Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T19:16:08.035Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Pay scheme preferences and health policy objectives

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 June 2010

Birgit Abelsen*
Affiliation:
Faculty of Medicine, Institute of Community Medicine, University of Tromsø, N-9037 Tromsø, Norway
*
*Correspondence to: Birgit Abelsen, Northern Research Institute Alta as, P.O. Box 1463, N-9506 Alta, Norway. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper studies the preferences among healthcare workers towards pay schemes involving different levels of risk. It identifies which pay scheme individuals would prefer for themselves, and which they think is best in furthering health policy objectives. The paper adds, methodologically, a way of defining pay schemes that include different levels of risk. A questionnaire was mailed to a random sample of 1111 dentists. Respondents provided information about their current and preferred pay schemes, and indicated which pay scheme, in their opinion, would best further overall health policy objectives. A total of 504 dentists (45%) returned the questionnaire, and there was no indication of systematic non-response bias. All public dentists had a current pay scheme based on a fixed salary and the majority of individuals preferred a pay scheme with more income risk. Their preferred pay schemes coincided with the ones believed to further stabilise healthcare personnel. The predominant current pay scheme among private dentists was based solely on individual output, and the majority of respondents preferred this pay scheme. In addition, their preferred pay schemes coincided with the ones believed to further efficiency objectives. Both public and private dentists believed that pay schemes, furthering efficiency objectives, had to include more performance-related pay than the ones believed to further stability and quality objectives.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abelsen, B. (2008), ‘What a difference a place makes: dental attendance and self-rated oral health among adults in three different counties in Norway’, Health & Place, 14(4): 827838.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Agresti, A. (2002), Categorical Data Analysis, 2nd edn, New Jersey, Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Allison, P. (1999), Multiple Regression. A Primer, Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.Google Scholar
Baker, G. (2002), ‘Distortion and risk in optimal incentive contracts’, The Journal of Human Resources, 37(4): 728751.Google Scholar
Bartlett, J., Kotrlik, J.Higgins, C. (2001), ‘Organizational research: determining appropriate sample size in survey research’, Information Technology, Learning, and Performance Journal, 19(1): 4350.Google Scholar
Bénabou, R.Tirole, J. (2003), ‘Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation’, The Review of Economic Studies, 70: 489520.Google Scholar
Chan, Y. (2005), ‘Multinomial logistic regression’, Singapore Medical Journal, 46(6): 259268.Google Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. (1989), ‘Agent theory: an assessment and review’, The Academy of Management Review, 14(1): 5774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, R. (1984), Strained Mercy: The Economics of Canadian Health Care, Toronto: Butterworths.Google Scholar
Falk, A.Kosfield, M. (2006), ‘The hidden costs of control’, The American Economic Review, 96(5): 16111630.Google Scholar
Fehr, E.Falk, A. (2002), ‘Psychological foundations of incentives’, European Economic Review, 46: 687724.Google Scholar
Garibaldi, P. (2006), Personnel Economics in Imperfect Labour Markets, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaynor, M.Gertler, P. (1995), ‘Moral hazard and risk spreading in partnerships’, The RAND Journal of Economics, 26(4): 591613.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. (1998), ‘Incentives in organizations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4): 115132.Google Scholar
Gravelle, H., Sutton, M.Ma, A. (2008), Doctor Behaviour Under a Pay For Performance Contract: Further Evidence From the Quality and Outcomes Framework. CHE Research Paper 28: Centre for Health Economics, University of York, York.Google Scholar
Groves, R. (2006), ‘Nonresponce rates and nonresponse bias in houshold surveys’, Public Opinion Quarterly, 70: 654675.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grytten, J. (1991), ‘The effect of supplier inducement on Norwegian dental services; some empirical findings based on a theoretical model’, Community Dental Health, 8: 221231.Google Scholar
Grytten, J. (1992), ‘Supplier inducement – its relative effect on demand and utilization’, Community Dentistry and Oral Epidemiology, 20: 69.Google Scholar
Grytten, J. (2005), ‘Models for financing dental services. A review’, Community Dental Health, 22: 7585.Google ScholarPubMed
Grytten, J.Sørensen, R. (2000), ‘Competition and dental services’, Health Economics, 9: 447461.3.0.CO;2-A>CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grytten, J., Holst, D.Laake, P. (1990), ‘Supplier Inducement. Its effects on dental services in Norway’, Journal of Health Economics, 9: 483491.Google Scholar
Grytten, J., Skau, I.Holst, D. (2007), ‘Practice organization in private dental care in Norway’, Nor Tannlegeforen Tid, 117: 196200.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B.Milgrom, P. (1991), ‘Multitask principal-agent analyses: incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design’, Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 7: 2452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunnes, A., Møen, J., Salvanes, K. (2007), Wage Structure and Labor Mobility in Norway 1980–1997. NBER Working Paper No. 12974.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D.Tversky, A. (1979), ‘Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk’, Econometrica, 47(2): 263291.Google Scholar
Lang, K.Gordon, P.-J. (1995), ‘Partnerships as insurance devices: theory and evidence’, The RAND Journal of Economics, 26(4): 614629.Google Scholar
Lazear, E. (2000), ‘Performance pay and productivity’, American Economic Review, 90(5): 13461361.Google Scholar
Lazear, E.Shaw, K. (2007), Personnel Economics: The Economist’s View of Human Resources. NBER Working Paper No. W13653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. (2004), ‘Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: evidence from the marketplace’, Econometrica, 72(2): 615625.Google Scholar
McGuire, T. (2000), ‘Physician agency’, in A. Culyer and J. Newhouse (eds), Handbook of Health Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 461536.Google Scholar
McNabb, R.Withfield, K. (2007), ‘The impact of varying types of performance-related pay and employee participation on earnings’, International Journal of Human Resource Management, 18(6): 10041025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, C. (1999), ‘The provision of incentives in firms’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37(1): 763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, A. (2000), ‘Economics of general practice’, in A. Culyer and J. Newhouse (eds), Handbook of Health Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 11751200.Google Scholar
Spremann, K. (1987), ‘Agent and principal’, in G. Bamberg and K. Spremann (eds), Agency Theory, Information, and Incentives, Berlin: Springer Verlag, 337.Google Scholar