Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T16:32:15.677Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

IL NEO-ISTITUZIONALISMO IN SCIENZA POLITICA: IL CONTRIBUTO DELLA TEORIA DELLA SCELTA RAZIONALE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 July 2018

Introduzione

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Insieme alla ripresa di interesse per il tema dello stato, lo studio delle istituzioni è tornato al centro dell'analisi politologica. È opinione condivisa che il rinnovato interesse per le istituzioni rappresenti una reazione alla rivoluzione comportamentista, la quale a sua volta - con l'enfasi sul comportamento osservabile e sui processi informali di potere e influenza - reagiva all'impostazione legalistica e formalistica degli esordi della disciplina. Ciò che, non senza qualche eccesso polemico, è stato definito uno «slittamento paradigmatico» ha coinvolto una varietà di approcci, accomunati dal riconoscimento dei limiti della behavioral persuasion, e in particolare dei due orientamenti teorici ad essa associati in scienza politica: il pluralismo, con l'accento posto sulla politica come processo e la conseguente messa in ombra degli elementi strutturali, e il funzionalismo, un approccio tendenzialmente più inclusivo ma che in scienza politica si è identificato sostanzialmente con la versione almondiana. Rispetto ai più ambiziosi tentativi teorici del funzionalismo sociologico, essa ha fornito soprattutto uno schema categoriale per l'analisi comparata dei sistemi politici, in cui è attribuito rilievo centrale alle funzioni di input o ai processi che vanno dalla società alla politica.

Summary

Summary

In the last decade several remarkable developments within the rational choice approach have been known as New Institutionalism. The renewal of interest in economic and political institutions springs from the recognition of the shortcomings of behavioral revolution in political science and the explicative inadequacies of neoclassical paradigm in economics. Within the New Institutionalism a number of different lines of investigation can be distinguished.

This essay focuses on political institutions with two aims: 1) to identify two main strands of research, one rooted in the positive political theory, particularly in the social choice literature, the other one in the transaction costs economics, in order to show their analytical similarities and to illustrate potential extensions to the study of parliamentary systems and to the analysis of the development of modern representative institutions.

Some general implications of the analysis are drawn and objections to the overall line of inquiry are discussed in the concluding section.

Type
RASSEGNE
Copyright
Copyright © Societ Italiana di Scienza Politica 

References

Riferimenti bibliografici

Alchian, A. e Demsetz, H. (1972), Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization, in «American Economic Review», LXII, pp. 777795.Google Scholar
Almond, G.A. (1988), The Return to the State, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXII, 3, pp. 853900.Google Scholar
Tullio-Altan, C. (1990), Political Science: A Discipline Divided, Beverly Hills and London, Sage.Google Scholar
Almond, G.A., Flanagan, S.C. e Mundt, R. (a cura di) (1973), Crisis, Choice and Change, Boston, Little & Brown.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1970), The Market for «Lemons»: Quality, Uncertainty and Market Mechanisms, in «Quarterly Journal of Economics», LXXXIV, pp. 488500.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books; trad. it. Giochi di reciprocità, Milano, Feltrinelli, 1985.Google Scholar
Arrow, K.J. (1963), Social Choice and Individual Values, New York, Wiley, 2a edizione; trad. it. Scelte sociali e valori individuali, Milano, Etas Kompass, 1974.Google Scholar
Barney, J.B. e Ouchi, W.G. (1986), Organizational Economics, San Francisco, Jossey Bass.Google Scholar
Bates, R.H. e Lien, D. (1985), A Note on Taxation, Development and Representative Government, in «Politics and Society», XIV, pp. 5370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendor, J. e Mookherjee, D. (1987), Institutional Structure and the Logic of Ongoing Collective Action, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXI, pp. 129–54.Google Scholar
Black, D. (1948), On The Rationale of Group Decision-Making, in «Journal of Political Economy», LVI, pp. 2334.Google Scholar
Black, D. (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections, London, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bowman, J. (1989), Transaction Costs and Politics, in «Archives européenne de sociologie», XXX, pp. 150168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J.M. e Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1937), The Nature of the Firm, in «Economica», IV, pp. 386485; trad it. in G. Brosio (a cura di), La teoria economica dell'organizzazione, Bologna, Il Mulino, 1989, pp. 167-193.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York, Harper & Row, 1957; trad. it. Teoria economica della democrazia, Bologna, Il Mulino, 1988.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, T. (1990), Economic Behavior and Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Enelow, J.M. e Hinich, M.J. (1984), The Spatial Theory of Voting. An Introduction, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Black, D. (1990), Advances in Spatial Theory of Voting, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, P.B., Rueschemeier, D. e Skocpol, T. (1985), Bringing The State Back In, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Farquharson, R. (1969), Theory of Voting, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Frey, B.S. (1984), A New View of Economics: Comparative Analysis of Institutions, in «Economia delle Scelte Pubbliche», II, pp. 316.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. e Maskin, E. (1986), The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with scounting or with Incomplete Information, in «Econometrica», LIV, pp. 533–54.Google Scholar
Gamm, G. e Shepsle, K.A. (1989), Emergence of Legislative Institutions: Standing Committees in the House and the Senate, 1810-1825, in «Legislative Studies Quarterly», XIV, pp. 3966.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. (1977), Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press; trad. it. Comportamento razionale e equilibrio di contrattazione, Milano, Il Saggiatore, 1985.Google Scholar
Hetcher, M. (1990), On the Inadequacy of Game Theory for the Solution of Real-World Collective Action Problems, in K. Cook e M. Levi (a cura di), The Limits of Rationality, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, pp. 240249.Google Scholar
Krasner, S.D. (1984), Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics, in «Comparative Politics», XVI, 2, pp. 223246.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K. (1988), Spatial Models of Legislative Choice, in «Legislative Studies Quarterly», XIII, pp. 259319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, K. (1987), Why Are Congressional Committees Powerful?, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXI, pp. 929–35.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, K. (1990), Information and Legislative Institutions, University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Kreps, D.M. e Wilson, R. (1982), Reputation and Imperfect Information, in «Journal of Economic Theory», XXVIII, pp. 253–79.Google Scholar
Laver, M. e Schofield, N. (1990), Multiparty Governments: The Politics of Coalition in Europe, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Levi, M. (1988), Of Rule and Revenue, Berkeley, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, D. (1962), Convention. A Philosophical Study, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Luce, R.D. e Raiffa, H. (1957), Games and Decisions, New York, Wiley.Google Scholar
March, J.G. e Olsen, J.P. (1984), The New Institutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXVIII, pp. 734749.Google Scholar
March, J.G. e Olsen, J.P. (1989), Rediscovering Institutions, New York, The Free Press; trad. it. Riscoprire le istituzioni, Bologna, Il Mulino, 1992.Google Scholar
Martelli, P. (1983), La logica della scelta collettiva, Milano, D Saggiatore.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R.D. (1976), Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control, in «Journal of Economic Theory», XII, pp. 472–82.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. e Roberts, J. (1988), An Economic Approach to Influence Activities in Organizations, «American Journal of Sociology», XCIV, supplemento speciale, pp. 154–79.Google Scholar
Miller, N.R., Grofman, B. e Feld, S.L. (1989), The Geometry of Maiority Rule, in «Journal of Theoretical Politics», I, 379406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, T.M. (1984), The New Economics of Organization, in «American Journal of Political Science», XXVIII, pp. 739777.Google Scholar
March, J.G. e Olsen, J.P. (1990a), The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy, in O.A. Williamson (a cura di), Organization Theory, Oxford University Press, pp. 116153.Google Scholar
March, J.G. e Olsen, J.P. (1990b), Political Institutions: The Neglected Side of the Story, in «Journal of Law, Economics and Organization», VI.Google Scholar
Monroe, K.R. (a cura di) (1990) The Nature of Contemporary Political Science: A Roundtable Discussion, in «PS: Political Science & Politics», XXIII, 1, pp. 3444.Google Scholar
March, J.G. e Olsen, J.P. (1991), The Economic Approach to Politics, New York, Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Morlino, L. (1989), Epitaffio per un approccio di successo: il sistema politico, in A. Panebianco (a cura di), L'analisi della politica. Tradizioni di ricerca, modelli, teorie, Bologna, Il Mulino, pp. 7187.Google Scholar
Mueller, D.C. (1989), Public Choice II, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nordlinger, E.A. (1987), Taking the State Seriously, in S.P. Huntington e J.M. Nelson, Understanding Political Development, Beverly Hills and London, Sage, pp. 353388.Google Scholar
North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D.C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
North, D.C. e Weingast, B.R. (1989), Constitutions and Commitment: Evolutions of the Institutions Governing Public Choice in 17th Century England, in «Journal of Economic History», II, pp. 803–32.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, P.C. (1990), The Emerging Discipline of Political Economy, in Alt, J.E. e Shepsle, K.A. (a cura di), Perspectives on Positive Political Theory, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, P.C. e Shepsle, K.A. (a cura di) (1981), Political Equilibrium, Boston, Kluwer-Nijhoff.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1991), Rational Choice Theory and Institutional Analysis: Toward Complementarity, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXV, pp. 237–43.Google Scholar
Plott, C.R. (1967), A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility Under Maiority Rule, in «American Economic Review», LVII, pp. 787806.Google Scholar
North, D.C. (1976), Axiomatic Social Choice Theory: An Overview and Interpretation, in «American Journal of Political Science», pp. 511–95.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971), A Theory of Justice, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press; trad. it. Una teoria della giustizia, Milano, Feltrinelli, 1982.Google Scholar
Richter, R. (1984), The New Institutional Economics, in «Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics», CXL, pp. 16.Google Scholar
Riker, W.H. (1962), The Theory of Political Coalitions, New Haven, Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, W.H. (1980), Implications From the Disequilibrium of Maiority Rule for the Study of Institutions, in «American Political Science Review», LXXIV, pp. 432446.Google Scholar
Riker, W.H. (1990), Political Science and Rational Choice, dattiloscritto, Università di Rochester.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 2a ed. 1980.Google Scholar
Schofield, N. (1978), Instability of Simple Dynamic Games, in «The Review of Economic Studies», XLV, pp. 575–94.Google Scholar
Schotter, A. (1981), The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. (1979), Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models, in «American Journal of Political Science», XXIII, pp. 2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. (1986), Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions, in H. Weisberg (a cura ai), Political Science: The Science of Politics, New York, Agathon Press, pp. 5181.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. (1989), Studying Institutions: Some Lessons From the Rational Choice Approach, in «Journal of Theoretical Politics», I, pp. 131147.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Laver, M. (1990a), Coalitions and Cabinet Government, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXIV, 3, pp. 873891.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Laver, M. (1990b), Government Coalitions and Intraparty Politics, in «British Journal of Political Science», XX, pp. 489507.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Laver, M. (1990c), Size Principle and Minority Cabinets, paper presentato alla Conferenza in onore di W.H. Riker, Rochester, 12-13 ottobre.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B.R. (1981), Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice, in «Public Choice», XXXVII, pp. 221–37.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B.R. (1987), Foundations of Committee Power, in «American Political Science Review», LXXXI, pp. 85104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H.A. (1957), Models of Man, New York, Wiley.Google Scholar
Strom, K. (1990), Minority Governments and Maiority Rule, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, M. (1976), Anarchy and Cooperation, New York, Wiley.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. (1986), Hierarchies and Bureaucracies, in «Journal of Law, Economics and Organization», II, pp. 235–59.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1981), Why So Much Stability?, in «Public Choice», XXXVII, pp. 189202.Google Scholar
Ulmann-Margalit, E. (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Urbani, G. (1989), La teoria del sistema politico: prospettive, in A. Panebianco (a cura di), L'analisi della politica. Tradizioni di ricerca, modelli, teorie, Bologna, Il Mulino, pp. 89102.Google Scholar
Weingast, B.R. (1990), The Role of Credible Commitments in State Finance, in «Public Choice», LXVI, pp. 8997.Google Scholar
Weingast, B.R. e Marshall, W. (1988), The Industrial Organization of Congress: or Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets, in «Journal of Political Economy», XCVI, pp. 132163; trad. it. parziale in G. Brosio (a cura di), La teoria economica dell'organizzazione, Bologna, 11 Mulino, 1989, pp. 435-467.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.A. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies, New York, The Free Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B.R. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York, The Free Press; trad. it. Le istituzioni economiche del capitalismo, Milano, Franco Angeli, 1988.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B.R. (1990a), Organization Theory. From Chester Barnard to Now, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K.A. e Weingast, B.R. (1990b), A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Organization, in «Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics», CXLVI, pp. 6171.Google Scholar
Zolberg, A.R., Strategic Interaction and the Formation of Modern States: France and England, in «International Social Science Journal», XXXII, 687716.Google Scholar