Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T06:16:21.804Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Writing a Bill of Exchange: The Perils of Pearl Street, The Adventures of Harry Franco, and the Antebellum Credit System

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 March 2019

ANDREW LAWSON*
Affiliation:
School of Cultural Studies, Leeds Beckett University. Email: [email protected].

Abstract

This article examines representations of credit instruments in two popular antebellum fictions: Asa Greene's The Perils of Pearl Street and Charles Frederick Briggs's The Adventures of Harry Franco. Drawing on a range of business histories it describes the operation of promissory notes and bills of exchange in the cotton-for-credit system, focussing on the “principle of deferral” and the ways in which these instruments attempted to solve the problem of time in long-distance exchange. By establishing concrete connections between characters, times, and places, these fictions demystify the antebellum financial system, revealing an economy based on new forms of social interdependence.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press and British Association for American Studies 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 North, Douglass C., The Economic Growth of the United States, 1790–1860 (New York: Norton, 1966), 67, 69Google Scholar.

2 Greene, Asa, The Perils of Pearl Street, Including a Taste of the Dangers of Wall Street, by a Late Merchant (New York: Betts & Anstice, and Peter Hill, 1834), 13, 17Google Scholar, Hathi Trust Digital Archive, Web, accessed 26 Aug. 2016. Further references to this edition are given parenthetically in the text.

3 Briggs, Charles Frederick, The Adventures of Harry Franco: A Tale of the Great Panic, 2 vols. (New York: F. Saunders, 1839), Volume I, 17Google Scholar, Hathi Trust Digital Archive, Web, accessed 22 Aug. 2016. Further references in the text.

4 Agnew, Jean-Christophe, Worlds Apart: The Market and the Theatre in Anglo-American Thought, 1550–1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Clark, Lewis Gaylord, “Literary Notices,” Knickerbocker, or New York Monthly Magazine, 14, 1 (1839), 7980Google Scholar.

6 Poe, Edgar Allan, “The Literati of New York,” Essays and Reviews (New York: Library of America, 1984), 1132Google Scholar. On Briggs's literary career see Weidman, Bette S., “Charles Frederick Briggs,” in Myerson, Joel, ed., Dictionary of Literary Biography, Volume III, Antebellum Writers in New York and the South (New York: Gale Research, 1979), 2225Google Scholar.

7 Cawelti, John G., Apostles of the Self-Made Man (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1965), 63, 64, 56Google Scholar.

8 Bergmann, Hans, God in the Street: New York Writing from the Penny Press to Melville (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1995), 52Google Scholar. See also Royot, Daniel G., “Asa Greene,” in Gale, Steven H., ed., Encyclopedia of American Humorists (New York: Routledge, 2016; first published 1988), 181–86Google Scholar.

9 Luskey, Brian P., On the Make: Clerks and the Quest for Capital in Nineteenth-Century America (New York: New York University Press, 2010), 9, 33, 35, 45, 94–95, 98CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Zakim, Michael, Accounting for Capitalism: The World the Clerk Made (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2018), 89, 88, 8CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Balleisen, Edward J., Navigating Failure: Bankruptcy and Commercial Society in Antebellum America (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2001), 3, 73Google Scholar.

10 Poovey, Mary, Genres of the Credit Economy: Mediating Value in Eighteenth- and Nineteenth-Century Britain (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2008), 7785CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 On antebellum paper money see Mihm, Stephen, A Nation of Counterfeiters: Capitalists, Con Men, and the Making of the United States (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2007), 119CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Henkin, David, City Reading: Written Words and Public Spaces in Antebellum New York (New York: Columbia University Press, 1998), 137–66Google Scholar; Shell, Marc, Money, Language, and Thought: Literary and Philosophical Economies from the Medieval to the Modern Era (Berkley: University of California Press, 1982), 522Google Scholar.

12 Anthony, David, Paper Money Men: Commerce, Manhood, and the Sensational Public Sphere in Antebellum America (Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 2009)Google Scholar.

13 Fichtelberg, Joseph, Critical Fictions: Sentiment and the American Market, 1780–1870 (Athens: University of Georgia Press, 2003), 9, 7Google Scholar.

14 Leggett, William, Political Writings, quoted in Sklansky, Jeffrey, Sovereign of the Market: The Money Question in Early America (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2017), 122Google Scholar.

15 Poovey, 5–7.

16 Foster, B. F., The Merchant's Manual, Comprising the Principles of Trade, Commerce, and Banking (Boston: Perkins & Marvin, 1838), 93, 92Google Scholar, Web. Hathi Trust Digital Archive. accessed 8 Aug. 2018.

17 On promissory notes see Bodenhorn, Howard, State Banking in Early America: A New Economic History (New York: Oxford University Press, 2003), 4849Google Scholar; Redlich, Fritz, “The Promissory Note as a Financial and Business Instrument in the Anglo-Saxon World: A Historical Sketch,” Revue internationale d'histoire de la banque, 3 (1970), 271–97Google Scholar. On local credit networks see Mann, Bruce H., Neighbors and Strangers: Law and Community in Early Connecticut (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1987), 29–30, 5455Google Scholar.

18 On the operation of bills of exchange in the transatlantic trade see Bodenhorn, 46–52; Neal, Larry, “The Finance of Business during the Industrial Revolution,” in Floud, Roderick and McCloskey, D. N., eds., The Economic History of Britain since 1700, Volume I (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 157–62Google Scholar; on the early history of bills as a form of foreign exchange see McCusker, John J., Money and Exchange in Europe and America, 1600–1775: A Handbook (London: Macmillan, 1978), 116–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 Rogers, James Steven, The Early History of the Law of Bills and Notes: A Study of the Origins of Anglo-American Commercial Law (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), 205CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Mann, Bruce H., Republic of Debtors: Bankruptcy in the Age of American Independence (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2002), 13Google Scholar.

21 Poovey, 174.

22 Finn, Margot, The Character of Credit: Personal Debt in English Culture, 1740–1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), 7Google Scholar.

23 Byles, John Barnard, A Practical Treatise on the Law of Bills of Exchange (Philadelphia: John S. Littell, 1837), iii, Web, HeinOnline, accessed 27 July 2018Google Scholar.

24 On the Seven Houses see Nelson, Scott Reynolds, A Nation of Deadbeats: An Uncommon History of America's Financial Disasters (New York: Vintage Books, 2013), 100–5Google Scholar, Perkins, Edwin J., Financing Anglo-American Trade: The House of Brown, 1800–1880 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1975), 1933CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Buck, Norman Sydney, The Development of the Organization of Anglo-American Trade, 1800–1850 (Newton Abbot: David & Charles, 1969), 3745Google Scholar. See also Nash, R. C., “The Organization of Trade and Finance in the British Atlantic Economy, 1600–1830,” in Coclanis, Peter A., ed., The Atlantic Economy during the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: Organization, Operation, Practice, and Personnel (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 2005), 95151Google Scholar.

25 Agricultural Department,” DeBow's Review, 13, 1 (1852), 57–74, 70Google Scholar; also quoted in Buck, 86.

26 Buck, 73.

27 Johnson, Walter, River of Dark Dreams: Slavery and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2013), 258CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 Woodman, Harold D., King Cotton and His Retainers: Financing and Marketing the Cotton Crop of the South, 1800–1925 (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1968), 118Google Scholar.

29 Albion, Robert Greenhalgh, The Rise of New York Port (1815–1860) (Newton Abbott: David & Charles, 1970), 98Google Scholar.

30 Buck, 81–84; Perkins, 148–49. See also Killick, John R., “The Cotton Operations of Alexander Brown and Sons in the Deep South, 1820–1860,” Journal of Southern History, 43, 2 (May 1977), 169–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar. A fast-growing scholarship examines the credit networks underpinning American slavery. See Schermerhorn, Calvin, The Business of Slavery and the Rise of American Capitalism, 1815–1860 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Baptist, Edward, The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism (New York: Basic Books, 2014), 75110Google Scholar; Kilbourne, Richard Holcombe Jr., Slave Agriculture and Financial Markets in Antebellum America: The Bank of the United States in Mississippi, 1831–1853 (London: Routledge, 2016; first published 2006)Google Scholar.

31 Buck, 89–89.

32 Johnson, 259.

33 Nelson, 101.

34 Buck, 151–67.

35 Ibid., 160; Nelson, 57; 77.

36 Bodenhorn, State Banking, 48–49; Balleisen, Navigating Failure, 30–31.

37 Hammond, Bray, Banks and Politics in America: From the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957), 317Google Scholar.

38 See Buchnea, Emily, “Transatlantic Transformations: Visualizing Change over Times in the Liverpool–New York Trade Network, 1763–1833,” Enterprise and Society, 15, 4 (Dec. 2014), 687721Google Scholar. Beckert, Sven, Empire of Cotton: A New History of Global Capitalism (London: Penguin Books, 2015), 30, 459 n. 1, 33, 36Google Scholar, uses “networks” to describe “local distributions of social, economic, and political power,” reserving “system” for the “global economic order.” For a discussion of how economic historians have used the network metaphor see Jeggle, Christophe, “Interactions, Networks, Discourses and Markets,” in Caracausi, Andrea and Jeggle, Christophe, eds., Commercial Networks and European Cities, 1400–1800 (London: Pickering & Chatto, 2015), 4563Google Scholar.

39 Levine, Caroline, Forms: Whole, Rhythm, Hierarchy, Network (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2015), 115Google Scholar.

40 Kilgore, Christopher D., “Rhetoric of the Network: Toward a New Metaphor,” Mosaic: Journal for the Interdisciplinary Study of Literature, 46, 4 (Dec. 2013), 3758, 40; Levine, 129CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

41 Lukács, György, Theory of the Novel: A Historico-philosophical Essay on the Forms of Great Epic Literature, trans. Bostock, Anna (London: Merlin Press, 1971), 20, 57, 62Google Scholar.

42 Killick, “Risk, Speculation and Profit,” 12.

43 WReC (Warwick Research Collective), Combined and Uneven Development: Towards a New Theory of World Literature (Liverpool: Liverpool University Press, 2015), 8Google Scholar.

44 Aglietta, Michel, A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The U.S. Experience, trans. Fernbach, David (London: Verso, 2000), 68Google Scholar.

45 On the “space of flows” see Arrighi, Giovanni, The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times (London: Verso, 1994), 8083Google Scholar.

46 On “land” and “market” see Sellers, Charles, The Market Revolution: Jacksonian America, 1815–1846 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994), 333Google Scholar.

47 Bodenhorn, Howard, A History of Banking in Antebellum America: Financial Markets and Economic Development in an Era of Nation-Building (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), 181Google Scholar; Perkins, Financing Anglo-American Trade, 147–48.

48 Zakim, Accounting for Capitalism, 202 n. 5.

49 See Pratt, Lloyd, Archives of American Time: Literature and Modernity in the Nineteenth Century (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Allen, Thomas M., A Republic in Time: Temporality and Social Imagination in Nineteenth-Century America (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2008), 114–45Google Scholar; Smith, Mark M., Mastered by the Clock: Time, Slavery, and Freedom in the American South (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1997)Google Scholar; Bruegel, Martin, “Time That Can Be Relied Upon: The Evolution of Time Consciousness in the Mid-Hudson Valley, 1790–1860,” Journal of Social History, 28, 3 (Spring 1995), 547–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hensley, Paul B., “Time, Work, and Social Context in New England,” New England Quarterly, 65, 4 (Dec. 1992), 531–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Goetzmann, William N., Money Changes Everything: How Finance Made Civilization Possible (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2016), 2CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On the role of “expectations, aspirations, and projections” in the modern economy see Beckert, Jens, Imagined Futures: Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2016), 3560CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51 Levine, Forms, 62.

52 Berge, Leigh Claire La, “The Rules of Abstraction,” Radical History Review, 118 (Winter 2014), 93112, 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

53 Levine, 52. On nineteenth-century temporality see Osterhammel, Jürgen, The Transformation of the World: A Global History of the Nineteenth Century, trans. Camiller, Patrick (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2014), 6776Google Scholar. Scholars of Victorian Literature have begun to explore the temporality of novelistic forms in relation to finance. See Kornbluh, Anna, Realizing Capital: Financial and Psychic Economies in Victorian Form (New York: Fordham University Press, 2014), 26–27, 5356Google Scholar; Tara McGann, “Literary Realism in the Wake of Business Cycle Theory: The Way We Live Now (1875),” in Francis O'Gorman, ed., Victorian Literature and Finance, Web, Oxford Scholarship Online (Jan. 2010).

54 On “fictitious capital” see M'Cready, John, A Review of the Trade and Commerce of New York, from 1815 to the Present Time (New York: C.S. Van Winkle, 1820)Google Scholar, Web, Making of the Modern World, accessed 26 Sept. 2016. M'Cready comments at 34, “So long as business continues regular, or is improving, fictitious capital flows smoothly on.” M'Cready cautions at 34, 36 that the 1819 panic had shown the fragility of “over-trading” in a system of “transactions bottomed upon no capital.” On the discourse of fictitious capital in nineteenth-century Britain see Kornbluh, 4–9.

55 Marsh, C. C., The Art of Single-Entry Book-Keeping; Improved (Baltimore: George McDowell & Son, 1832), 13Google Scholar, Web, Hathi Trust. On the connection between probity in accounting and trust see Zakim, 70–84.

56 Bodenhorn, A History of Banking in Antebellum America, 178–79; Porter, Glenn and Livesay, Harold C., Merchants and Manufacturers: Studies in the Changing Structure of Nineteenth-Century Marketing (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1971), 7475Google Scholar; on shaving see Greef, Albert O., The Commercial Paper House in the United States (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1938), 1017Google Scholar. For more on shinning and the intense financial pressures experienced by antebellum proprietors see Balleisen, Navigating Failure, 73–80.

57 Bakhtin, Mikhail, The Dialogic Imagination: Four Essays, trans. Emerson, Caryl and Holquist, Michael (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1981), 84Google Scholar.

58 Vernon, John, Money and Fiction: Literary Realism in the Early Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1984), 126Google Scholar.

59 Balleisen, 30.

60 Bakhtin, 225.

61 Larson, John Lauritz, The Market Revolution in America: Liberty, Ambition, and the Eclipse of the Common Good (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011), 47, 58Google Scholar.

62 Jameson, Fredric, A Singular Modernity: Essay on the Ontology of the Present (London and New York: Verso, 2002), 142Google Scholar.

63 Bakhtin., Mikhail M.Speech Genres and Other Late Essays, trans. McGee, Vern W. (Austin: University of Texas, 2002), 26Google Scholar; Perry Anderson, “Modernity and Revolution,” New Left Review, 144 (March–April 1984), 96–113, 101, also quoted in WReC, Combined and Uneven Development, 10.

64 On Smollet's American vogue see Davidson, Cathy N., Revolution and the Word: The Rise of the Novel in America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), 165–68Google Scholar.

65 Bunn, James H., “Signs of Randomness in Roderick Random,” Eighteenth-Century Studies, 14, 4 (Summer 1981), 452–69, 452CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lynch, Deidre Shauna, The Economy of Character: Novels, Market Culture, and the Business of Inner Meaning (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1998), 107Google Scholar.

66 Bakhtin, The Dialogic Imagination, 92, 128.

67 Ibid., 111.

68 Lhamon, W. T. Jr., Raising Cain: Blackface Performance from Jim Crow to Hip Hop (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998), 2Google Scholar.

69 Ibid., 3.

70 Bakhtin, Speech Genres, 36.

71 See Henkin, City Reading, 34–38; Blackmar, Elizabeth, Manhattan for Rent, 1785–1850 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1989), 273Google Scholar; Pred, Allan Richard, “Manufacturing in the American Mercantile City: 1800–1840,” Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 56, 2 (June 1966), 308–38, 313CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

72 Marx, Karl, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume III, trans. Fernbach, David (London: Penguin, Books, 1991), 567Google Scholar.

73 Larson, Market Revolution in America, 44.

74 Rev. Dewey, Orville, Moral Views of Commerce, Society, and Politics in Twelve Discourses (London: Charles Fox, 1838), 58Google Scholar.

75 Hildreth, Richard, Banks, Banking, and Paper Currencies (Boston: Whipple & Damrell, 1840), 160Google Scholar, Hathi Trust Digital Library, Web, accessed 25 Aug. 2016, original emphasis.

76 Schumpeter, Joseph, The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 2012), 101Google Scholar. For the argument that antebellum banks were Schumpeterian see Bodenhorn, State Banking in Early America, 45–71.

77 Pred, 309–10.

78 Marx, 599.

79 Harvey, David, The Limits to Capital (London: Verso, 2006), 241Google Scholar.

80 For a concise account of the 1837 panic see Balleisen, Navigating Failure, 32–41. For more detailed narratives tracing the transatlantic dimensions of the crisis see Lepler, Jessica M., The Many Panics of 1837: People, Politics, and the Creation of a Transatlantic Financial Crisis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lévy-Leboyer, Maurice, “Central Banking and Foreign Trade: The Anglo-American Cycle in the 1830s,” in Kindleberger, Charles P. and Laffargue, Jean-Pierre, eds., Financial Crises: Theory, History, and Policy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982), 66109Google Scholar. On communication networks as transmission mechanisms of the Panic see Pred, Allan R., Urban Growth and the Circulation of Information: The United States System of Cities, 1790–1840 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1973), 253–54Google Scholar.

81 Sewell, William H., “The Temporalities of Capitalism,” Socio-economic Review, 6 (April 2008), 517–37, 519CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

82 Chitty, Joseph, A Practical Treatise on Bills of Exchange (Springfield, MA: G. and C. Merriam, 1836), 147Google Scholar, Hathi Trust Digital Archive, Web, accessed 26 Sept. 2016.

83 Story, Joseph, Commentaries on the Law of Agency (Boston: C. C. Little & J. Brown, 1839), 221Google Scholar, Web, Hathi Trust Digital Archive, accessed 21 Aug. 2018.

84 Chitty, 31, 40, original emphasis.

85 See Balibar, Etienne and Laugier, Sandra, “Agency,” in Cassin, Barbara, ed., Dictionary of Untranslatables: A Philosophical Lexicon (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2014), 21Google Scholar; Strong, Norman and Waterson, Michael, “Principals, Agents and Information,” in Clark, Roger, ed., The Economics of the Firm (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987), 1921Google Scholar.

86 Bakhtin, The Dialogic Imagination, 106.

87 Boltanski, Luc and Chiapello, Eve, The New Spirit of Capitalism (London: Verso, 2005), 148Google Scholar.

88 Marx, Karl, Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy (Rough Draft), trans. Nickolaus, Martin (London: Penguin Books, 1993), 96, 95Google Scholar.

89 Jameson, Fredric, Representing “Capital”: A Reading of Volume One (London: Verso, 2014), 37Google Scholar.

90 Basker, James G., Bouché, Paul Gabriel, and Seary, Nicole A., “Introduction” to Tobias Smollett, The Adventures of Roderick Random (Athens: University of Georgia Press, 2012), xxiii–lix, xlviiGoogle Scholar.

91 Bakhtin, The Dialogic Imagination, 232.

92 Bruegel, Martin, Farm, Shop, Landing: The Rise of a Market Society in the Hudson Valley, 1780–1860 (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2002), 84CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bakhtin, The Dialogic Imagination, 232.

93 Bakhtin, The Dialogic Imagination, 225.

94 Kornbluh, Realizing Capital, 54, original emphasis.

95 Ibid., 54.

96 Postone, Moishe, Time, Labor, and Social Domination: A Reinterpretation of Marx's Critical Theory (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), 222CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

97 Marx, Karl, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume I, trans. Fowkes, Ben (London: Penguin Books, 1982), 550Google Scholar.

98 Marx, Capital, Volume I, 550.

99 Johnson, River of Dark Dreams, 244.

100 Marx, Capital, Volume III, 613.

101 Lukács, György, History and Class Consciousness, trans. Livingstone, Rodney (London: Merlin Press, 1971), 8, 9Google Scholar, quoting Marx, A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy.

102 Marx, Capital, Volume III, 572; Toscano, Alberto, “Materialism without Matter: Abstraction, Absence and Social Form,” Textual Practice, 28, 7 (Nov. 2014), 1221–40, 1225CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

103 Marx, Capital, Volume III, 654.

104 Franta, Andrew, “From Map to Network in Humphrey Clinker,” ELH, 83, 3 (Fall 2016), 771–93, 772–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

105 Levine, Forms, 126.

106 La Berge, “The Rules of Abstraction,” 93.