota buyout. Office of Economics, United States International Trade Commission, Washington, D.C. Google Scholar
Womach, J. (2005). Tobacco quota buyout. CRS Report, United States Congress, Washington, D.C. Retrieved from http://www.nationalaglawcenter.org/assets/crs/RS22046.pdf.Google Scholar