Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-27T00:42:15.720Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Persistence of Turkey's Majoritarian System of Government

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2013

Abstract

This study uses the case study of a ‘transitioning’ country, Turkey, in exploring institutional endurance and change. In this context it uses the framework of Arend Lijphart's majority and consensus democracy in order to uncover patterns of institutional evolution and persistence which have implications for the nature of its democratic transition. This is achieved through a step-by-step exploration of the key dimensions of democracy discussed by Lijphart. This empirical study seeks to demonstrate that despite the introduction of anti-majoritarian institutions in 1961, Turkey has never consolidated consensus democracy. Instead, since 1982 the trend has been a move towards a system more in line with the majoritarian regime established under the 1924 constitution. As such, the study offers a useful case study of the dynamics of political transformation in the face of institutional persistence, suggesting a need for tracing the history if we are to identify institutional patterns in contrast to the more generalized democratization frameworks.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2012.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Alexander, Gerard, ‘Institutions, Path Dependence, and Democratic Consolidation’, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 13: 3 (2001), pp. 249–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Özbudun, Ergün, ‘Turkey: How Far from Consolidation?’, Journal of Democracy, 7: 3 (1996), pp. 123–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Nikiforos P. Diamandouros and Richard Gunther (eds), Parties, Politics, and Democracy in the New Southern Europe, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2001.

4 Bulsara, Hament and Kissane, Bill, ‘Lijphart and Irish Democracy’, West European Politics, 32: 1 (2009), pp. 172–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Taagepera, Rein, ‘Implication of the Effective Number of Parties for Cabinet Formation’, Party Politics, 8: 2 (2002), p. 3 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Arend Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy, New Haven, CT, and London, Yale University Press, 1999, pp. 90–1.

7 MW/OP = (One-party) + 1/2 [Minimal-winning coalition + Minority government]. See Taagepera, Rein, ‘Arend Lijphart's Dimensions of Democracy: Logical Connections and Institutional Design’, Political Studies, 51 (2003), p. 3 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Metin Heper and Jacob Landau (eds), Political Parties and Democracy in Turkey, London, Tauris, 1991, p. 127.

9 Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy.

10 Kalaycıoğlu, Ersin, Turkish Dynamics, Bridge Across Troubled Lands, New York, Palgrave Macmillan, 2005 Google Scholar.

11 Ibid.

12 Ersin Kalaycıoğlu, ‘Cyclical Breakdown, Redesign and Nascent Institutionalisation: The Turkish Grand National Assembly’, in Ulrika Liebert and Maurizio Cotta (eds), Parliament and Democratic Consolidation in Southern Europe, London and New York, Pinter, 1990.

13 Kalaycıoğlu, ‘Cyclical Breakdown, Redesign and Nascent Institutionalisation’.

14 Ömer Faruk Gençkaya, ‘Reforming Parliamentary Procedure in Turkey’, in Ruşen Keleş, Yasushi Hazama and Ömer Faruk Gençkaya (eds), Aspects of Democratization in Turkey, Tokyo, Institute of Developing Economies (JETRO), 1999, pp. 2–21.

15 Demir, Fırat, ‘Militarization of the Market and Rent-Seeking Coalitions in Turkey’, Development and Change, 36: 4 (2005), pp. 667–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Taagepera, ‘Arend Lijphart's Dimensions of Democracy’.

17 Özbudun, Ergün, Contemporary Turkish Politics: Challenges to Democratic Consolidation, London, Lynne Rienner, 2000 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18 As Özbudun remarks in ibid., there is no area specified in the constitution where a countersignature by the prime minister is not needed, though an exception may be the discretion with which the president can call a referendum or refer laws to the Constitutional Court. Plus, the president has no power to decide the composition of the cabinet.

19 Kalaycıoğlu, Turkish Dynamics.

20 Ibid.

21 Ibid.

22 Gönenç, Levent, ‘Presidential Elements in Government: Turkey’, European Constitutional Law Review, 4 (2008), pp. 488523 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

23 Sayari, Sabri, ‘Towards a New Turkish Party System?’, Turkish Studies, 8: 2 (2007), pp. 197210 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

24 Gönenç, ‘Presidential Elements in Government’.

25 Özbudun, Contemporary Turkish Politics.

26 See Çarkoğlu, Ali, ‘The Turkish Party System in Transition: Party Performance and Agenda Change’, Political Studies, 46 (1998), pp. 541–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 Sabri Sayari, ‘The Changing Party System’, in Sabri Sayari and Yilmaz R. Esmer (eds), Politics, Parties, and Elections in Turkey, Boulder, CO, Lynne Rienner, 2002, p. 27.

28 Sayari, Sabri, ‘Aspects of Party Organisation in Turkey’, Middle East Journal, 30 (1976), pp. 187–99Google Scholar.

29 Kalaycıoğlu, Turkish Dynamics.

30 From Laakso, M. and Taagepera, R., ‘Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 12: 1 (1979), pp. 327 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Fuat Keyman, ‘The Question of Democratic Consolidation in Turkey’, CIEE conference paper, 2009.

32 İlter Turan, ‘Evolution of the Electoral Process’, in Metin Heper and Ahmet Evin (eds), Politics in the Third Turkish Republic, Boulder, CO, Westview Press, 1994.

33 Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell, The Politics of Electoral Systems, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2008; Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy.

34 See Turan, ‘Evolution of the Electoral Process’. While this system has been largely maintained, the introduction of a district-level quota for the 1987 and 1991 elections led to increased disproportionality due to very high threshold levels which worked against small parties.

35 Kalaycıoğlu, Ersin, ‘Elections and Party Preferences in Turkey: Changes and Continuities in the 1990s’, Comparative Political Studies, 27: 3 (1994), pp. 420–2CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Hale, William, ‘The Electoral System and the 2007 Elections: Effects and Debates’, Turkish Studies, 9: 2 (2008), pp. 233–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37 See Ali Çarkoğlu, and Emre Erdoğan, ‘Fairness in the Apportionment of Seats in the Turkish Legislature: Is There Room for Improvement?’, ICPSR Study 1192, 1999.

38 Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy.

39 Özbudun, Contemporary Turkish Politics.

40 Ibid.

41 Özler, Hayrettin and İnaç, Hüsamettin, ‘Problems of Collective Action and Institutionalization in the Turkish Policymaking Environment’, Turkish Studies, 8: 3 (2007), pp. 365–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Öniş, Ziya, ‘Redemocratization and Economic Liberalization in Turkey: The Limits of State Autonomy’, Studies in Comparative International Development, 27: 2 (1992), p. 20 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 Özler and İnaç, ‘Problems of Collective Action and Institutionalization’, p. 391.

43 Taagepera, ‘Arend Lijphart's Dimensions of Democracy’.

44 Metin Heper (ed.), Local Government in Turkey: Governing Greater Istanbul, London, Routledge, 1989, p. 3.

45 Ibid., p. 4.

46 Ibid.

47 Kalaycıoğlu, Ersin, ‘Decentralization of Government’, in Heper, Metin and Evin, Ahmet (eds), Politics in the Third Turkish Republic, Boulder, CO, Westview Press, 1994 Google Scholar.

48 Öniş, ‘Redemocratization and Economic Liberalization’.

49 Köker, Levent, ‘Local Politics and Democracy in Turkey: An Appraisal’, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 540 (1995), pp. 5162 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Robert Devereux, The First Ottoman Constitutional Period: A Study of the Midhat Constitution and Parliament, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1963, p. 227.

51 Cemil Koçak, ‘Parliament Membership during the Single-Party System in Turkey (1925–1945)’, European Journal of Turkish Studies, thematic issue 3 (2005), at http://ejts.revues.org/index497.html.

52 Mardin, Şerif, ‘Centre-Periphery Relations: A Key to Turkish Politics?’, Daedalus, 102: 1 (1973), pp. 169–90Google Scholar.

53 Ibid.

54 Article 71. Devereux, The First Ottoman Constitutional Period, p. 176.

55 Belge, Ceren, ‘Friends of the Court: The Republican Alliance and Selective Activism of the Constitutional Court of Turkey’, Law and Society Review, 40: 3 (2006), pp. 653–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

56 For the period 1984–92, see Hazama, Yasushi, ‘Constitutional Review and the Parliamentary Opposition in Turkey’, Developing Economies, 34: 3 (1996), pp. 316–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

57 Ibid.

58 This reasoning was used a total of four times to strike down constitutional amendments in the 1970s. See Ergün Özbudun, Türk Anayasa Hukuku, Ankara, Yetkin Yayınları, 2009; Özbudun, Contemporary Turkish Politics.

59 The June 2008 headscarf amendment was struck down on the basis that it contravenes the fundamental principles of the Republic, which has been described as a ‘usurpation of power’ for violating Article 148. See Ergün Özbudun and Ömer Faruk Gençkaya, Democratization and the Politics of Constitution-Making in Turkey, Budapest, Central European University Press, 2009.

60 Secretariat General for EU Affairs, Law No 5982, Amending Certain Provisions of the Constitution, 2010.

61 Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy, p. 230.

62 Lijphart, Arend, Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries, New Haven, CT, Yale University Press, 1984, p. 204 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

63 Qvortrup, Mads, ‘Are Referendums Controlled and Pro-hegemonic?’, Political Studies, 48 (2000), pp. 821–6CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

64 David Butler and Austin Ranney, Referendums: A Comparative Study of Practice and Theory, Washington, DC, AEI, 1978, p. 202.

65 Qvortrup, ‘Are Referendums Controlled and Pro-Hegemonic?’.

66 Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy, p. 235.

67 Central Bank of Turkey.

68 See Bulsara and Kissane, ‘Lijphart and Irish Democracy’. The Z-score is calculated in the following way: where x is the original score; μ is the mean of data set; σ is the standard deviation of the data set.

69 As argued by observers such as Metin Heper.

70 Özbudun, Contemporary Turkish Politics.

71 Lichtenstein, Peter M., ‘Book Review on Strategic Choice and Path Dependency in Post-Socialism’, Comparative Economic Studies, 38: 2–3 (1996), pp. 159–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

72 Wolfgang Streeck and Kathleen Thelen (eds), Beyond Continuity, Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2005.

73 Bourdieu, Pierre, ‘Rethinking the State: Genesis and Structure of the Bureaucratic Field’, Sociological Theory, 12: 1 (1994), pp. 34 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

74 Özbudun and Gençkaya, Democratization and the Politics of Constitution-Making, p. 12.

75 Bulsara and Kissane, ‘Lijphart and Irish Democracy’.

76 Belge, ‘Friends of the Court’.

77 Layna Mosley and Andrew Reynolds, ‘The Consequences of Electoral Systems: A Global Study’, 2002, at http://www.unc.edu/polisci/areyno1/pdfs/MosleyReynoldsFeb20031.pdf.

78 İnsel, Ahmet, ‘The AKP and Normalizing Democracy in Turkey’, South Atlantic Quarterly, 102: 2 (2003), pp. 293308 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

79 Bulsara and Kissane, ‘Lijphart and Irish Democracy’.

80 Diamandouros and Gunther, Parties, Politics, and Democracy in the New Southern Europe, p. 81.

81 Bulsara and Kissane, ‘Lijphart and Irish Democracy’.