Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T08:47:22.522Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Supply Response by Traditional and Commercial Producers of Basic Grains in LDCs*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Jose Alvarez
Affiliation:
Food and Resource Economics Department, Institute of Food and Agricultural Sciences, University of Florida
Chris O. Andrew
Affiliation:
Food and Resource Economics Department, Institute of Food and Agricultural Sciences, University of Florida

Extract

Traditional farms can play an important role in the agricultural development process [4, 6, 7, 8]. Less developed countries (LDCs) emphasize production and productivity increases for basic grains by relying on modern yield-increasing technology [2]. Technological advance, however, may produce diverging results; productivity may increase while production stagnates or declines. Due to both major seasonal and cyclical price fluctuations in basic grains and income limitations, traditional farmers in LDCs choose, quite rationally, to grow only enough of some food crops for home consumption. Yet policy makers often seek to increase the marketed supply of food crops and to determine possible changes in land utilization to meet that objective.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1977

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

University of Florida Agricultural Experiment Station Journal Series Number 799

References

[1] Alvarez, Jose. Traditional and Commercial Farm Supply Response in Agricultural Development: The Case for Basic Grains in Guatemala, Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Food and Resource Economics Department, University of Florida, 1977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[2]Dorner, Peter and Kanel, Don. “The Economic Case for Land Reform: Employment, Income Distribution, and Productivity,” in Dorner, Peter, Ed., Land Reform in Latin America-Issues and Cases, Land Economic Monograph No. 3, Madison: University of Wisconsin, 1971, pp. 4156.Google Scholar
[3]Falcon, Walter P.The Green Revolution: Generation of Problems,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 52 (1970): 698710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4]Johnston, Bruce F. and Mellor, John W.. “The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development,” in Meier, Gerald M., Ed., Leading Issues in Development Economics, New York: Oxford University Press, 1964, pp. 291297.Google Scholar
[5]Medani, A. I.Elasticity of the Marketable Surplus of a Subsistence Crop at Various States of Development,Economic Development and Cultural Change, 23 (1975): 421429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[6]Nicholls, William H.The Place of Agriculture in Economic Development,” in Eicher, Carl and Witt, L., Eds., Agriculture in Economic Development, New York: McGraw Hill Book Company, 1964.Google Scholar
[7]Papanek, Gustav F.Development Problems Relevant to Agriculture Tax Policy,” Papers and Proceedings of the Conference on Agricultural Taxation and Economic Development, Cambridge: Harvard Law School, 1954, pp. 193196.Google Scholar
[8]Schultz, Theodore W.Transforming Traditional Agriculture, New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969.Google Scholar