Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T05:28:12.592Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Missing link: the Views of the Second International School of Thought on Development, Underdevelopment and Dependency

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 April 2010

Marc Michielsen
Affiliation:
(Belgium)

Extract

In the long run, no country can avoid capitalism. No matter how bad the condition of the lower classes in a country in which they are defenselessly subjugated to the capitalist mode of production, they would still be worse off in a country that is economically under the spell of capitalist exploitation, whereas the ruling system does not give capitalist production the opportunity to arise; in a country where the population is proletarianized by the usurer, the merchant and by foreign competition, and where this proletariat cannot be absorbed by nascent big industries and cannot be gradually prepared for resistance against capitalism. The example of such a country is nowadays Turkey, and the Philippines will arrive at the same situation if the Spanish regime continues for a long time.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Research Institute for History, Leiden University 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

1 Brewer, Antony, Marxist Theories of Imperialism (London 1980) 127.Google Scholar

2 Barone, Charles A., Marxist Thought onImperialism (Armonk 1985) 56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Robinson cites Hobson, Hilferding, Lenin and Hallgarten.

4 Robinson, Ronald, ‘The Excentric Idea of Imperialism, with or without Empire’, in: Mommsen, Wolfgang J. and Osterhammel, Jurgen ed., Imperialism and After (London 1986) 268.Google Scholar

5 Braillard, Pierre and Senarclens, Pierre de, L'imperialisme (Paris 1980) 2137 and 81119;Google ScholarMommsen, Wolfgang, Theories of Imperialism (London 1980) 2958 and 113–141;Google ScholarBrewer, Antony, Marxist Theories of Imperialism, 79127 and 131–257Google Scholar.

6 See Gallagher, J. and Robinson, R., ‘The Imperialism of Free Trade, 1815–1914’, Economic History Review 6 (1953) 115;CrossRefGoogle ScholarRobinson, R., ‘Non-European Foundations of European Imperialism: Sketch for a Theory of Collaboration’ in: Owen, R. and Sutcliffe, B. ed., Studies in the Theory of Imperialism (London 1972) 117140;Google ScholarRobinson, Ronald, ‘The Excen-tric Idea of Imperialism’, 269289Google Scholar.

7 Brewer, Antony, Marxist Theories of Imperialism, 133.Google Scholar

8 The Second International existed between the years 1889 and 1923. The hey-day of this school of thought can be situated between the years 1896 and 1918. The activities of the school centered around Die Neue Zeit, which was at that time the world's leading Marxian scientific review. For more details, see my dissertation: Marc Michielsen, ‘Empires, impérialismes, sous-devéloppement et relations internationales: Hobson, l'école de la lie Internationale, Lénine et la théorie de l'impérialisme (1897–1918)’ (Unpublished Ph.D.-thesis; Louvain-la-Neuve 1988).

9 Hobson, John Atkinson, Democracy after the War (London 1917) 113.Google Scholar

10 Kautsky discussed capitalist expansion at different occasions. He also adopted different points of view. Brought together, his analyses form a kind of mosaic. In 1898 Kautsky distinguished between an old and a new colonial policy. On e year later he focused on the role of Great Britain. In 1901 he discussed the commercial policies which accompanied the two periods. In 1907 he refined his analysis of 1898 by distinguishing between settler colonies and colonies of exploitation and he centered on the present period of imperialist expansion. In 1914 he explained the presence of expansionist tendencies by analysing the differences in the rate of development of agriculture and industry. (Kautsky, Karl, ‘Altere und neuere Kolonialpolitik’, Die Neue Zeit 16, 1 (18971898) 769781 and 800–817;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Der Krieg in Sudafrika’, Die Neue Zeit 18, 1 (1899–1900) 196–203; Idem, Handelspolilik und Sozialdemokratie (Berlin 1901); Idem, Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik -Eine Auseinanderset-zung (Berlin 1907); Idem, ‘Der Imperialismus’, Die Neue Zeit 22, 2 (1913–1914) 908–922).

11 Kautsky, , ‘Altere and neuere Kolonialpolitik’, 770 and 780, 802, 806.Google Scholar

12 Kautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinandersetzung, 24.Google Scholar

13 Kautsky, , Handelspolitik und Sozialdemokratie, 10, 14.Google Scholar

14 Kautsky, ‘Altere und neuere Kolonialpolitik’, 780. According to Kautsky the Peace of Paris (1763), which ended the presence of French absolutism in Canada, accelerated this evolution.

15 Kautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinanderselzung, 32,33.Google Scholar

16 Kautsky, , ‘Der Krieg in Südafrika’, 198.Google Scholar

17 Kautsky, , Handelspolitik and Sozialdemokratie, 35.Google Scholar

18 Kautsky, , Sozialismus and Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinandersetzung, 3639.Google Scholar

19 Kautsky, , ‘Der Krieg in Sudafrika’, 199Google Scholar. Imperialism is defined by Kautsky and Parvus as a policy that seeks to establish a union between an industrial state and its colonies (which are of an agricultural character), both being linked by a protective tariff (Parvus, , Die Kolonialpolitik and der zusammenbruch (Leipzich 1907) 97Google Scholar; Kautsky, , ‘Der Krieg in Sudafrika’, 199;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Der Imperialismus’, 909).

20 Parvus, , Die Kolonialpolitik und der Zusammenbruch, 3942.Google Scholar

21 Kautsky, , ‘Der Imperialismus’, 919.Google Scholar

22 Kautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinandersetzung, 66;Google ScholarIdem, Weg zur Macht: Politische Belrachtungen über das Hineinwachsen in die Revolution (Berlin 1909) 89–95; Idem, ‘Der Imperialismus’, 920–921.

23 Parvus, , Die Kolonialpolitik und der Zusammenbruch, 7892.Google Scholar

24 At first colonial powers used their colonies as a source of luxuries and valuables. Laler on colonies became a source of consumer goods and of raw materials. Finally they became markets.

25 Parvus, , Die Kolonialpolitik und der Zusammenbruch, 97 and 108–109.Google Scholar

26 See note 14.

27 Parvus and Kautsky both rejected the imperialist policybecause of its impracticability. Parvus concentrated on the economicaspect of the problem, while Kautsky (who also acknowledged the impossibility of economic autarky) considered above all the political effects of imperialism: the costly character of inter-imperialist rivalry and the awakening of the peoples of the East and of the Islamic world.

28 Proposals and Drafts of Resolutions with Explanatory Reports Submitted to the International Socialist Congress ofStuttgart (18–24 August 1907). International Socialist Bureau (Brussels s.d.) 510, reprinted in: Congrès sodaliste international - Stuttgart 18–24 août 1907 (Genève 1978) 510;Google ScholarKautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinandersetzung, 29;Google ScholarHilferding, Rudolf, Das Finanzkapital (Wien 1910) 405Google Scholar.

29 Congrès socialiste international d'Amsterdam des 14–20 aout 1904 - Rapports et projets de rèsolutions sur les questions de I'ordre du jour. Le secrétariat socialiste international (Bruxelles 1904) 37–38, reprinted in: Haupt, Georges ed., Congrés socialiste international Amsterdam 14–20 aout 1904 (Geneva 1980) 7374Google Scholar.

30 Proposals and Drafts ofResolutions with Explanatory Reports Submitted to the International Socialist Congress of Stuttgart (18–24 August 1907) 494.

31 Congrés socialiste international d'Amsterdam des 14–20 août 1904, 713/269–275.

32 Ibidem, 55–60/91–96.

33 Ibidem, 82/118.

34 Septiéme congres sodaliste international lenu à Stuttgart du 18 au 24 août 1907, compte rendu analytique. Bureau socialiste international (Bruxelles 1908) 314, reprinted in: Haupt, Georges ed., Congiès sodaliste international - Stuttgart 18–24 août 1907 (Geneva 1980) 644Google Scholar.

35 Van Kol and some rightist Socialists have argued that the road to Socialism led through capitalism and colonial policy. Kautsky rejected this point of view. Even if one could not escape capitalism, one did not have to pass by the same stages to arrive at a higher level of development (Proposals and Drafts of Resolutions with Explanatory Reports Submitted to the International Sotialist Congress of Stuttgart (18–24 August 1907), 56–57).

36 Ibidem, 76–77.

37 Kautsky, , Handelspolitik and Sozialdemokratie, 4546.Google Scholar

38 Pawlowitsch, Michel, ‘Die persische Revolution, ihre Ursachen, ihr Character und ihre Kampfesmethoden’, Die Neue ze1t 28, 2 (1909–1910) 50.Google Scholar

39 Tschilinkirian, Arschavir, ‘Die wirtschaftliche and sozialen Ursachen der persischen Revolution’, Die Neue Zeit 28, 1 (19091910) 202204 and 234–235.Google Scholar

40 Radek, Karl, ‘Die Lage in Marokko’, Die Neue Zeit 28, 1 (19091910) 582;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Der neue Marokkokurs Deutschlands’, Die Neue Zeit 29, 2 (1910–1911) 649; Rothstein, Theodor, ‘Die Englander in Ägypten’, ErgänzungsheflezurNeuen Zeit 07 1911 (no. 10) 512;Google ScholarRothstein, Theodor, ‘Internationale Finanz and Politik in China’, Die Neue Zeit 31, 1 (19121913) 627638;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Chinas Erdrosselung’, Die Neue Zeit 31, 2 (1912–1913) 343–344.

41 Hilferding, Rudolf, Das Einanzkapital, 418419.Google Scholar

42 Kautsky, , ‘Der Imperialismus’, p918Google Scholar.

43 Kautsky, , ‘Der amerikanische Arbeiter’, Die Neue Zeit 24, 1 (19051906) 678683 and 717–719.Google Scholar

44 Kautsky, , ‘Der Imperialismus’, 918.Google Scholar

45 Kautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Ausdnandersetzung, 42;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Der Imperialis-mus’, 918; Hilferding, Rudolf, Das Finanzkapital, 406Google Scholar.

46 Beer, Max, ‘Imperialistische Politik’, Die Neue Zeit 21, 1 (19021903) 391.Google Scholar

47 Kautsky, Karl, ‘Der amerikanische Arbeiter’, 680.Google Scholar

48 The collapse of a weak state structure (in the Egyptian case: Rothstein, ‘Die Englander in Agypten’, 5–12), the underdeveloped character or the absence of a state (Kautsky, , Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik - Eine Auseinandersetzung, 43;Google ScholarHilferding, , Das Finanzkapilal, 405406) leads to formal dominationGoogle Scholar.

49 Cunow, Heinrich, ‘Die wirtschaftliche Lage Chinas’, Die Neue Zeit 18, 2 (18991900) 524.Google Scholar

50 ‘Resolution carried on October, 1lth 1908, on the political situation’, Bulletin periodique du Bureau Socialiste International 1, 5 (1910) 127, reprinted in: Bureau Socialiste International (Geneva 1979) 137;Google ScholarManifesto of the International against the War’, Bulletin périodique du Bureau Socialiste International 3, 9 (1912) 3Google Scholar, reprinted: in Bureau Socialiste International (Genera 1979) 441Google Scholar.

51 Kabaktschieff, Christo, ‘Fürstenbund oder Balkanrepublik?’, Die Neue Zeit 31, 1 (19121913) 316.Google Scholar

52 Rothstein, , ‘Die Englander in Ägypten’, 40;Google ScholarIdem, ‘Internationale Finanz und Politik in China’, 627–638.

53 Bauer, Otto, ‘Die Arbeiterklasse und die Schutzzolle’, Die Neue Zeit 23, 1 (19041905) 537. According to Bauer,tariffs should be established to compensate for this inequality.Google Scholar

54 Renner, Karl, Marxismus, Krieg und Internationale (Stuttgart 1917) 210219.Google Scholar

55 Rothstein, , ‘Die Englander in Agypten’, 40.Google Scholar

56 The same thing can be said of Davis and Huttenback's recent book Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire. Intended as a critique of the theories of Hobson and Lenin, O'Brien demonstrated that the book rather confirms than invalidates Hobson's thought. (See: Davis, Lance E. and Huttenback, Robert A., Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire (London 1986);Google ScholarO'Brien, Patrick K., ‘The Costs and Benefits of British Imperialism 1846–1914’, Past and Present (08 1988) 163200)Google Scholar.