Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T05:56:30.920Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

I. The Abuse and Outlawing of Sanctuary for Debt in Seventeenth-Century England

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 February 2009

James R. Hertzler
Affiliation:
Goshen College, Indiana

Extract

On 16 April 1697 King William III of England gave his Royal Assent to a Bill just passed by his Whiggish Parliament, thereby making illegal a custom of very long standing in the history of English law and convention. During the Middle Ages the practice of imprisonment for debt had come into being through statutory enactments and through judicial procedure; parallel to it had grown the use of so-called ‘privileged places’, refuges to which delinquent debtors could flee and evade arrest for debt. While imprisonment for debt persisted as a legal process in England until the middle of the nineteenth century, sanctuary for debtors was legally abolished by this Act of 1697. That this Act was passed by a Whig-dominated Parliament is not without significance, for a substantial element in the Whig Party was the mercantile interest, the group most likely to suffer damage by the flight of debtors to these places of refuge.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1971

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Imprisonment for debt was first introduced in statutory form in the later thirteenth century in cases of manorial stewards who failed to account for funds due their masters. It was gradually extended to other categories of debtors, partly through additional statutes, partly through competition between the central courts of King's Bench and Common Pleas for business. The rationale for imprisoning delinquent debtors had at least two dimensions. It was intended as a deterrent to careless borrowing. But it was also viewed as a means of recovering outstanding debts, for the imprisoned debtor might be expected to call on friends, relatives, or his own concealed assets to satisfy the debts and obtain his release from prison. On the history of imprisonment for debt, see Holdsworth, William S., History of English Law (14 vols., London, 1903),Google Scholar especially vols. 1, VI and VIII; Plucknett, Theodore F., A Concise History of the Common Law (London, 1956);Google Scholar and Hertzler, James R., ‘The Reform of Imprisonment for Debt during the Interregnum and Later Stuart Periods’, unpublished University of Wisconsin Ph.D. dissertation (Madison, 1967).Google Scholar

2 8 & 9 Will. 3, c. 27, para. xv. The adverb ‘legally’ before ‘abolished’ is deliberate; while sanctuary was done away by law, in actual fact it continued at various locations in the early eighteenth century, partly because enforcement procedures were inadequate.

3 Numbers 35: II-28.

4 Cox, John Charles, The Sanctuaries and Sanctuary Seeders of Medieval England (London, 1911), pp. 14.Google Scholar

5 SirSmith, Hubert L., The History of East London (London, 1939), pp. 140, 141.Google Scholar

6 The Mirror of Justices, Publications of the Selden Society, VII (London, 1895), 34.Google Scholar

7 In order to secure the arrest of the delinquent debtor the creditor had to apply to a court for a writ of arrest. The most important of these were the writ capias ad respondendum, which commanded the sheriff to attach the body of the accused and hold it to insure the debtor's appearance in court, and the writ capias ad satisfaciendum, which required the sheriff to keep the debtor in prison until complete satisfaction was made for the debt, for costs, and for damages to the plaintiff.

8 Cox, , op. cit. pp. 107–9.Google Scholar

9 Trevelyan, G. M., England in tie Age of Wycliffe (London, 1909), p. 94, from Rotuli parliamentarii, ii, 369, iii, 37.Google Scholar

10 Bell, Walter George, Fleet Street in Seven Centuries (London, 1912), pp. 277–93.Google Scholar

11 Sanctuaries existed at many places outside London. Information about them is not so readily available as is the case with London. This study deals almost entirely with London, where the use, and the abuse, of sanctuary privileges was most prevalent.

12 Daniel Defoe gives a sample case in the Review which may very well have been taken from his own personal experience as a dealer in pantiles: ‘But I appeal to all the World, as to the Equity of the case, what the difference is between having my House broken up in the Night to be Robb'd, and a Man coming in Good Credit, and with a Proffer of Ready Money in the middle of the Day, and buying 5001. of Goods, and carry them directly from my Warehouse into the Mint, and the next day laugh at me, and bid me defiance? Yet this I have seen done: I think ‘tis the justest thing in the world that the last shou'd be esteem'd the greater Thief, and deserves most to be hang'd.’ Review, III, 21 (16 Feb. 1706), 81.

13 Trevelyan, , op. cit. pp. 8991, 95.Google Scholar

14 Wyclif, John, The English Worlds of Wyclif Hitherto Unprinted, edited by Mathew, F. D. (London, 1902), p. 221. This is not simply a case of Wyclif toadying to the powerful Lancastrian faction that protected him, but is rather in line with his broader attacks on clerical privilege.Google Scholar

15 2 Rich. 2, Stat. 2, c. 3.

16 32 Hen. 8, c. 12; 1 Jac. 1, c. 25, para. 7.

17 Birch, Walter (ed.), The Historical Charters and Constitutional Documents of the City of London (London, 1887), pp. 143, 144.Google Scholar

18 21 Jac. 1, c. 28, para. 7.

19 Corporation of London Record Office, Journals of the Court of Common Council, Journal 40, fos. 3, 4.

20 Certaine petitions presented by the lord maior and commonalty of the Citie of London to the Honorable House of Commons, shewing the great inconvenience of protections, priviledge, and priviledged places (London, 1641), pp. 4, 5.Google Scholar

21 Good summaries of attempted legal reform in the Interregnum can be found in Holdsworth, History of English Law, VI, 412–28;Google ScholarJames, Margaret, Social Problems and Policy during the Puritan Revolution, 1640–1660 (London, 1930), pp. 326–38;Google Scholar and Niehaus, C. R., ‘The Issue of Law Reform in the Puritan Revolution’, unpublished Ph.D. dissertation at Harvard University (1957).Google Scholar

22 Christie, W. D. (ed.), Letters Addressed from London to Sir Joseph Williamson, Publications of the Camden Society, New Series, VIII (2 vols., Westminster 1879), 1, 52.Google Scholar

23 The Loyal Impartial Mercury, no. 2 (9–13 June 1682).Google Scholar

24 Public Record Office, Privy Council Register, 2/71, fos. 143, 144. Hereafter, P.C.

25 Borgman, Albert S., Thomas Shadwell, His Life and Comedies (New York, 1928), pp. 212, 213.Google Scholar

26 Ibid. p. 58.

27 One of Dryden's most famous poems, ‘MacFlecknoe’, is a direct, personal satire on the Whiggish dramatist and poet.

28 Shadwell, Thomas, The Dramatic Worlds of Thomas Shadwell, esq. (4 vols., London, 1720), IV, 214, 236.Google Scholar

29 Shadwell, , op. cit. IV, 280.Google Scholar

30 Borgman, , op. cit. p. 216,Google Scholar quoted from Spence, Joseph, Anecdotes, Observations, and Characters of Booths and Men (London, 1820), p. 43.Google Scholar

31 Corporation of London Record Office, Repertories of the Court of Aldermen, Repertory 91, fos. 26, 27. Hereafter, Repertories.

32 P.C. 2/67, fo. 134; 2/69, fo. 668; 2/70, fos. 115, 169; 2/71, fo143. The Savoy was used until about 1702 as a hospital, and at times sick or wounded soldiers were housed there. It apparently also served as barracks for a detachment of troops. Wheatley, H. B., London Past and Present (3 vols., London, 1891), III, 218, 219.Google Scholar

33 Historical Manuscripts Commission, Thirteenth Report, Appendix, pt. v, The Manuscripts of the House of Lords (London, 1892), p. 21.Google Scholar

34 Repertories, 101, fo. 40.

35 Kerr, R. J. andDuncan, J. C., The Portledge Papers (London, 1928), pp. 113, 114;Google ScholarLuttrell, Narcissus, A Brief Historical Relation of State Affairs (6 vols., Oxford, 1857), II, 259, 260.Google Scholar

36 Historical Manuscripts Commission, The Manuscripts of the House of Lords, new series (London, 1903), II, p.Google Scholar

37 The Post Man, no. 180 (2–4 July 1696).Google Scholar

38 Journals of the House of Commons, XI, 646.Google Scholar

39 8 & 9 Will. 3, c. 27, para. xv.

40 The Post Boy, no. 309 (27–29 Apr. 1697).Google Scholar

41 Review, IV, 25 (8 Apr. 1707), 100.Google Scholar

42 The Tatler, no. 66 (10 Sept. 1709).

43 Ward, Edward, The London Spy (London, 1927), p. 125.Google Scholar

44 Journals of the House of Commons, XXI, 257;Google Scholar see also undated petition, The case of the several landlords of White-Friers, the Savoy, Salisbury Court, Ram-Alley, Mitre Court, Fuller's Rents, Baldwin's Gardens, Mountague Close, the Minories, Mint, Clinks, and Deadman's Place, in the name of themselves, and the rest of the houses within those places, B.M., T. 100 (50).

45 The Post Man, no. 309 (20–22 Apr. 1697).

46 The deplorable case of the poor people in the Mint, humbly offer'd to the charitable consideration of the honourable, the Commons of Great Britain in parliament assembled (c. 1700), Library of Lincoln's Inn, Miscellaneous Pamphlets, 103, fo. 390.

47 The Post Man, no. 276 (11–13 Feb. 1696/7).Google Scholar

48 The case of the shelterers in the Mint (c. 1700), Library of Lincoln's Inn, Misc. Pamphlets, 103, fo. 391. Jailers had the right to demand all sorts of payments for services rendered.

49 Dawk's News Letter, no. 353 (20 Sept. 1698).Google Scholar

50 The London Post (27–29 Mar. 1700).Google Scholar

51 The Flying Post (28–30 Mar. 1700).Google Scholar

52 The English Post (14–16 Oct. 1700).Google Scholar

53 The Tatler, no. 66 (10 Sept. 1709).Google Scholar

54 The Post Man, no. 331 (12–15 June 1697).Google Scholar

55 Journals of the House of Commons, XV, 147.Google Scholar

56 Miege, Guy, The Present State of Great Britain (London, 1707), p. 198.Google Scholar

57 Baston, Thomas, Thoughts on Trade (London, 1716), pp. 111, 112.Google Scholar

58 13 Car. 2, Stat. 2, c. 2.

59 Journals of the House of Commons, XI, 643.Google Scholar

60 Probably one of the most famous, and certainly one of the largest of the debtors’ prisons, was the Fleet. John Macky, an early eighteenth-century observer, makes this institution almost appear attractive: ‘The House it self consists of Four Galleries one above another, with Eight Rooms of a Side in each Gallery, for the Conveniency of such Prisoners as do not, or cannot take the Liberty of the Rules. There is a handsome Chapel adjoining to it, where Prayers are said twice a day, and Sermons on Sundays and Holidays. Underneath the House is a large Garden, well planted, for the Prisoners to walk in. … There is a Travelling-Market every day of all sort of Provisions; so that you have the cries in the Galleries of every thing, as you have in the Streats. And no Place in London is cheaper than the Fleet. …’ This was not a bad hide-out for debtors who might, through collusion, get themselves informally and temporarily committed to the Fleet before a court could commit them legally and more permanently. Macky, John, A Journey Through England (2 vols., London, 1724), 11, 2, 3.Google Scholar

61 Dawk's News-Letter, no. 504 (7 Sept. 1699).Google Scholar

62 The Post Boy, no. 1032 (25–27 Dec. 1701).Google Scholar

63 J. B., , An argument shewing that ‘tis impossible for the nation to be rid of the grievances occasion'd by the marshal of the Kings-Bench, and warden of the Fleet, without an utter extirpation of their present offices (London, 1699), p. vi.Google Scholar

64 Journals of the House of Commons, XIV, 284, 351.Google Scholar

65 Defoe estimated in 1709 that there were as many as 20,000 persons in danger of arrest for debt who were lurking in privileged places such as the environs of prisons, the verges of court, in the houses of nobility and other sanctuaries. Review, V, 145 (1 03 1709), 579.Google Scholar However, there was an exceptionally high rate of commitment of prisoners to the Fleet Prison between 1697 anc’ 17°o; th's might be interpreted as a result of the attack on privileged places. The rate of commitment ran more than three times that of the early 1690s. Public Records Office, Pris. 1a, 1b, 2, 10.

66 9 Geo. I, c. 29; 11 Geo. I, c. 22.

67 SirBesant, Walter, South London (New York, 1898), p. 242.Google Scholar

68 One might refer to ‘pro-creditor’ reforms, such as the prevention of debtor escapes, which were enacted into law under Whig auspices; in contrast, one might note ‘pro-debtor’ reforms such as the periodic release Acts for insolvent prisoners, most of which were passed by Cavalier or Tory Parliaments.