Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T08:41:18.067Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Towards an alternative economics of health care

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 December 2008

GEOFFREY M. HODGSON*
Affiliation:
The Business School, University of Hertfordshire, UK
*
*Correspondence to: Professor Geoffrey Hodgson, The Business School, University of Hertfordshire, De Havilland Campus, Hatfield, Hertfordshire AL10 9AB, UK. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

It is argued here that an economics centred on subjective utility-maximization is unsuitable for the analysis and policy grounding of health care provision. To some extent, the peculiarities of health care have been recognized by mainstream health economists, who sometimes abandon Paretian welfare considerations to focus on needs instead. This article examines important peculiarities of health care that are relatively neglected in the literature. Some of these concern health care needs: while health itself is a universal need, needs for health care provision are largely involuntary, varied, and idiosyncratic. These issues have important consequences for the planning of health care systems and the extent of transaction costs in any market-based system. These factors, combined with the inherent dynamism of modern health care needs and capabilities, create an opening for alternative approaches to health care economics.

Type
Perspective
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aoki, Masahiko (2001),Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963), ‘Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care’, American Economic Review, 53(5): 941973.Google Scholar
Ross, Ashby W. (1956), An Introduction to Cybernetics, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Ashton, Toni (1998), ‘Contracting for health services in New Zealand: a transaction cost analysis’, Social Science and Medicine, 46(3): 357367.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benson, Susanne G. and Dundis, Stephen P. (2003), ‘Understanding and motivating health care employees: integrating maslow’s hierarchy of needs, training and technology’, Journal of Nursing Management, 11(5): 315320CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blaug, Mark (1998), ‘Where are we now in British health economics?’, Health Economics, 7: S63S78.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boulding, Kenneth E. (1966), ‘The concept of need for health services’, Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, 44(October): 202–23.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Braybrooke, David (1987), Meeting Needs, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica, 4(New Series, November): 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David C. (2005), ‘The making of an economist redux’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1): 175198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corning, Peter A. (2000), ‘Biological adaptation in human societies: a “basic needs” approach’, Journal of Bioeconomics, 2: 4186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Culyer, Anthony J. (1995), ‘Need: the idea won’t do – but we still need it’, Social Science and Medicine, 40(6): 727730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Culyer, Anthony J. (ed.) (1991), The Economics of Health, 2 vols, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Culyer, Anthony J. and Newhouse, Joseph P. (eds) (2000), Handbook of Health Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Culyer, Anthony J. and Wagstaff, A. (1993), ‘Equity and equality in health and health care’, Journal of Health Economics, 12: 431457.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Deci, Edward L. (1975), Intrinsic Motivation, New York: Plenum Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, John (1939), Theory of Valuation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dixon, Anna and Mossialos, Elias(eds) (2002), Health Care Systems in Eight Countries: Trends and Challenges, London: European Observatory on Health Care Systems and London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Doyal, Leonard and Gough, Ian (1991), A Theory of Human Need, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Evans, Karen G. (2000), ‘Reclaiming John Dewey: democracy, inquiry, pragmatism, and public management’, Administration and Society, 32(3): 308328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. (1997), Not Just for Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Goddard, Maria, Hauck, Katharina, Preker, Alex, and Smith, Peter C. (2006), ‘Priority setting in health – a political economy perspective’, Health Economics, Policy and Law, 1(1): 7990.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1945), ‘The use of knowledge in society’, American Economic Review, 35(4): 519530.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2008), ‘An institutional and evolutionary perspective on health economics’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32(2): 235256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsiao, William C. (1995), ‘Abnormal economics in the health sector’, Health Policy, 32:125139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hurley, Jeremiah (2000), ‘An overview of the normative economics of the health sector’, in Culyer, Anthony J. and Newhouse, Joseph P. (eds), Handbook of Health Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 55–118.Google Scholar
Jan, Stephen (2000), ‘Institutional considerations in priority setting: transactions cost perspective on PBMA’, Health Economics, 9: 631–41.3.0.CO;2-N>CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Janssen, Peter P. M., Jonge, Jan de and Bakker, Arnold B. (1999), ‘Specific determinants of intrinsic work motivation, burn-out and turn-over intentions: a study among nurses’, Journal of Advanced Nursing, 29(6): 13601369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Andrew M. (ed.) (2006), The Elgar Companion to Health Economics, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kapp, K. William (1976), ‘The nature and significance of institutional economics’, Kyklos, 29(2): 209232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Labelle, R., Stoddart, G., and Ruffles, T.(1994), ‘An examination of the meaning and importance of supplier-induced demand’, Journal of Health Economics, 13: 347368.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lutz, Mark A. and Lux, Kenneth (1979), The Challenge of Humanistic Economics, Menlo Park, CA: Benjamin/Cummings.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1920), Principles of Economics: An Introductory Volume, 8th edn, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Maslow, Abraham H. (1954), Motivation and Personality, New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Matthew, G. K. (1971), ‘Measuring need and evaluating services’, in Gordon, McLachlan (ed.), Portfolio for Health, London: Oxford University Press, pp. 27–46.Google Scholar
Maynard, Alan (1991), ‘Developing the health care market’, Economic Journal, 101(September): 12771286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McPake, Barbara, Kumaranayake, Lilani, and Normand, Charles (2002), Health Economics: An International Perspective, London and New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mooney, Gavin (1994), Key Issues in Health Economics, Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (1981), ‘Assessing private enterprise: an exegesis of tangled doctrine’, Bell Journal of Economics, 12(1): 93111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G.(1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Newhouse, Joseph P. (1996), ‘Reimbursing health plans and health providers: selection versus efficiency in production’, Journal of Economic Literature, 34(3):12361263.Google Scholar
Nove, Alexander (1979), Political Economy and Soviet Socialism, London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha (2000), Women and Economic Development: The Capabilities Approach, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha and Sen, Amartya(eds)(1993), The Quality of Life, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Reinhardt, U. (1985), ‘The theory of physician-induced demand: reflections after a decade’, Journal of Health Economics, 14: 187193.Google Scholar
Reisman, David (1993), The Political Economy of Health Care, London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rice, Thomas (2001), ‘Should consumer choice be encouraged in health care?’, in Davis, John B. (ed.), The Social Economics of Health Care, London and New York: Routledge, pp. 9–39.Google Scholar
Ryan, Alan (1995), John Dewey and the High Tide of American Liberalism, New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle, translated by Redvers Opie from the second German edition of 1926, first edition 1911, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Scott, Anthony, Maynard, Alan, and Elliott, Robert(eds) (2003), Advances in Health Economics, Chichester: John Wiley.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. (1985), Commodities and Capabilities, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Steers, Richard M. and Porter, Lyman W.(eds) (1991), Motivation and Work Behavior, New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein B. (1919), The Place of Science in Modern Civilization and Other Essays, New York: Huebsch.Google Scholar
Vroom, Victor H. (1964), Work and Motivation, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New York: Free Press.Google Scholar