Published online by Cambridge University Press: 18 December 2008
The issue of “spontaneity versus organisation” has provoked constant controversy within labour movements, at least since the polemic between Lenin and Luxemburg in the first years of this century. The rise of mass social-democratic parties and national industrial unions generated a familiar dilemma for the left: an apparent contradiction between direct, localised and immediate collective expressions of working-class experience and aspirations – with the virtues of authenticity and self-activity – and the centralised, co-ordinated and disciplined institutions which strategic efficacy seemingly required. Experience of the particularly bureaucratic and authoritarian German movement helped inspire Michels' eloquent thesis that hierarchical organisational structures were unavoidable, yet inevitably resulted in conservative and anti-democratic outcomes. Others – most notably, perhaps, the Webbs – insisted that oligarchy could be avoided by appropriate organisational engineering; yet others, implicitly endorsing Michels' equation, proposed syndicalist strategies for avoiding institutional discipline. Subsequently the Third International, with its concept of “democratic centralism”, sought to dissolve the whole issue by what critics regarded as a definitional sleight-of-hand.
1 Webb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, A History of Trade Unionism (London, 1894), p. vii.Google Scholar
2 I borrow this terminology from Allan Flanders' usage (in a rather different context).
3 Jefferys, James B., The Story of the Engineers (London, 1945).Google Scholar
4 Hobsbawm, E.J., “Trade Union Historiography”, Bulletin of the Society for the Study of Labour History, 4 (1964).Google Scholar
5 Brown, E.H. Phelps, The Growth of British Industrial Relations (London, 1959).Google Scholar
6 Cole, G.D.H. and Postgate, Raymond, The Common People (London, 1938).Google Scholar
7 Zeitlin, Jonathan, “From Labour History to the History of Industrial Relations”, Economic History Review, XL (1987).Google Scholar
8 Our respective contributions to the conference were summarised in the Bulletin of the Society for the Study of Labour History, 46 (1983).Google Scholar
9 A couple of illustrations must suffice. In 1875 an Association of Trade Union Officials was reportedly formed to protect full-time officers from “unjust” criticism by dissatisfied members (Fraser, W. Hamish, Trade Unions and Society (London, 1974), p. 65)Google Scholar; in 1908 George Barnes resigned as secretary of the Engineers, protesting that “there had been the development of an undemocratic feeling in the trade unions which worked out in the direction of mistrust of officials and officialdom” (quoted in Jefferys, , Story of the Engineers, p. 168).Google Scholar
10 Roberts, Geoff, “The Strategy of Rank-and-Filism”, Marxism Today (12, 1976).Google Scholar
11 Holton, Bob, British Syndicalism 1900–1914 (London, 1976), p. 23.Google Scholar
12 Holton, , British Syndicalism, p. 204.Google Scholar
13 White, Joseph L., The Limits of Trade Union Militancy (Westport, 1978), p. 180.Google Scholar
14 See also White, Joe, “1910–1914 Reconsidered” in Cronin, James E. and Schneer, Jonathan (eds), Social Conflict and the Political Order in Modern Britain (London, 1982)Google Scholar; in this survey he is concerned to emphasise the very specific sources of militancy in different industries, unions and regions.
15 Burgess, Keith, The Origins of British Industrial Relations (London, 1975), pp. 308–310.Google Scholar
16 Burgess, , The Challenge of Labour (London, 1980).Google Scholar
17 Burgess, , Origins of British Industrial Relations, p. 309.Google Scholar
18 See for example Burgess, “New Unionism for Old? The Amalgamated Society of Engineers in Britain” in Mommsen, Wolfgang J. and Husung, Hans-Gerhard (eds), The Development of Trade Unionism in Great Britain and Germany, 1880–1914 (London, 1985).Google Scholar
19 Price, Richard, Masters, Unions and Men (Cambridge, 1980).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
20 Price, , “Rethinking Labour History: the Importance of Work”Google Scholar in Cronin, and Schneer, , Social Conflict and the Political OrderGoogle Scholar; “The Labour Process and Labour History”, Social History, VII (1983)Google Scholar; “The New Unionism and the Labour Process” in Mommsen, and Husung, , Development of Trade Unionism.Google Scholar
21 Price, , Labour in British Society (London, 1986), p. 12.Google Scholar
22 Cronin, James E., Industrial Conflict in Modern Britain (London, 1979), p. 195.Google Scholar
23 Cronin, , Labour and Society in Britain 1918–1979 (London, 1984), p. vii.Google Scholar
24 Hinton, James, The First Shop Stewards' Movement (London, 1973), p. 13.Google Scholar
25 Hinton, , Labour and Socialism (London, 1983)Google Scholar; “Disconnecting Socialist Aspiration from Class Consciousness”, Bulletin of the Society for the Study of Labour History, 51 (1986).Google Scholar
26 Hyman, Richard, The Workers' Union (Oxford, 1971).Google Scholar
27 Hinton, and Hyman, , Trade Unions and Revolution (London, 1975).Google Scholar
28 Hyman, , “Mass Organisation and Militancy in Britain: Contrasts and Continuities”Google Scholar in Mommsen, and Husung, , Development of Trade Unionism, p. 262.Google Scholar In part my argument involves a rejection of Price's interpretation of the pre-war “labour unrest”: as Price notes in his response to Zeitlin, the seven supposed representatives of the rank-and-filist school spend a considerable amount of time criticising each other. I have myself published critical reviews of works of Burgess, Cronin and Price in, respectively, International Socialism, 90 (1976)Google Scholar; Bulletin of the Society for the Study of Labour History, 40 (1980)Google Scholar; and Labour/le Travail, 13 (1984).Google Scholar
29 Hyman, , “Rank-and-File Movements and Workplace Organisation, 1914–39” in Wrigley, Chris J. (ed.), A History of British Industrial Relations, Vol. 2:1914–39 (Brighton, 1988).Google Scholar
30 The Kuhnian notion of paradigm – a set of ontological and epistemological assumptions underlying a protracted phase of “normal science” – is clearly not appropriate as a characterisation of what Zeitlin terms “rank-and-filism”.
31 Frank Rose of the ASE, quoted in Hinton, , First Shop Stewards' Movement, pp. 82–83.Google Scholar
32 See, for example, the sensitive analysis in Brown, Phelps, Growth of British Industrial Relations, pp. 228–235.Google Scholar
33 A notable instance is the study of industrial conflict in Manchester docks (Woodward, J. et al. , The Dock Worker, Liverpool, 1955Google Scholar), which identified a mutually conditioning dialectic of official union conservatism and successful rank-and-file militancy.
34 Zeitlin has developed these arguments in various contexts; for example, “The Emergence of Shop Steward Organisation and Job Control in the British Car Industry”, History Workshop Journal, 10 (1980)Google Scholar; Shop Floor Bargaining and the State (ed., with Steven Tolliday, Cambridge, 1985)Google Scholar; and “Industrial Structure, Employer Strategy and the Diffusion of Job Control” in Mommsen, and Husung, , Development of Trade Unionism.Google Scholar
35 Hinton, with his insistence that “socialism is the aspiration of a community, not the destiny of a class” (“Disconnecting Socialist Aspiration”, p. 39Google Scholar) is in this respect exceptional.
36 It is worth noting that while “class” is a category at odds with detailed empirical reality, the same is true of the notion of the “state” – a term which Zeitlin employs without embarrassment.
37 I have attempted to grapple with a number of relevant issues in essays compiled in my recent collection The Political Economy of Industrial Relations (London, 1989).Google Scholar
38 Gramsci, Antonio, Selections from Political Writings, 1910–1920 (ed. Hoare, Quintin, London, 1977), p. 265.Google Scholar
39 Gramsci, , Political Writings, pp. 285–286.Google Scholar
40 Muste, A.J., “Factional Fights in Trade Unions” in Hardman, J.B.S. (ed.), American Labor Dynamics in the Light of Post-War Developments (New York, 1928).Google Scholar
41 Zeitlin is perhaps over-influenced by the arguments of Muste, who wrote in the context of inter-war USA. Partly because of forceful anti-union drives by major employers, the indifference or hostility of state and federal governments towards unions, and perhaps also the lack of cohesion among an ethnically differentiated labour force, grassroots organisation was relatively weak and union structures were strongly hierarchical. Hence intra-union conflict did indeed often take the form of factional rivalry. The development of internal union politics in Britain has been very different: union democracy has reflected many of the structures and traditions of the movement's localised grassroots origins; the number of full-time officials has been relatively small, and their powers more limited than in the US; and anti-leadership traditions (articulated particularly powerfully in The Miners' Next Step) have often proved very influential. It should of course be added that the more recent experience of American unionism (Muste was writing before the creation of the CIO) has shown considerable evidence of shop-floor organisation and rank-and-file revolts.
42 Harbison, Frederick H., “Collective Bargaining and American Capitalism” in Kornhauser, Arthur et al. (eds), Industrial Conflict (New York, 1954), p. 277.Google Scholar
43 As with the very different argument of Muste, it would be rash to assume that Harbison's conclusion can be applied without qualification in the British context.