Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T00:51:31.912Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

‘No Elders Were Present’: Commoners and Private Ownership In Asante, 1807–96*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 January 2009

Gareth Austin
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science

Extract

It has been argued here that the impression, given by most of the existing literature, of near-total state dominance over the economic sources of wealth in the Asante economy during 1807–83 is mistaken. Admittedly, there was a large and often thriving state sector in the export–import trade; the state had a share in the production of marketable goods; chiefs had the largest concentrations of slaves and slave-descendants; and inheritance taxes gave the state a powerful instrument for the appropriation of privately generated wealth. But the accumulation of evidence now suggests that the private sector, too, was a major force in the extra-subsistence economy: an economy which included a lively domestic trade, which has been given too little scholarly attention. It appears that it was possible for ordinary commoners to acquire wealth through both external and internal trade, and through production for both export and domestic markets. The widespread acquisition of slaves by commoners, for incorporation in their households, was both a measure of financial achievement and a critical means for enhancing it in future. Death duties amounted normally to a form of progressive taxation rather than to wholesale expropriation.

It is suggested that the private sector is most plausibly seen as comprising a relatively small number of producers and traders prosperous enough to be considered as members of the asikafoɔ, the wealthy, plus a mass of people supplying export markets on a small unit scale. It seems reasonable to assume that the strong position of commoners within the post-Atlantic slave trade economy of Asante, and their accumulation of slaves and other forms of wealth, involved a relative decline, at least compared to the second half of the eighteenth century, in the chiefs' share of foreign trade and general wealth. Such a shift, and in particular the emergence of small producers and traders as a major element in the export economy, provides support for Hopkins' interpretation of the nineteenth-century commercial transition in West Africa generally. One qualification to Hopkins' analysis is that, while it allowed for the large-scale application of slave labour within the ‘economy of legitimate commerce’ by former exporters of slaves, it did not explicitly envisage the widespread use of small numbers of slaves and pawns by small producers and traders.

The shift in the distribution of income had political consequences. The essay argues that it is necessary to revise the argument, put forward by Wilks, about the emergence of a ‘middle-class’ element in the political conflicts of the last years of Asante independence. In particular, the proposition that such a movement developed primarily amongst the members of a monopolistic state trading company is rejected. In any case, it was a mass of commoners, rather than an ‘organized middle class’, that took the decisive role in the uprising that overthrew Mensa Bonsu in 1883. It is suggested that this was the political climax of the ‘adaptive challenge’ presented by the ending of slave exports: a movement of export-producing commoners, poor and rich alike, against the centralizing monarchy's new and punitive measures to raise revenue. The commoners sought not to overthrow chieftaincy but to use its authority to amplify their protests. Finally, it is suggested that the 1883 rising was the start of a pattern of rebellion by export-suppliers, in alliance with chiefs, against what they saw as organized extortion: a pattern that was to recur in the cocoa hold-ups of the 1930s and the National Liberation Movement of the mid-1950s.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Though anticipated, in brief, in Wilks, Ivor, ‘Ashanti government’, in Forde, Daryll and Kaberry, P. M. (eds.), West African Kingdoms in the Nineteenth Century (London, 1967), 216–17, 230232.Google Scholar

2 Wilks, Ivor, ‘Asante policy towards the Hausa trade in the nineteenth century’, in Meillassoux, C. (ed.), The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa (London, 1971), 130Google Scholar; Wilks, , Asante in the Nineteenth Century: The Structure and Evolution of a Political Order (London, 1975), 178.Google Scholar

3 Wilks, , ‘Ashanti government’, 216–17.Google Scholar

4 Wilks, , Asante, 435–6.Google Scholar

5 Wilks, Ivor, ‘The Golden Stool and the Elephant Tail: an essay on wealth in Asante’, Research in Economic Anthropology, II (1979), 28Google Scholar (reprinted with ‘minor revisions’ in Wilks, , Forests of GoldGoogle Scholar [Athens, Ohio, 1993]).

6 Wilks, , Asante, 435–6Google Scholar, and ‘Golden Stool’, 28.

7 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 28.Google Scholar

8 Ibid. 29; Wilks, , Asante, 697.Google Scholar

9 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 29.Google Scholar

10 Ibid. 28–9; Wilks, , Asante, 444.Google Scholar

11 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 29.Google Scholar

12 Ibid. 28–9.

13 Wilks, , Asante, 692–3, 696Google Scholar; ‘Golden Stool’, 23–9.Google Scholar

14 Wilks, , Asante, 685, 689.Google Scholar

15 Ibid. 444, 721 n. (cf. Wilks, , ‘Ashanti government’, 230)Google Scholar, citing Bowdich, T. Edward, A Mission from Cape Coast Castle to Ashantee (London, 1819; reprinted 1966), 257.Google Scholar

16 Wilks, , Asante, 697–9Google Scholar; ‘Golden Stool’, 1921.Google Scholar

17 Arhin, Kwame, ‘Trade, accumulation and the state in Asante in the nineteenth century’, Africa, LX (1990), 529.Google Scholar

18 Marx, , Capital, vol. 1 (London, 1965), 235Google Scholar, quoted by Terray, Emmanuel, ‘Long distance exchange and the formation of the state: the case of the Abron kingdom of Gyaman’, Economy and Society, III (1974), 334.Google Scholar

19 Arhin, , ‘Trade, accumulation and the state’, 529.Google Scholar

20 Arhin, Kwame, ‘Some Asante views of colonial role: as seen in the controversy relating to death duties’, Trans. Hist. Soc. Ghana, XV (1974), 6384.Google Scholar

21 Terray, , ‘Long-distance exchange’, 315–45Google Scholar; Terray, , ‘Gold production, slave labor, and state intervention in precolonial Akan societies: a reply to Raymond Dumett’, Research in Economic Anthropology, V (1983), 95129.Google Scholar

22 Terray, , ‘Long-distance exchange’, 329–31.Google Scholar

23 Maier, D. J. E., ‘Military acquisition of slaves in Asante’, in Henige, D. and McCaskie, T. C. (eds.), West African Economic and Social History: Studies in Memory of Marion Johnson (Madison, 1990), 119–32.Google Scholar

24 Ibid. 122, 128.

25 Aidoo, Agnes A., ‘Political crisis and social change in the Asante kingdom, 1867–1901’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of California, Los Angeles, 1975), Part 1, 107Google Scholar; McCaskie, T. C., ‘Office, land and subjects in the history of the Manwere/fekuo of Kumase: an essay in the political economy of the Asante state’, J. Afr. Hist., XXI (1980), 192.Google Scholar McCaskie was referring primarily to the use of the state's judicial and patronage powers as a means of manipulating the distribution of authority and wealth, notably between the central government and the provincial chiefs, a different issue from that discussed in the present essay. See, further, McCaskie, T. C., ‘Ahyiamu: “a place of meeting”: an essay on process and event in the history of the Asante state’, J. Afr. Hist., XXV (1984), 169–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

26 Wilks, , Asante, 191, 680–1.Google Scholar

27 Ibid. 700; Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 89, 1516.Google Scholar See also McCaskie, T. C., ‘Accumulation, wealth and belief in Asante, Part I: The nineteenth century’, Africa, LIII (1983), 33.Google Scholar

28 Wilks, , Asante, 700, cf. 720.Google Scholar

29 Wilks, Ivor, ‘Dissidence in Asante politics: two tracts from the late nineteenth century’, in Abu-Lughod, I. (ed.), African Themes (Evanston, Illinois, 1975), 52Google Scholar (reprinted in Wilks, , ForestsGoogle Scholar, with some changes); Asante, 701Google Scholar; ‘Golden Stool’, 22–3.Google Scholar

30 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 30Google Scholar; Asante, 701–5.Google Scholar

31 Lewin, Thomas J., Asante Before the British: The Prempean Years, 1875–1900 (Lawrence, Kansas, 1978), 53–4, 57–8, 77–8, 98, 116, 160, 186–7, 214–5Google Scholar; Aidoo, Agnes A., ‘Order and conflict in the Asante empire: a study in interest group relations’, African Studies Review, XX (1977), 24–7.Google Scholar

32 Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’Google Scholar; see, further, Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’.Google Scholar

33 Quoted in Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’, 59.Google Scholar

34 LaTorre, Joseph Raymond, ‘Wealth surpasses everything: an economic history of Asante, 1750–1874’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of California, Berkeley, 1978), 262–5.Google Scholar

35 Ibid. 117. His definition of ‘upper stratum’ is presented on pp. 93–5.Google Scholar

36 Arhin, Kwame, ‘Succession and gold mining at Manso-Nkwanta’, Research Review (Institute of African Studies, University of Ghana), VI, 3 (1970), 104–6Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Goldmining and trading among the Ashanti of Ghana’, Journal des Africanistes, XLVIII (1978), 91.Google Scholar

37 The points stated in the last three sentences are discussed at length in a book I am writing under the title of ‘Labor, land and capital in rural Asante, 1807–1956’. For an earlier statement see Austin, Gareth, ‘Rural capitalism and the growth of cocoa-farming in south Ashanti, to 1914’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of Birmingham, 1984), chs. 3 and 5.Google Scholar

38 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 7.Google Scholar

39 Dumeti, Raymond E., ‘Precolonial gold mining and the state in the Akan region: with a critique of the Terray hypothesis’, Research in Economic Anthropology, II (1983), 3768.Google Scholar See also Dumett, , ‘Traditional slavery in the Akan region in the nineteenth century: sources, issues, and interpretalions’Google Scholar, in Henige, and McCaskie, (eds.), West African Economic and Social History, 1718.Google Scholar The quolalion is from the latter, p. 17.

40 Terray, , ‘Gold production’, 118–19Google Scholar; Klein, A. Norman, ‘Inequality in Asante: a study of the forms and meanings of slavery and social servitude in pre- and early colonial Akan-Asante society and culture’ (Ph.D. thesis, University of Michigan, 1990), vol. 1, 99, 127.Google Scholar

41 Polanyi, Karl with Rotstein, Abraham, Dahomey and the Slave Trade: An Analysis of an Archaic Economy (Seattle, 1966).Google Scholar This analysis has been rigorously rebutted by later research: see especially Law, Robin, ‘Royal monopoly and private enterprise in the Atlantic trade: the case of Dahomey’, J. Afr. Hist., XXI (1977), 555–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Law, , ‘Posthumous questions for Karl Polanyi: price inflation in pre-colonial Dahomey’, J. Afr. Hist., XXXIII (1992), 387420CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Johnson, Marion, ‘Review article: Polanyi, Peukert and the political economy of Dahomey’, J. Afr. Hist., XXI (1980), 395–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

42 The quotation is from Wilks, , ‘Ashanti government’, 232Google Scholar; the parallel is hinted at in Ibid. 234, and made explicit in Wilks, , Asante, 720–3.Google Scholar

43 Hopkins, A. G., An Economic History of West Africa (London, 1973), 125–7, 142–7.Google Scholar For a survey of the general debate see Law, Robin, ‘The historiography of the commercial transition in nineteenth-century West Africa’, in Falola, T. (ed.), African Historiography: Essays in Honour of Jacob Ade Ajayi (London, 1993), 91115Google Scholar; and, further, Law, (ed.), From Slave Trade to ‘Legitimate’ Commerce.Google Scholar

44 Hopkins, , Economic History, 144.Google Scholar

45 Wilks, , Asante: the quotations are from pp. 437 and 689 respectively, cf. p. 444.Google Scholar

46 Lonsdale, John, ‘States and social processes in Africa’, African Studies Review, XXIV (1981), 180.Google Scholar

47 Isaacman, Allen F., ‘Peasants and rural social protest in Africa’, in Cooper, F. et al. , Confronting Historical Paradigms: Peasants, Labor, and the Capitalist World System in Africa and Latin America (Madison, Wisconsin, 1993), 205317Google Scholar (reprinted from African Studies Review, XXX (1990), 1120).Google Scholar

48 Cf. Wilks, , Asante, 47–8.Google Scholar

49 For a survey of the debate (started by Wilks) about the significance of these creations of ‘service stools’ for the nature of political authority in the Asante kingdom see Yarak, Larry W., Asante and the Dutch 1744–1873 (Oxford, 1990), 1727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

50 The meaning is thus broader than that of ‘tradeables’: which economists define as goods that can be traded in foreign as well as domestic markets.

51 British Parliamentary Papers, C.4477, Further Correspondence Regarding the Affairs of the Gold Coast (London, 1885), p. 91Google Scholar: Captain Kirby's, Brandon report on his mission to Kumase, Accra, 15 04 1884.Google Scholar

52 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 181Google Scholar; Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 27Google Scholar; McCaskie, , ‘Accumulation, Part 1’, 28–9.Google Scholar

53 Bowdich, , Mission, 324Google Scholar; Daaku, K. Y. (compiler and ed.), Oral Traditions of Adanse (Institute of African Studies, University of Ghana, Legon, 1969), 111.Google Scholar

54 Dupuis, Joseph, Journal of a Residence in Ashantee (London, 1824; reprinted 1966), 53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 60.Google Scholar

55 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 209.Google Scholar

56 For example, see McCaskie, T. C. and Wiafe, J. E., ‘A contemporary account in Twi of the Akompi Sa of 1863: a document with commentary’, Asantesem, XI (1979), 74.Google Scholar

57 G. Austin Fieldnotes: interview with Nana Owusu Sekyere, chief spokesman (okyeame)of Kokofu, and Opanyin Kwesi Kaabi in Kokofu, 12 05 1980.Google Scholar

58 Arhin, , ‘Succession and gold mining’, 108.Google Scholar

59 Bowdich, , Mission, 28, 30Google Scholar; Dupuis, , Journal, 59, 60Google Scholar; Hutton, W., A Voyage to Africa (London, 1821), 196Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 302, 306–7.Google Scholar

60 Bowdich, , Mission, 28Google Scholar; Dupuis, , Journal, 59Google Scholar; Rattray, , Religion and Art in Ashanti (Oxford, 1927), 301Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 46, 295.Google Scholar

61 Bowdich, , Mission, 28Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 23.Google Scholar

62 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 172, 209.Google Scholar

63 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 103Google Scholar; Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 12.Google Scholar

64 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 170Google Scholar; for a general reference to Asante production of gold ‘trinkets, chains, breast-plates, and ornaments’ see Dupuis, , Journal, lviii.Google Scholar

65 Garrard, Timothy, Akan Weights and the Gold Trade (London, 1980), 118.Google Scholar

66 Rattray, , Religion and Art, 271, 273.Google Scholar

67 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 139, 151, 170.Google Scholar

68 Bowdich, , Mission, 28.Google Scholar

69 Arhin, , ‘Succession and gold mining’, 106.Google Scholar

70 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 373Google Scholar, quoting Opanyin Abubekr of Fomena.

71 For example, see Rattray, R. S., Ashanti Law and Constitution (Oxford, 1929), 154–7.Google Scholar

72 For the ambiguity see Bowdich, , Mission, 324.Google Scholar

73 As noted above, Wilks and Terray argued this, and Dumett accepted the ‘likelihood’ that part – a ‘relatively small’ part – of gold output was produced by the state (‘Gold mining and the state’, 58).Google Scholar

74 Garrard, , Akan Weights, 117.Google Scholar

75 Arhin, Kwame, ‘Aspects of the Ashanti northern trade in the nineteenth century’, Africa, LX (1970), 365–71.Google Scholar

76 Dumett, Raymond, ‘The rubber trade of the Gold Coast and Asante in the nineteenth century: African innovation and market responsiveness’, J. Afr. Hist., XII (1971), 94–5Google Scholar; Arhin, Kwame, ‘The economic and social significance of rubber production and exchange on the Gold and Ivory Coasts, 1880–1900’, Cah. Ét. Afr., LXXVII–LXXVIII (1980), 56–7, 71.Google Scholar

77 Terray, , ‘Gold production’, 119.Google Scholar

78 Garrard, , Akan Weights.Google Scholar

79 Bowdich, , Mission, 29, 30Google Scholar; Hutton, , Voyage, 196Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 23.Google Scholar

80 McCaskie, and Wiafe, , ‘A contemporary account’, 74.Google Scholar

81 The first point is clear, the second is the impression conveyed by the specialist studies, though neither makes the point explicitly: see Arhin, , ‘Market settlements’, 143–4Google Scholar, and Lovejoy, Paul E., Caravans of Kola: The Hausa Kola Trade 1700–1900 (Zaria, 1980), 21–2.Google Scholar

82 Dumett, , ‘Precolonial gold mining’, 44–7Google Scholar; compare Terray, , ‘Long-distance exchange’, 327–8Google Scholar, and ‘Gold production’, 101–6.Google Scholar

83 Arhin, , ‘Market settlements’, 136–7, 143–5Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Succession and gold mining’, 107–9Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Gold-mining and trading’, 92–3Google Scholar; Dumett, , ‘Traditional slavery’, 1718Google Scholar; Dumett, , ‘Rubber trade’, 94–5Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Economic and social significance’, 52–4, 61.Google Scholar

84 For a discussion of the trends in levels of various trades which are summarized in this paragraph, including such figures as are available, see Austin, , ‘Between abolition and jihad’.Google Scholar

85 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 28, 29Google Scholar; cf. Wilks, , Asante, 441–2.Google Scholar

86 The Western Echo, 1, 10 (24 02 1868), 8Google Scholar, reporting the views of T. B. Freeman. Quotation exactly as it appears in Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 29.Google Scholar

87 Wilks, , Asante, 101.Google Scholar

88 Bowdich, , Mission, 322–5.Google Scholar For later in the century see Brown, James Wilson, ‘Kumasi, 1896–1923: urban Africa during the early colonial period’ (Ph.D thesis, University of Wisconsin, Madison, 1972), 32–3.Google Scholar

89 Wilks, , Asante, 690.Google Scholar

90 G. Austin Fieldnotes: interview with Nana Owusu Sekyere, chief spokesman (Okyeame) of Kokofu, and Opanyin Kwesi Kaabi in Kokofu, 12 05 1980Google Scholar; interview, with elders of Aheuren, 07 1987Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 23, 45–6.Google Scholar

91 La Torre, , ‘Wealth’, 262–3.Google Scholar

92 Dupuis, , Journal, 167.Google Scholar

93 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 262.Google Scholar

94 Dupuis, , Journal, IX–X.Google Scholar

95 Ibid. 124.

96 Bowdich, , Mission, 257.Google Scholar

97 Wilks, , Asante, 437, 444, 685.Google Scholar

98 Asantehene Osaey Tutu Tutu Bonso (Osei Bonsu) to Danish governor, 17 05 1819Google Scholar, quoted and translated in Kea, R. A., ‘On preferential trade terms: a letter from Asantehene Osei Bonsu to the Danish governor (1819)’, Asantesem, X (1979), 55.Google Scholar

99 Letter from Governor Svanekiaer, 15 10 1819Google Scholar, in State Archives, Copenhagen, quoted and translated in Kea, , ‘On preferential trade terms’, 56.Google Scholar

100 Wilks, , Asante, 689.Google Scholar

101 Kea, , ‘On preferential trade terms’, 56–7.Google Scholar

102 Wilks, , Asante, 689.Google Scholar

103 Rattray, , Ashanti Law, 109–11.Google Scholar That Sapon of Mampon was Rattray's informant is explicit in Rattray's notes on the interview. See Royal Anthropological Institute, manuscript collection: R. S. Rattray papers, MS. 107: 2, pp. 1770, 1774–8.Google Scholar This collection is housed in the Museum of Mankind in London; cited with permission of the Director of the RAI.

104 Sapon, quoted in Rattray, , Ashanti Law, 111.Google Scholar So far no-one appears to have found evidence of this in the European archives, as Larry Yarak has confirmed after extensive work of his own on Dutch and British sources. As Yarak comments, if pre-emption was exercised in the southern trade it seems surprising that it was not reported in this voluminous documentation (personal communication). In principle it seems likely that the Asante government would have claimed a right of pre-emption in the southern trade, as did the king of Dahomey. See Law, , ‘Royal monopoly and private enterprise in the Atlantic trade’, 561, 568Google Scholar, citing Forbes's account of his 1850 visit.

105 Daaku, Kwame Y., ‘Akan trade in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries’Google Scholar, in Meillassoux, (ed.), Development of Indigenous Trade, especially 172–5.Google Scholar

106 See LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 409–13Google Scholar, and Yarak, , Asante and the Dutch, especially 106–11.Google Scholar

107 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 414.Google Scholar

108 Cf. Ibid. 408. At the time of writing Larry Yarak is engaged in further work on the Dutch ‘recruitment’ in Asante, which, among other things, may test this conclusion.

109 Hayford, J. H. Casely, Gold Coast Native Institutions (London, 1903), 28.Google Scholar

110 Bowdich, , Mission, 257.Google Scholar

111 Austin, Gareth, ‘Indigenous credit institutions in West Africa, c. 1750–c. 1960’, in Austin, G. and Sugihara, K. (eds.), Local Suppliers of Credit in the Third World, 1750–1960 (Basingstoke, 1993), 108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

112 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 194.Google Scholar

113 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 107.Google Scholar

114 Robertson, G. A., Notes on Africa (London, 1819), 178–81.Google Scholar

115 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adame, 358.Google Scholar

116 Arhin, , ‘Trade, accumulation and the state’, 528.Google Scholar

117 Ibid. 528–9; and see above.

118 Wilks, , Asante, 442.Google Scholar

119 Ibid. 7–12.

120 Bowdich, , Mission, 317.Google Scholar

121 Austin, Gareth, ‘Human pawning in Asante c. 1820–c. 1950: markets and coercion, gender and cocoa’, in Falola, T. and Lovejoy, P. (eds.), Pawnship in Africa (Boulder, 1994), 126, 133–4.Google Scholar

122 Boaten, Kwasi, ‘Trade among the Asante of Ghana up to the end of the 18th Century’, Research Review, VII (1970), 36.Google Scholar Cf. Poku, K., ‘Traditional roles and people of slave origin in modern Ashanti – a few impressions’, Ghana Journal of Sociology, V (1969), 37.Google Scholar T. B. Freeman implicitly accepted that commoners owned slaves when he questioned whether they, like chiefs, were allowed to sacrifice them at funerals (School of Oriental and African Studies Library, University of London: Methodist Missionary Society Archive, Papers of Thomas Birch Freeman, manuscript of unpublished book, n.d. but c. 1860, 38, 38b). Also, Bowdich referred to ‘the middling orders’ as slave owners (Bowdich, , Mission, 323Google Scholar). See, further, Arhin, , ‘Aspects of the Ashanti northern Trade’, 365.Google Scholar

123 Austin, , ‘Between abolition and jihad’.Google Scholar

124 Klein, , ‘Inequality in Asante’, especially vol. I, chs. 4 and 5.Google Scholar

125 For an admittedly late example, in 1896, see Musgrave, G. C., To Kumassi with Scott (London, 1896), 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

126 See especially Johnson, Marion, ‘The slaves of Salaga’, J. Afr. Hist., XXVII (1986), 349.Google Scholar

127 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 38, 173, 303Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Market settlements’, 144–5Google Scholar; Arhin, Kwame, West African Traders in Ghana in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (London, 1979), 59Google Scholar; Aidoo, , ‘Political crisis’, Part 2, 608.Google Scholar

128 Bowdich, , Mission, 332–3.Google Scholar

129 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 407Google Scholar, quoting Pel, H., Aanteekeningen gehouden op eene Rets van S. George d'Elmina naar Coomassie (Leiden, ?1842), 24.Google Scholar

130 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 414.Google Scholar

131 Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 45.Google Scholar

132 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 408Google Scholar, citing an interview with the then Amoafohene in 1975.

133 Arhin, , West African Traders, 43–4, 46–7.Google Scholar

134 African Studies Centre Library, University of Cambridge: Meyer Fortes papers, 8.39, Notebook entitled 'Asokore Bima II’, recording testimony of Kwasi Frompong (sic), n.d. but c. 1946.

135 Arhin, , ‘Market settlements’, 144–5.Google Scholar

136 Freeman, Richard Austin, Travels and Life in Ashanti and Jaman (London, 1967: 1st ed. 1898), 489.Google Scholar

137 Dumett, , ‘Precolonial gold mining’, 45–6Google Scholar; ‘Traditional slavery’, 1718.Google Scholar

138 Garrard, , Akan Weights, 145–8Google Scholar; cf. Curtin's, Philip D. analysis, for a Malian case, in ‘The lure of Bambuk gold’, J. Ajr. Hist., XIV (1973), 623–31.Google Scholar

139 Rattray papers, MS 106, p. 2033Google Scholar, quoted by Terray, , ‘Gold production’, 117.Google Scholar Cf. Cardinall, A. W., The Gold Coast, 1931 (Accra, n.d.), 78.Google Scholar

140 Cf. Law, , ‘Posthumous questions for Karl Polanyi’, 419.Google Scholar

141 Fortes papers, 8.2, Supplementary Notes on Marriage and Divorce Questionnaire.

142 Eldredge, Elizabeth, A South African Kingdom: The Pursuit of Security in Nineteenth-century Lesotho (Cambridge, 1993), 124.Google Scholar

143 Arhin, , ‘Trade and accumulation’, 529Google Scholar; West African Traders, 910.Google Scholar

144 Austin, , ‘Rural capitalism’, 143–7, 175–6.Google Scholar I Will elaborate in the manuscript I am currently writing.

145 Wilks, , Asante, 692–3.Google Scholar

146 Ibid. 697.

147 See, for example, Rattray, , Ashanti Law, 111Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 45–6, 210, 304–5.Google Scholar

148 Wilks, , Asante, 420–1.Google Scholar

149 LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 249Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse.Google Scholar

150 Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’, 63–4Google Scholar; LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 243.Google Scholar

151 Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 20.Google Scholar Earlier, Wilks had previously seen ayibuadie as a payment by certain important chiefs on succession to their stools, in addition to or instead of, awunyadie (Asante, 698).Google Scholar

152 Peredwan: an Asante gold weight conventionally valued at £8 sterling during the nineteenth century. For a refinement of this valuation see LaTorre, , ‘Wealth’, 207.Google Scholar

153 Bowdich, , Mission, 254Google Scholar: the passage quoted by Wilks, , ‘Golden Stool’, 20.Google Scholar

154 Bowdich, , Mission, 254.Google Scholar

155 Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’, 63–4Google Scholar; Rattray, , Ashanti, 226Google Scholar; Rattray, , Ashanti Law and Constitution, 140.Google Scholar

156 Wilks, , Asante, 697.Google Scholar

157 Arhin, , ‘Succession and gold mining’, 107Google Scholar; Daaku, , Oral Traditions of Adanse, 69, 217, 261.Google Scholar

158 Rattray, , Ashanti Law, 107–8, 140, 161–2, 186, 211–12, 229–30, 248–9.Google Scholar

159 Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’, 63.Google Scholar

160 Henty, G. A., The March to Coomassie (2nd ed., London, 1874), 360–1.Google Scholar

161 Dupuis, , Journal, 54.Google Scholar

162 A point of dispute between Bowdich, , Mission, 27Google Scholar, and Dupuis, , Journal, 54.Google Scholar

163 Wilks, , Asante, 713–15Google Scholar; compare with the criticism by LaTorre of that part of this evidence relating to former state traders in ‘Wealth’, 264–5.Google Scholar

164 As LaTorre pointed out: ‘Wealth’, 264.Google Scholar

165 Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’, 51.Google Scholar A similar analysis of the economic origins and social composition of the opposition was put forward by Aidoo, , ‘Order’, 1933Google Scholar, though by comparison with Wilks she emphasized what she saw as the ultimate limits of their ambitions and political strength: reformist rather than revolutionary, and weak compared to ‘the entrenched hereditary chiefs’ (26–7, 31).Google Scholar

166 Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’, 51.Google Scholar

167 Latorre, , ‘Wealth’, 264.Google Scholar

168 Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’, 52.Google Scholar Perhaps in recognition of the absence of evidence, in the 1993 edition of the essay the sentence has been revised and ‘the bourgeoisie’ deleted (Forests of Gold, 73).Google Scholar

169 Wilks, , Asante, 561–2: compare 470.Google Scholar

170 Ibid. 717.

171 Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’.Google Scholar More generally on rubber trading, exile and pride in wealth see Brown, , ‘Kumasi, 1896–1923’, 197–9.Google Scholar

172 Wilks, , Asante, 535–8.Google Scholar

173 Ibid. 535, 710.

174 As has been emphasized by Aidoo, , ‘Order’, 26Google Scholar; and Arhin, Kwame, ‘Rank and class among the Asante and Fante in the nineteenth century’, Africa, LIII (1983), 34.Google Scholar

175 I.e. chained him to a heavy piece of wood.

176 National Archives of Ghana, Ghana: ADM 11/1/773 ‘Bekwai Native Affairs’: item 115, ‘Ancient History of Bekwai Division’, written down by R.[?] Judd, W., District Commissioner, 4 06 1928.Google Scholar

177 McCaskie, , ‘Ahyiamu’.Google Scholar

178 The major source for this is a later petition from an interested party: National Archives of Ghana, Kumasi: File D3, ‘Death Duties’, Nketia, Cobina and twelve others to Chief Commissioner of Ashanti, Kumasi, 14 02 1908Google Scholar, reprinted in Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’, 70.Google Scholar See also Sraha, K. and others to Chief Commissioner, Kumasi, 11 10 1930Google Scholar, in the same file, reprinted ibid., 77. McCaskie rightly notes that we cannot be certain of the veracity of the statement (‘Ahyiamu’, 187Google Scholar). But for some confirmation see Rattray, , Ashanti Law, 135.Google Scholar

179 For opposition to such chiefs see Kirby's, report, 91–2.Google Scholar

180 Nketia, and others, 14 02 1908.Google Scholar

181 ‘The Ashantis’ to governor, Cape Coast, 15 12 1894Google Scholar, quoted in Wilks, , ‘Dissidence’, 59.Google Scholar

182 Ibid. 59 (restated in Forests, 180).Google Scholar

183 See the letters in Arhin, , ‘Some Asante views’.Google Scholar

184 Ibid. 82; Arhin, , ‘Note on the Asante akonkofo’, 28.Google Scholar

185 Austin, , ‘Between abolition and jihad’.Google Scholar

186 Hopkins, , Economic History, 124.Google Scholar

187 Dumett, , ‘Rubber trade’, 94–6 (the quotation is from p. 96)Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Aspects of the Ashanti northern trade’, 369, 371–2Google Scholar; Arhin, , ‘Economic and social significance’.Google Scholar

188 Austin, Gareth, ‘Capitalists and chiefs in the cocoa hold-ups in south Asante, 1927–1938’, Int. J. Afr. Hist. Studies, XXI (1988), 6395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

189 Hopkins, , Economic History, 143–4.Google Scholar

190 Austin, , ‘Between abolition and jihad’.Google Scholar

191 To use Hopkins' phrase: Economic History, 139.Google Scholar

192 On the NLM see Allman, Jean Marie, The Quills of the Porcupine: Asante Nationalism in an Emergent Ghana (Madison, Wisconsin, 1993).Google Scholar See also Rathbone, Richard, ‘“The youngmen and the porcupine”’, and Allman's reply, in J. Afr. Hist., XXXII (1991), 333–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

193 Austin, , ‘Capitalists and chiefs’.Google Scholar

194 Austin, , ‘Rural capitalism’Google Scholar; ‘Class struggle and rural capitalism in Asante history’, paper presented to the annual meeting of the African Studies Association, Chicago, 1988.