Article contents
Ideology and Social Policy: the Origins of the Trade Boards Act
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 11 February 2009
Extract
The issue of sweated labour formed one of the most intractable social problems of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Numerous remedies to solve sweating, such as the restriction of female and child labour, the abolition of domestic workshops, consumers' leagues, and co-operative production were variously advanced but subsequently found to be wanting. Eventually, and bowing to the inevitable, Edwardians finally sanctioned one cautious measure which they thought would curb sweating at its root – that is the legal control of low pay in the form of the 1909 Trade Boards Act. Initially, the act applied to domestic chain-making, ready-made and wholesale bespoke tailoring, paper-box making, and the machine-made lace and finishing trade. In these four industries in which wages were deemed unduly low, boards were established consisting of equal numbers of employers' and workers' representatives, plus independent members nominated by the state. In effect, the boards were thus a form of compulsory arbitration on pay.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1991
References
1 Snowden, P., An autobiography (2 vols., 1934), I, 240Google Scholar.
2 Paper by Tawney, R. H. on minimum wage fixing in League of Nations Union, Towards industrial peace (London, 1927), p. 19Google Scholar.
3 Pond, C. and Winyard, S., The case for a national minimum wage (London, 1982), pp. 29–30Google Scholar, 40–5. At the present time, wages councils encompass some 2.6 million workers and twenty-six trades.
4 Hay, J. R., The origins of the Liberal welfare reforms 1906–1914 (London, 1975), p. 217CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
5 Gilbert, B. B., The evolution of national insurance in Great Britain: the origins of the welfare state (London, 1966), p. 9Google Scholar.
6 Nation, 27 March 1909.
7 Bythell, D., The sweated trades (London, 1978), p. 247Google Scholar.
8 Schmiechen, J. A., Sweated industries and sweated labor: the London clothing trades, 1860–1914 (London, 1984), p. 134Google Scholar.
9 Schmiechen, J. A., ‘State reform and the local economy: a reply’, Economic History Review, 2nd ser., XXV (1982), 305Google Scholar.
10 Morris, J., Women workers and the sweated trades (Aldershot, 1986), pp. 211–12Google Scholar.
11 Davidson, R., Whitehall and the labour problem in late- Victorian and Edwardian Britain (London, 1985), pp. 269–73Google Scholar.
12 Hennock, E. P., ‘Poverty and social theory in England: the experience of the eighteen-eighties’, Social History, I (1976), 67–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
13 Select committee on the sweating system (S.C.S.S.), Fifth report (Parl. Papers, 1890, XVII), pp. xlii–xliii.
14 Dorothy George, for instance, refers to ‘garret-masters’ and ‘chamber-masters’ in the shoe and watch trades. See London life in the eighteenth century (Harmonsworth, 1966), pp. 174–5Google Scholar.
15 See, for instance, Mayhew's Morning Chronicle letters on the tailors in Thompson, E. P. and Yeo, E. (eds.), The unknown Mayhew (Harmondsworth, 1973), pp. 217–73Google Scholar.
16 For the role of the sewing-machine in sweated tailoring, see Gainer, B., The alien invasion (London, 1972), pp. 15–17Google Scholar.
17 Thompson, and Yeo, , Mayhew, p. 102Google Scholar.
18 Burnett, John, Report as to the condition of nailmakers and small chainmakers in South Staffordshire and East Worcestershire (P.P., 1888Google Scholar, XCI), p. 46.
19 Beales, H. L., The making of British social policy (Oxford, 1946), p. 20Google Scholar.
20 Fried, A. and Ellman, R. (eds.), Charles Booth's London (Harmondsworth, 1971), p. 175Google Scholar.
21 S.C.S.S. First report (P.P. 1888, XX), Q. 3248. See also, Potter, B., ‘The Lords and the sweating system’, Nineteenth Century, XXVII (1890), 905Google Scholar. Hennock is not strictly accurate, however, in suggesting that no one recommended a minimum wage. One Black Country union official did suggest a minimum wage, but he was persuaded, by an adroit cross-examination, to retract his statement. See Hennock, , ‘Poverty and social theory’, p. 87Google Scholar and Blackburn, S. C., ‘Working-class attitudes to social reform’, International Review of Social History, XXXIII (1988), 50Google Scholar.
22 S.C.S.S., Third report (P.P. 1889Google Scholar, XIII) QQ. 18208–34. For the impact of the Punch cartoon, see Webb, B., My apprenticeship (Harmondsworth, 1971), p. 334Google Scholar.
23 See, for example, the evidence of William Adamson, vicar of Old Ford, S.C.S.S., First report (P.P. 1888, XX) QQ. 2568.
24 Burnett, J., Report to the Board of Trade on the sweating system at the East End of London (P.P., 1887, LXXXIX)Google Scholar. See also Burnett's insistent remarks that his report was correct. S.C.S.S., Second report (P.P. 1888, XXI), QQ. 17284–7, 17290–4.
25 S.C.S.S., Fifth report (P.P., 1890, XVII), p. cxxxv–cxxxvii. Fair wages resolutions were subsequently passed in 1891, 1909 and 1946. The proposals with regard to female chain and nailmakers never became law.
26 Hansard (Commons), 3rd ser. CCCL, 1711, 26 Feb. 1891.
27 Minority report by Abraham, W., Austin, M., Mawdsley, J. and Mann, T., Royal commission on labour (P.P., 1894Google Scholar, XXXV), pp. 130–46.
28 Macrosty, H. W., Sweating: its cause and remedy (Fabian tract 50, 1894), p. 10Google Scholar.
29 Mill, J. S., Principles of political economy (London, 1878 edn), pp. 218–21Google Scholar. See also, Barker, E., Political thought in England from Herbert Spencer to the present day (London, 1915), p. 9Google Scholar.
30 See, for instance, Emy, H. V., Liberals, radicals and social politics, 1892–1914 (Cambridge, 1973). PP. 112–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
31 Hobson, J. A., ‘A living wage’, Commonwealth, I (1896), 128–9Google Scholar, 165–7.
32 Ibid. Hobson, however, doubted that the S.C.S.S.'s proposal of producer co-operatives was aviable one. See Hobson, , Problems of poverty: an inquiry into the industrial conditions of the poor (London, 1891)Google Scholar, ch. VI.
33 Hobson, , ‘A living wage’, p. 167Google Scholar.
34 Ibid.
35 , S. and Webb, B., Industrial democracy (2 vols., London, 1897 edn), II, 766–74Google Scholar.
36 Ibid. pp. 750–3, 799.
37 Ibid. p. 749.
38 Ibid. p. 748.
39 Ibid. pp. 765–60.
40 Hobson also believed that his living wage should vary according to different types of workers and different regions of the country for ‘No principle of absolute or mechanical equity can be maintained’. See Hobson, , ‘A living wage’, pp. 128–9Google Scholar.
41 Webbs, , Industrial democracy, II, 774–5Google Scholar.
42 Williams, G., The state and the standard of living (London, 1936), p. 105Google Scholar.
43 Despite the comparative newness of Australia and New Zealand, their abundance of land and relative scarcity of labour, investigations carried out in the 1880s and 1890s revealed that, underneath the surface prosperity, there was a morass of sweating. Unlike Britain, however, the two colonies had been prepared to countenance state intervention in the wages contract. In New Zealand, the evils of sweating were combatted through the courts of arbitration. Originally established by an Act of 1894 to prevent strikes and lock-outs, local courts of arbitration (conciliation boards) also had power to fix a legal minimum wage for low-paid workers. In Victoria, by contrast, wage regulation was embodied in the Factory Act of 1896, following a campaign carried out by the Victorian anti-sweating league. The 1896 Act empowered the governor to appoint special boards to fix legal minimum wages for persons employed in or outside a factory in certain specified trades. These boards consisted of between four and ten members and representation on them was divided equally between employers and employees. The boards held office for two years and were under the direction of a chairman. Dilke favoured wages boards (as opposed to the state arbitration of New Zealand), since they did not interfere with the more powerful trade unions which possessed adequate collective bargaining machinery. See Reeves, W. Pember, ‘The minimum wage law in Victoria and South Australia’, Economic Journal, XI (1901), 335–8Google Scholar. See also, Dilke's, evidence before the Select committee on homework (S.C.H.), (P.P., 1908Google Scholar, VIII), QQ. 3926, 4028.
44 Mill, however, eventually rejected wages boards on Malthusian grounds. See Mill, , Principles, p. 219Google Scholar.
45 Dilke attributed his inspiration for wages boards, before the S.C.H., to Mill. See S.C.H. (P.P., 1908, VIII), Q. 3920. There is little doubt, however, that Charles Deakin, Chief Secretary of Victoria, persuaded Dilke that wages boards were actually workable. See Rickard, J., ‘The anti-sweating movement in Britain and Victoria: the politics of empire and social reform’, Historical Studies, XVIII (1979), 585Google Scholar.
46 Several historians, including Tawney, wrongly suppose that Dilke's Bill was first introduced in 1898. See Tawney, , Towards industrial peace pp. 22–3Google Scholar.
47 Bosanquet, H., The strength of the people (London, 1902), pp. 267–312Google Scholar.
48 Labour Leader, 17 May 1907.
49 The W.I.C. had carried out several valuable enquiries into the problems of homework, and had also sent investigators to gather further information on the subject in other English-speaking nations overseas. In America, the W.I.C. became aware of the licensing system. In New York and Massachusetts, and in several other states, outwork was forbidden unless the place where the work was going to be completed had been inspected and licensed. The workers, themselves, had to apply for this licence, and were to produce it when applying for work. The MacDonalds made a visit to the U.S.A., and were personally converted to the scheme. See MacDonald, R., Margaret Ethel MacDonald (London, 1924), pp. 137–46Google Scholar.
50 Rowntree, B. S., Poverty: a study of town life (London, 1901)Google Scholar.
51 Masterman, C. F. G., The condition of England (London, 1909), p. 172Google Scholar.
52 Hutchins, B. L. and Harrison, A., A history of factory legislation (London, 1966 edn), p. 216Google Scholar.
53 Gooch, G. P., ‘Sweating and the minimum wage’, Commonwealth, XII (1907), 65Google Scholar.
54 A wage census inquiry had been attempted in 1886, but its results were inadequate. See Mallon, J. J., ‘Women's wages in the wage census of 1906’, in Hutchins, B. L., Women in moderm industry (London, 1915), pp. 213–38Google Scholar.
55 Rickard, , ‘The anti-sweating movement’, pp. 585–6Google Scholar.
56 Daily Mews, 25 April 1906, 13 June 1906. Cadbury also compensated those who were, as a result of appearing in the exhibition, victimized. See Daily Mews, 8 May 1906.
57 Justice, the organ of the Social Democratic Federation, however, sarcastically remarked that princesses and sweated workers went well together. See Justice, 5 May 1906.
58 Daily Mews, 13 June 1906.
59 Gladstone, in fact, bought a shawl for one old lady at work in the exhibition who was sitting in a draught. Ibid. 18 May 1906.
60 Mudie-Smith, R. (ed.), Sweated industries being a handbook of the ‘Daily News’ exhibition (London, 1906)Google Scholar. See also, Williams, , The state, pp. 105–6Google Scholar.
61 Some of the exhibitions were still being run as late as 1914, although they appear to have lost their initial impact. See the Daily Herald, 14 Nov. 1914.
62 Handbook to the sweated industries exhibition, Ilford, October 28–31, 1908, p. 7.
63 Tuckwell, G., ‘The story of the Trade Boards Act’, Contemporary Review, CXX (1921), 601Google Scholar.
64 Gooch, G. P., ‘The Edwardian decade’ in Hearnshaw, F. J. C. (ed.), Edwardian England (London, 1933), p. 23Google Scholar.
65 See, for example, MacDonald's, Margaret comments, Labour Leader, 11 05 1906Google Scholar.
66 Bythell, , The sweated trades, p. 236Google Scholar.
67 See, for example, Lansbury, G., Looking backwards and forwards (London, 1935), pp. 217–20Google Scholar. See also, Wright, T., ‘Operation and co-operation’, in Wright, T. (ed.), Sweated labour and the Trade Boards Act (London, 1911), p. 57Google Scholar. George Cadbury became the president of the N.A.S.L., and paid the rent on the N.A.S.L.'s headquarters. See Koss, S., Fleet street radical: A. G. Gardiner and the Daily News (London, 1973), p. 77Google Scholar.
68 N.A.S.L., , Report of conference on a minimum wage, held at the Guildhall, London (London, 1907), p. 6Google Scholar.
69 Ibid. pp. 54–8. Later in life, though, Hobson campaigned for a voluntary living wage since this did not impinge on free collective bargaining. See Brailsford, H. N., Hobson, J. A., Jones, A. Creech and Wise, E. F., The living wage (London, 1926), pp. 33–5Google Scholar.
70 Women's Trade Union Review, 01 1907, p. 14Google Scholar. However, the Women's Industrial News, the organ of the W.I.C., pronounced Webb's paper ‘lacking in freshness’, and a disappointment to his admirers. See Women's Industrial News, 12 1906, p. 586Google Scholar.
71 N.A.S.L., , First annual report (Manchester, 1907), p. 4Google Scholar.
72 Herbert Samuel, under-secretary at the Home Office, and a Webb convert, was responsible for appointing Aves. See Samuel, Viscount, Memoirs (London, 1945), p. 63Google Scholar.
73 S.C.H., Report (P.P. 1907Google Scholar, VI). By the time the committee had been established, two bills concerning wages boards had been placed before parliament. The first bill was introduced by the Liberal, Ernest Lamb. See Hansard (Commons), 4th ser. CLXIX, 419, 15 02 1907Google Scholar. The second bill, the Sweated Industries Bill, was introduced by Henderson on behalf of the Labour Party. See Hansard (Commons), 4th ser. CLXXII, 559–600, 15 04 1907Google Scholar. The Sweated Industries Bill was reintroduced in February 1908 and, on passing its second reading unopposed, was referred to the S.C.H. by the home secretary. See N.A.S.L., , Second annual report (Manchester, 1908), p. 5Google Scholar.
74 S.C.H., , Report (P.P. 1908Google Scholar, VIII), pp. vii, xi.
75 Ibid. p. xiv.
77 Hansard (Commons), 5th ser. II, 1792–3, 24 03 1909Google Scholar.
78 See speech by Gooch, , Hansard (Commons), 5th ser. IV, 400, 28 04 1909Google Scholar. Henderson, in fact, clashed with MacDonald at the 1908 Labour Party conference over the issue of trade boards. Henderson was also instrumental in gaining union support for the boards. See Cole, M., Makers of the labour movement (London, 1948), p. 253Google Scholar, and Hamilton, M. A., Arthur Henderson (London, 1938). PP. 55–7Google Scholar.
79 Boyaval, P., ‘La lutte contre le sweating system: le minimum légal de salaire l'example de l'Australiasie et de l'Angleterre’ (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Paris, 1911), p. 422Google Scholar.
80 Webb, S., introduction to Hutchins and Harrison, A history of factory legislation, p. xivGoogle Scholar. See also, McBriar, A. B., Fabian socialism and English politics, 1884–1918 (Cambridge, 1966), p. 261Google Scholar. It is sometimes suggested that, because Herbert Gladstone lacked courage, Churchill took over trade boards. See Caldwell, J. A. C., ‘The genesis of the Ministry of Labour’, Public Administration, XXXVII (1959), 371–82Google Scholar. It is more probable, however, that the Board of Trade was better equipped than the Home Office to handle labour problems. See Davidson, R., ‘Llewellyn Smith, the labour department and government growth, 1886–1909’, in Sutherland, G. (ed.), Studies in the growth of nineteenth century government (London, 1972), pp. 227–62Google Scholar.
81 Labour year book (London, 1916), p. 214Google Scholar.
82 Cole, G. D. H., Living wages (London, 1938), p. 7Google Scholar. For further details of inadequate inspection, see Blackburn, S., ‘Sweated labour and the minimum wage’ (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of London, 1983), pp. 164–9Google Scholar.
83 Davidson, R., ‘Llewellyn Smith’, pp. 242–3Google Scholar. See also, Davidson, , ‘The myth of the servile state’, Bulletin of the Society for the Study of Labour History, XXIX (1974), 64Google Scholar.
84 Davidson, R., ‘Sir Hubert Llewellyn Smith and labour policy, 1886–1916’ (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Cambridge, 1971), pp. 204–5Google Scholar, 223. See also, Davidson, R., ‘Government administration’ in Wrigley, C. J. (ed.), A history of British industrial relations 1875–1914 (Brighton, 1982), p. 169Google Scholar. The same point is also made in Davidson, R., Whitehall and the labour problem, pp. 115–16Google Scholar, 269–73.
85 Ibid. p. 273.
86 Aves' report was uncertain and inconclusive. He doubted whether the experiment of Victoria could be considered applicable for Britain. See Aves, , Report to the Home Secretary on the wages boards and industrial conciliation and arbitration acts of Australia and New Zealand (P.P., 1908Google Scholar, LXXI).
87 S.C.H. (P.P. 1908, VI), Q. 822.
88 Askwith, G. R., Industrial problems and disputes (London, 1920), p. 293Google Scholar.
89 The sweated industries bill (cabinet memo by H. Gladstone dated Feb. 1908), London, British Library, Papers and memoranda, 1902–9.
90 Hay, J. R., The development of the British welfare stale, 1880–1975 (London, 1978), p. 108Google Scholar.
91 Blackburn, ‘Sweated labour and the minimum wage’, ch. IV.
92 See, for instance, the reaction of trade unionists to a national minimum wage, N.A.S.L., , Report of conference, pp. 42–3Google Scholar, 46. See also evidence of Dilke, , S.C.H. (P.P. 1908Google Scholar, VIII), Q. 3928. For further details of the ambivalent attitude of the unions towards legal control of low pay, see Blackburn, S., ‘The problem of riches: from trade boards to a national minimum wage’, Industrial Relations Journal, XIX (1988), 124–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
93 The ambiguities in employers' motives are dealt with in Blackburn, S., ‘Employers and social policy’, Midland History, XII (1987), 85–102CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
94 For a breakdown of the N.A.S.L. membership, see the N.A.S.L.'s annual reports.
95 See Stewart, M. and Hunter, L., The needle is threaded (London, 1964), pp. 140–2Google Scholar. J. J. Mallon, whilst serving on the chain trade board described the meeting to the chainmakers' union leader, Mr Albert Head. (Information from interview with A. E. Head, 13 Oct. 1976). Henderson, in fact, had not only introduced a sweated industries bill (based on wages boards), but he had also voted, as a member of the S.C.H., for wages boards. See Women's Trade Union Review, 10 1908, p. 4Google Scholar.
96 For Mallon's and Llewellyn Smith's connection with Toynbee Hall, see Briggs, A. and Macartney, A., Toynbee Hall: the first hundred years (London, 1984)Google Scholar. Mallon later became the warden of Toynbee Hall.
97 Belgium, France, Luxemburg, Holland, Portugal and Spain all have a general minimum wage. See Starr, G., Minimum wage fixing (International Labour Organization, Geneva, 1981)Google Scholar, ch. 3.
98 Hansard (Commons), 5 ser. XXIV, 1881–1924, 26 04 1911Google Scholar.
99 Public Record Office, London, Lab 11/150/L/1913. Trade boards were eventually extended to five more trades in 1913.
100 Mallon, J. J., Industry and a minimum wage (London, 1950), p. 7Google Scholar.
101 Tawney reviewing Burns, E. M., Wages and the state (1926)Google Scholar, in Economica, VII (1927), 104Google Scholar.
102 Ibid. p. 103. See also, Tawney, R. H., ‘The minimum wage in Great Britain’, Mew Republic, 06 28, 1922, p. 125Google Scholar.
103 Ibid. p. 126.
104 Tawney, , Towards industrial peace, p. 27Google Scholar.
105 Blackburn, ‘Sweated labour and the minimum wage’, ch. VI.
106 Tawney, , ‘The minimum wage in Great Britain’, p. 127Google Scholar. However, this flexibility was often illusory. Trade boards were instructed to fix rates for the least competent men and women in each grade. Tawney's criticisms of a national minimum wage had no doubt been fashioned by his reading of Hobson's works but, unlike the latter, Tawney viewed a living wage as unattainable. See Freeden, M., Liberalism divided: a study in British political thought, 1914–1939 (Oxford, 1986), P. 313CrossRefGoogle Scholar.
107 Saville, J., ‘The welfare state: an historical approach’, New Reasoner, I (1957–1958), 17Google Scholar.
108 Tawney, , Towards industrial peace, p. 18Google Scholar.
109 For further details of the national minimum wage in the United States of America, see Low Pay Unit, ‘American comment: prospects for a hike in the U.S. minimum wage’, Low Pay Review, XXXI (1987), 38–9Google Scholar.
110 Hobson, , ‘A living wage’, pp. 128–9Google Scholar.
- 9
- Cited by