Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T03:07:17.087Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal Dynamic Management of Agricultural Land-Uses: An Application of Regime Switching

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 January 2015

Graeme J. Doole
Affiliation:
Centre of Environmental Economics and Policy, School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Faculty of Natural and Agricultural Sciences, University of Western Australia, Crawley, Western Australia, Australia Department of Economics, Waikato Management School, University of Waikato, Hamilton, New Zealand
Greg L. Hertzler
Affiliation:
School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Faculty of Agriculture, Food and Natural Resources, University of Sydney, Sydney, New South Wales, Australia

Abstract

The capacity of global agricultural production to meet increased demand for food from population growth and wealth accumulation is threatened by extensive land degradation. Nonetheless, previous research has focused primarily on the dynamic implications of input management and ignored land-use choice. This paper extends this theory through an examination of the intertemporal management of agricultural land through the use of non-crop inputs, such as fertilizer, and land uses that either degrade or restore productivity. The need to consider the relative total asset value of alternative crops over time is demonstrated. Moreover, higher output prices for degrading crops are shown to increase their relative value, motivating the later adoption of substitutes. An inability of land markets to reflect differences in resource quality and low capital malleability promote greater degradation. However, substitution of complementary effects through input use may help to sustain productivity. These factors are discussed in the context of crop sequence management in Western Australian cropping systems.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Amit, R.Petroleum Reservoir Exploitation: Switching from Primary to Secondary Recovery.Operations Research 34(1986):534–49.10.1287/opre.34.4.534Google Scholar
Barbier, E.B.The Farm-Level Economics of Soil Conservation: The Uplands of Java.Land Economics 66(1990):199211.10.2307/3146369Google Scholar
Barrett, S.Optimal Soil Conservation and the Reform of Agricultural Pricing Policies.Journal of Development Economics 36(1991):167–87.10.1016/0304-3878(91)90031-PGoogle Scholar
Bathgate, A.D., Revell, C., and Kingwell, R.S.Identifying the Value of Pasture Improvement Using Whole Farm Modelling.Agricultural Systems 102(2009):4857.10.1016/j.agsy.2009.06.008Google Scholar
Bruinsma, J. The Resource Outlook to 2050. Paris: FAO, 2009.Google Scholar
Clarke, C.J., George, R.J., Bell, R.W., and Hatton, T.J.Dryland Salinity in South-Western Australia: Its Origins, Remedies, and Future Research Directions.Australian Journal of Soil Research 40(2002):93113.10.1071/SR01028Google Scholar
Clarke, H.R.The Supply of Non-degraded Agricultural Land.Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 36(1992):3156.10.1111/j.1467-8489.1992.tb00711.xGoogle Scholar
Doole, G.J.A Practical Algorithm for Multiple-Phase Control Systems in Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics.Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 34(2009):109–29.Google Scholar
Doole, G.J., Bathgate, A.D., and Robertson, M.J.The Economic Value of Grazing Vegetative Wheat (Triticum aestivum L.) Crops in Mixed-Farming Systems of Western Australia.Animal Production Science 49(2009):807–15.10.1071/EA08286Google Scholar
Doole, G.J., and Pannell, D.J.On the Economic Analysis of Crop Rotations.” Crop Rotation: Economics, Impact, and Management. Berklian, Y.U., ed., pp. 71106. Hauppauge: Nova Science Publishers, 2009.Google Scholar
Doole, G.J., and Weetman, E.Tactical Management of Pasture Fallows in Western Australian Cropping Systems.Agricultural Systems 104(2009):2432.Google Scholar
Goetz, R.U.Diversification in Agricultural Production: A Dynamic Model of Optimal Cropping to Manage Soil Erosion.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79(1997):341–56.10.2307/1244134Google Scholar
Grepperud, S.Soil Conservation as an Investment in Land.Journal of Development Economics 54(1997):455–67.10.1016/S0304-3878(97)00051-5Google Scholar
Hennessy, D.A.On Monoculture and the Structure of Crop Rotations.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88(2006):900–14.10.1111/j.1467-8276.2006.00905.xGoogle Scholar
Hertzler, G.L.Dynamically Optimal Adoption of Farming Practices Which Degrade or Renew the Land.” Agricultural Economics Discussion Paper No. 5/90. University of Western Australia, Perth, 1990.Google Scholar
Just, R.E., and Miranowski, J.A.Understanding Farmland Price Changes.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75(1993):156–68.10.2307/1242964Google Scholar
LaFrance, J.T.Do Increased Commodity Prices Lead to More or Less Soil Degradation?American Journal of Agricultural Economics 36(1992):5782.10.1111/j.1467-8489.1992.tb00712.xGoogle Scholar
McConnell, K.E.An Economic Model of Soil Conservation.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65(1983):8389.10.2307/1240340Google Scholar
Orazem, P.F., and Miranowski, J.A.A Dynamic Model of Acreage Allocation with General and Crop-Specific Soil Capital.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76(1994):385–95.10.2307/1243651Google Scholar
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development and the Food and Agriculture Organization of the UN (OECD-FAO). Agricultural Outlook 2009-2018. Paris: OECD, 2009.Google Scholar
Willassen, Y.On the Economics of the Optimal Fallow-Cultivation Cycle.Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 28(2004):154156.10.1016/j.jedc.2003.04.001Google Scholar