Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T04:07:08.777Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Origins of the “Temple-Economy” as seen in the Light of Prehistoric Evidence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 August 2014

Extract

The “temple-state theory” of Mesopotamian economy was first propounded by A. Deimel. Unfortunately, he unjustifiably considered his reconstruction to be normative for the whole area and the entire history of Mesopotamia. Subsequent research by Gelb and Diakonoff has shown that temple holdings and economy were but one form of economic life during the third millennium. It would appear that in the course of the third millennium a large part of the “Gross National Product” was in fact produced by the holdings of private owners, the community lands owned by clans, extended families or, to use Diakonoff's term, obschinas. Little attention has, however, been paid to the fact that only a minor share of these products could have been accumulated, re-invested or utilized through long-distance trade by private entrepreneurs. Temple economy most probably participated in the accumulation, redistribution and mobilization of goods to a much larger degree than its own production.

The problem of why, how and when economic goods, and later still, land itself came into the ownership of the temple, an originally non-economic organization, is still open to debate. According to Gelb, land was owned by the tribe, the clan or the community during the early—not defined more precisely—periods of Mesopotamian history, in the time of the primitive communities. He went on to propose that land came under temple ownership when with the fully established centralized state organization and more advanced agricultural economy, the village land controlled by tribes and clans gave way to public land controlled by the crown, temple and nobility. Diakonoff suggested that temple estates gradually absorbed public or community holdings during the Uruk IV–III period at the latest, but perhaps at an even earlier date. Both opinions give a terminus ante quem rather than a chronologically exact date.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The British Institute for the Study of Iraq 1983

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Select bibliography

Tell es-Sawwan preliminary reports in Sumer 21 (1965), 1732; 22 (1966), b; 23 (1967), a–c and 167–76; 20 (1964), 1–2; 24 (1968), 3–15 and 57–60; 26 (1970), 3–20; 27 (1971), 3–7; 28 (1972), b.Google Scholar
Yarim Tepe preliminary reports in Sumer 25 (1969), 125–31; 27 (1971), 9–22 and 23–32; 29 (1973), 3–16; 32 (1976), 25–61; R. M. Munchaev—N. J. Merpert: Earliest agricultural settlements of Northern Mesopotamia (Moscow, 1981), passim.Google Scholar
Beale, T. W.Bevelled rim bowls and their implications for change and economic organisation in the later fourth millennium B.C. (JNES 37 (1978), 289313).Google Scholar
Deimel, A.Šumerische Tempelwirtschaft zur Zeit Urukaginas undseiner Vorgänger (AnOr 2; Roma, 1931).Google Scholar
Diakonoff, I. M.The structure of Near Eastern Society before the Middle of the 2nd Millennium B.C. (Oikumene 3 (1982), 7100).Google Scholar
Falkenstein, A.La cité-temple sumérienne (Cahiers d'histoire mondiale 1: 4 (1954), 784814).Google Scholar
Gelb, I. J.On the alleged temple and state economies in Ancient Mesopotamia (Studi in Onore di E. Volterra, vol. VI (Roma, 1969), 137–54).Google Scholar
Gelb, I. J.From freedom to slavery (in Gesellschaftsklassen im Alten Zweistromland (XVIII R.A.I.; München, 1972), 8192).Google Scholar
Gibson, McGuire. Violation of fallow and engineered disaster in Mesopotamian civilisation (in Irrigation's impact on Society, ed. by Downing, T. E. and Gibson, McG. (Tucson, 1974), 717).Google Scholar
Gibson, McGuire. By stage and cycle to Sumer (in The Legacy of Sumer (Bibliotheca Mesopotamica 1; Malibu, 1976), 51–8).Google Scholar
Jawad, A. J.The advent of the era of townships in Northern Mesopotamia (Leiden, 1965).Google Scholar
Lamberg-Karlovsky, C. C. The economic world of Sumer (in The Legacy of Sumer, op. cit., 59–68).Google Scholar
Kirkbride, D.Umm Dabaghiyah: a trading outpost? (Iraq 36 (1974), 8592).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maisler, B., Stekelis, M., Avi-Yonah, M.The excavations at Beth Yerah (Khirbet el-Kerak), 1944–1946 (IEJ 2 (1952), 165–73 and 218–29).Google Scholar
Moorey, P. R. S.The late prehistoric administrative building at Jamdat Nasr (Iraq 38 (1976), 95106).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oppenheim, A. L.Ancient Mesopotamia. Portrait of a dead civilisation (Chicago, 1964), 89–90, 111, 187–90).Google Scholar
Speiser, E. A.Excavations at Tepe Gawra, vol. I (Philadelphia, 1935), 31–2.Google Scholar