Comparative analyses of labour often assume a dividing line between free and forced labour which is universally applicable. However, during the past twenty years, several researchers have stressed the divergent historical meanings and definitions of both “free” and “unfree” labour.Footnote 1 In fact, until the middle, if not the end, of the nineteenth century, the notion of “free” labour was not that to which we are now accustomed;Footnote 2 it included indenture, debt bondage, and several other forms of unfree labour;Footnote 3 conversely, the official abolition of slavery saw not the disappearance of forced labour but rather the emergence of new forms.Footnote 4 In both cases, coerced labour was in legal terms “free labour”.
In this increasingly complex picture, the historical transition from “slavery” to “emancipation” has also been reassessed. For example, in French as well as in British and Spanish colonies, personal emancipation often took a long time, with years sometimes elapsing between the deed signed by the owner and the tax paid by the quasi ex-slave. During those years, the ex-slaves had an intermediate status between that of a slave and a freedman.Footnote 5 That transitory period occurred too at a macrosocial and institutional level: general emancipation in the British colonies was accomplished after an intermediate period of apprenticeship lasting almost ten years (the 1830s).Footnote 6
The tensions between “freedom” and “unfreedom” may therefore be identified more precisely as those between multiple notions and practices of contract, status, and social conditions. The legal status of the indentured, coolies, and apprentices was historically different from that of their “masters”, and this gave a peculiar value to the contracts in which they were involved. Nowadays, child labour confirms this link between the unequal legal status of socioeconomic actors and forms of contract.Footnote 7 From that perspective, freedom of person and liberty of contract are no longer synonymous.
The papers collected here aim to push those analyses further and to show that, historically, the tensions between freedom and unfreedom were intimately linked to those between status and contract. The dividing line between freedom and unfreedom is fluid precisely because that between status and contract is too. Indeed, this long-standing opposition has been widely diffused in history and the social sciences since the last quarter of the nineteenth century, when Henri Maine and A. Dicey opposed unfree societies (ancien régime, feudalism, slavery) to free societies. In the former, the legal status of the actors conditioned their social, political, and economic actions, while in the latter the contract dominated. This view emerged in response not only to the abolition of slavery in the United States and serfdom in Russia, but also to the transformation of labour institutions in Europe and the United States. In particular, the emergence of collective bargaining and the welfare state was considered synonymous with the decline of freedom of contract and a resurgence of status, the latter being a distinctive feature of “old regimes”. Ever since, several authors have developed this argument.Footnote 8
However, during recent decades, this simplistic scheme has been increasing attacked; for ancien régime France, for example, it has been demonstrated that the division of society into “old orders” and corporative regulation had already weakened greatly, and to some extent had disappeared, by the early eighteenth century,Footnote 9 while, on the other hand, important status markers persisted under the liberal regime (in relation to the legal status of married women, children, and merchants, for example). This was true not only in France but also in Britain and Germany.Footnote 10 According to this approach, the return of status in the twentieth century cannot be compared with old-regime status insofar as it appeals to rules and rights in order to reduce inequalities rather than to increase them. The world of labour, in particular the rights of workers under collective agreements in Europe and their fate on the one hand and the tough conditions endured by coolies, bonded people, and immigrants on the other, shows clearly enough the importance of this point for understanding past and present societies.Footnote 11 From this standpoint, the tension between legal status, contract, social conditions, and economic dynamics was a feature of the history of “coerced” labour as well as of “free” labour. Free and unfree labour on the one hand, status and contract on the other, are historically determined categories. We argue that those histories do not run in parallel but are strictly intersected. To prove this assertion, the papers in this volume have recourse to, first, a more complex relationship between written rules and legal procedures; secondly, an explicit analysis of the connections between legal and economic entitlements; and thirdly, a non-ethnocentric and global approach.
Rules first. The ways in which economic and social actors appropriate legal rules have been extensively studied in sociology, economics, history, and anthropology, and, of course, by legal scholars. The “effectiveness of law” reveals an anxiety widely shared among historians and expresses a particular approach to law. Laws are placed on the statute book but might then quickly become dead letters. Such laws are said to have little impact on the “real lives” of most people. Historians therefore want to know to what extent laws are enforced. This view misses the point: judicial statistics reveal not how rules affect the behaviour of ordinary people but merely the extent to which they are formally enforced. As a legal historian has stressed, there may for example be little enforcement and widespread disobedience, little enforcement and loss of compliance.Footnote 12 In studying “law in action” one has to keep in mind that the degree of litigation is not a measure of the impact of rules on “real life” but rather of the degree to which people have access to means to enforce their legal rights.Footnote 13
From that point of view, social and economic inequalities are mutually linked to legal entitlements; a modification in legal entitlements strongly influences the economic and social equilibrium, and vice versa. Legal entitlement is measured not only by law texts, but above all by procedures, charges of proof, and access to law courts for example; that is, a whole set of procedural rules and institutions giving concrete opportunities for individuals to mobilize rules. Those opportunities are not available equally to everybody. Undoubtedly, servants and coolies, not to speak of serfs and slaves, enjoyed many fewer rights and juridical opportunities than their masters did. Still, those rights were not nonexistent, and that led to different social and economic equilibriums.Footnote 14
We study this problem in detail, with fresh analyses of the interaction between legal status and economic conditions in tsarist Russia (in a comparative perspective) and pre-slavery-abolition Brazil. In particular, we show that the socioeconomic and legal conditions endured by serfs were much more elastic and open to negotiation than is usually asserted and that the so-called abolition of serfdom should therefore be seen within the context of a longer process of institutional change. Indeed, ex-serfs were subject to important legal constraints in post-emancipation Russia. “Serfs” were not serfs de la glèbe and ex-serfs were bound to landowners and, when working in manufactories, subject to strong legal constraints as well. Similarly, in Brazil, if bondage was extremely widespread after the abolition of slavery,Footnote 15 conversely labour contracts were in use before that date for manumitted slaves trying to repay debts contracted to buy their freedom. The definition of “contract” was important in guiding the labour laws relating to Brazilian national and immigrant workers, as well as former slaves.
At least in the urban areas studied here, only former slaves entered into labour contracts, and those had their own logic and features. They included settlements and long-term engagements, with monetary debts being incurred to pay the costs of manumission. These outcomes have found important confirmation in other parts of the world, and above all in India. In fact, legally, Indian workers were servants under British law and, as such, they had far fewer rights than their masters (both British and Indians).Footnote 16 In other words, rather than opposing the world of “freedom” and contract to the world of “unfreedom” and status, we measure the way rules, legal entitlements, and economic forces intervened in defining individual and social trajectories and hierarchies.
Underlying this conclusion is a perspective that is resolutely non-Eurocentric and global. We do not endeavour to find the “missing” freedom of contract in the “periphery”, nor do we consider the “cultural” and economic domination of “the West” as a starting point. We stress instead the mutual connection between “peripheries” and “core” categories and practices. In particular, we do not judge the level of freedom and unfreedom in Brazil or Russia in terms of a general, let us say British, notion of free labour; instead we consider the historical interplay between the two.
The emergence of the ideology of freedom in Britain and the United States in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries was quite complex and controversial, the economic and moral argument not always being compatible with it.Footnote 17 This was equally true in France, where enlightened philosophers and “liberal” physiocrats expressed quite ambiguous attitudes towards the immediate abolition of serfdom and slavery, at least until the insurrection in Santo Domingo. And even after, Napoleon was quick to restore slavery, while Jean-Baptiste Say, Le Play, and even Bentham continued to express a desire to introduce Russian serf discipline in Europe.Footnote 18 From that point of view, Russian and Brazilian perspectives on unfree labour were far from expressing the attitude of “backward” owners and elites. They reflected instead the ambiguities of European thought on this issue. In a similar and broader way, Clarence Smith has recently shown that the abolition of slavery in Islam reflected not just the impact of “Western influence” but that indigenous trends in that direction were already in motion.Footnote 19
Such a bilateral circulation of ideas and practices contrasts with the argument according to which “the West” invented “freedom” and coercion as well. In various “Western countries” “freedom” acquired different significances at different moments; conversely, freedom had different meanings outside Europe, as precolonial forms of bondage in India and Africa testify.Footnote 20 This implies that the cultural and material circulation of models and men did not necessarily follow the centre versus periphery scheme. Indeed, the evolution of legal and economic notions and practices of masters and servants in Britain interacted with that of servants, coolies, and masters in India and the British Empire. Not only did the British regulation of labour mould into Indian practices; the evolution of British jurisprudence and legislation governing the relationship between master and servant were strongly influenced by Indian jurisprudence. Between the 1860s and World War I, several projects aimed at codifying British law were all strongly influenced by Indian rules and jurisprudence.Footnote 21 Bentham’s and James Mill’s ideals and approaches to the law,Footnote 22 as well as the famous analysis of status and contract by Maine mentioned earlier, were strongly inspired by Indian regulation and jurisprudence.
This discovery opens new perspectives: Maine’s analysis seems no longer to be linked exclusively to the emergence of the social state and welfare regulation in Europe; it is strongly connected to the “colonial question”. This confirms that the history of “free” and “unfree” labour and that of forms of “contract” and “status” do not run in parallel but are connected. Stanziani’s paper (pp. 359–389) confirms this mutual relationship between Russia and Europe and shows how deeply the notion of “serfdom” influenced notions and practices of labour in Europe. Again, forms of bonded labour in the “periphery” cannot be understood without recognizing how they interplayed with the evolution of notions and practices of labour in the “core”.
However, the two papers here do not only revisit the circulation of ideas and the global political economy of labour; they wish also to revisit the historical dynamics. Our first point is that global economic dynamics from the seventeenth to the end of the nineteenth century (a period which saw “revolutions” in agriculture, trade, and consumption, protoindustrial growth, and the first industrial revolution) were anchored to a notion and practices of labour as “service”, in which the boundary between freedom and unfreedom was flexible and the master/employer acquired ownership of all the labour time of the worker/servant over the engagement period. Labour as service was at the root not only of serfdom and slavery, but also of the indentured, servants, and wage earners (labour being rented out as a service under a contract).Footnote 23
This world changed slowly during the nineteenth century and collapsed only at the turn of the twentieth century. In fact, it was not only Russian serfs but also American slaves, English servants, and French loueurs d’oeuvre who saw no change in their legal status following a single reformatory act or statute; that change came only as the result of a long-term process of rule-making, judicial action, and economic dynamics.Footnote 24 It was not until the middle, or in some cases towards the end, of the nineteenth century that labour rules were radically changed in all those countries and the “labour contract” as we know it today established. This coincided with a new notion of labour, the emergence of the welfare state and trade unions, and, last but not least, the second industrial revolution.
It is probably true that the notion and practices of “free labour” saw an unprecedented and wide success towards the end of the eighteenth and during the nineteenth century. However, this march was, at best, confined to western Europe and the United States; elsewhere twentieth-century practices were still strongly rooted in notions of labour as service and therefore to an uncertain boundary between freedom and unfreedom. Debt bondage and forms of servitude did not disappear in the second half of the nineteenth century, nor even in the century thereafter. On the contrary, they actually increased in Southeast Asia, Africa, and Latin America, as well as in the Soviet Union.