Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:02:57.054Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introduction: Meeting in the Middle

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2013

Abstract

Compromise is routinely evoked in everyday language and in scholarly debates across the social sciences. Yet, it has been subjected to relatively little systematic study. The introduction to this inter-disciplinary volume addresses the research gap in three steps. First, we offer three reasons for the study of compromise: its empirical omnipresence in politics, its theoretical potential to bridge the rationalist-constructivist divide, and its normative promise to recognize the plurality of society. Second, we introduce different approaches to the coherence, legitimacy and limits of compromise found in the existing explanatory and normative literatures. We discuss why these literatures need to speak to one another, and identify possible applications in empirical research. Third, we conceptualize compromise as one possible solution to a conflict. Distinct from both dissensus and consensus, all compromises share three characteristics: concessions, non-coercion and continued controversy. However, different types of compromise can be distinguished by how mutual, costly and painful concessions are; by whether all forms of coercion are absent; and by the degree to which the relevant parties’ grounds for conflict are transformed. We conclude by discussing the challenge and appeal of ‘politics as compromise’ in plural and complex societies.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2012.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

2 Pope, Jeremy C. and Treier, Shawn, ‘Reconsidering the Great Compromise at the Federal Convention of 1787: Deliberation and Agenda Effects on the Senate and Slavery’, American Journal of Political Studies, 55: 2 (2011), pp. 289306 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lewis, Jeffrey, ‘Is the “Hard Bargaining” Image of the Council Misleading? The Committee of Permanent Representatives and the Local Elections Directive’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 36: 4 (1998), pp. 479504 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ruggie, John G., ‘International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order’, International Organization, 36: 2 (1982), pp. 379415 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Richard Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism: Towards a Politics of Compromise, London, Routledge, 1999; Avishai Margalit, On Compromise and Rotten Compromises, Princeton, Princeton University Press, 2010; M. E. Morrell, Empathy and Democracy: Feeling, Thinking, and Deliberation, University Park, Pennsylvania State University Press, 2010; Christopher H. Achen, ‘Evaluating Political Decision-Making Models’, in Robert Thomson Frans N. Stikman, Christopher H. Achen and Thomas König (eds), The European Union Decides, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2006.

4 Martin Benjamin, Splitting the Difference: Compromise and Integrity in Ethics and Politics, Lawrence, University Press of Kansas, 1990.

5 The underlying disagreements, however, did not go away, which had serious repercussions for the implementation of the agreement.

6 Kornprobst, Markus, ‘The Agent's Logics of Action: Defining and Mapping Political Judgment’, International Theory, 3: 1 (2011), pp. 70104 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Bohman, James, ‘How to Make Social Science Practical: Pragmatism, Critical Social Science and Multiperspectival Theory’, Millennium, 31: 3 (2002), pp. 499524 CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 502.

8 Peter Katzenstein and Rudra Sil, ‘Eclectic Theorizing in the Study and Practice of International Relations’, in Christian Reus-Smit and Duncan Snidal (eds), The Oxford Handbook of International Relations, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2008, p. 109.

9 Isaiah Berlin, The Crooked Timber of Humanity: Chapters in the History of Ideas, ed. Henry Hardy, London, John Murray, 1990, pp. 17–18.

10 Jürgen Habermas, Theorie des kommunikativen Handelns I: Handlungsrationalität und gesellschaftliche Rationalisierung, Frankfurt am Main, Suhrkamp, 1995; Jürgen Habermas, Theorie des kommunikativen Handelns II: Zur Kritik der funktionalistischen Vernunft, Frankfurt am Main, Suhrkamp, 1995.

11 John Rawls, Political Liberalism, New York, Columbia University Press, 2005, pp. 55–6.

12 Rawls, Political Liberalism, p. 4.

13 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, chapter 4. This is not to say, however, that any kind of compromise is warranted. Indeed, there are ‘rotten compromises’, made at the expense of others' humanity. See Margalit, On Compromise.

14 John Morley, On Compromise, London, Macmillan, 1886; James Pennock and John W. Chapman (eds), Compromises in Ethics, Law and Politics, New York, New York University Press, 1979; Luban, David, ‘Bargaining and Compromise: Recent Work on Negotiation and Informal Justice’, Philosophy and Public Affairs, 14: 4 (1985), pp. 397416 Google Scholar. Benjamin, Splitting the Difference; J. Patrick Dobel, Compromise and Political Action: Political Morality in Liberal and Democratic Life, Savage, MD, Rowman and Littlefield, 1990; Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism; Margalit, On Compromise.

15 Morley, On Compromise. p. 1.

16 e.g. May, Simon, ‘Principled Compromise and the Abortion Controversy’, Philosophy and Public Affairs, 33: 4 (2005), pp. 317–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

17 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, p. 114.

18 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, pp. 103–11.

19 Yet there are some leads on this issue in the literature on EU decision-making. See Neyer, Jürgen, ‘Explaining the Unexpected: Efficiency and Effectiveness in European Decision-Making’, Journal of European Public Policy, 11: 1 (2004), pp. 1938 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Christine Reh, ‘Consensus, Compromise and “Inclusive Agreement”: Negotiating Supranational Governance’, in Corneliu Bjola and Markus Kornprobst (eds), Arguing Global Governance: Agency, Lifeworld and Shared Reasoning, London, Routledge, 2010.

20 William Reno, Warlord Politics and African States, London, Longman, 1972; Edward Aspinall, Opposing Suharto: Compromise, Resistance, and Regime Change in Indonesia, Stanford, Stanford University Press, 2005.

21 Ken Cloke, Mediating Dangerously: The Frontiers of Conflict Resolution, New York, John Wiley & Sons, 2001; Edward Newman and Oliver Richmond, ‘Obstacles to Peace Processes: Understanding Spoiling’, in Edward Newman and Oliver Richmond (eds), Challenges to Peacebuilding: Managing Spoilers During Conflict Resolution, Tokyo, United Nations University Press, 2006.

22 Carolyn Shaw, Cooperation, Conflict and Consensus in the Organization of American States, Basingstoke, Palgrave, 2004.

23 George Tsebelis, Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1990, pp. 185–6.

24 Achen, ‘Evaluating Political Decision-Making’; Arregui, Javier and Thomson, Robert, ‘States’ Bargaining Success in the European Union', Journal of European Public Policy, 16: 5 (2009), pp. 655–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 657.

25 Andreas Wimmer, Nationalist Exclusion and Ethnic Conflict: Shadows of Modernity, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2002, p. 31.

26 Ruggie, John G., ‘International Response to Technology: Concepts and Trends’, International Organization, 29: 2 (1975), pp. 557–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 Langner, Carrie A. and Winter, David G., ‘The Motivational Basis of Concessions and Compromise: Archival and Laboratory Studies’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 81: 4 (2001), pp. 711–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 711II.

28 Theodore M. Benditt, ‘Compromising Interests and Principles’, in J. Roland Pennock and John W. Chapman (eds), Compromise in Ethics, Law, and Politics, New York, New York University Press, 1979, p. 26.

29 Joseph H. Carens, ‘Compromises in Politics’, in J. Roland Pennock and John W. Chapman (eds), Compromise in Ethics, Law, and Politics, New York, New York University Press, 1979, p. 126.

30 Erik Oddvar Eriksen, ‘Reflexive Supranationalism in Europe: On the Cogs and Wheels of Integration’, in Erik Oddvar Eriksen, Christian Joerges and Florian Rödl (eds), Law and Democracy in the Post-National Union, Oslo, ARENA, 2006.

31 Habermas, Theorie des kommunikativen Handelns I.

32 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 20.

33 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, pp. 103ff.

34 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 91. ‘Mutual concessions’ and ‘non-coercion’ are defining features of what Margalit calls ‘sanguine compromise’. See Margalit, On Compromise, pp. 48–54.

35 Richard Bellamy and Martin Hollis, ‘Consensus, Neutrality and Compromise’, in Richard Bellamy and Martin Hollis (eds), Pluralism and Liberal Neutrality, London and Portland, OR, Frank Cass, 1999, p. 64; Martin P. Golding, ‘The Nature of Compromise: A Preliminary Inquiry’, in Pennock and Chapman, Compromise in Ethics, p. 13; Hirschman, Albert O., ‘Social Conflicts as Pillars of Democratic Market Society’, Political Theory, 22: 2 (1994), pp. 203–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 214.

36 Langner and Winter, ‘The Motivational Basis’, p. 711II.

37 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 39.

38 Benditt, ‘Compromising Interests’, p. 26; Margalit, On Compromise, p. 20.

39 Quoted in Benditt, ‘Compromising Interests’, p. 45.

40 E. Burke, ‘Speech on Conciliation with America’ (March 1775), in I. Hampshire-Monk (ed.), The Political Philosophy of Edmund Burke, Harlow, Longman, 1987, p. 126.

41 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, p. 101.

42 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 50.

43 Naurin, Daniel, ‘Why Give Reason? Measuring Arguing and Bargaining in Survey Research’, Swiss Political Science Review, 13: 4 (2007), pp. 559–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar, at p. 562.

44 Bellamy, Liberalism and Pluralism, p. 101.

45 David A. Lax and James K. Sebenius, The Manager as Negotiator: Bargaining for Cooperation and Competitive Gain, New York and London, Free Press, 1986, p. 119.

46 Naurin, ‘Why Give Reason?’, p. 563.

47 Morrow, Bruce Bueno De Mesquita James and Zorick, Ethan, ‘Capabilities, Perception, and Escalation’, American Political Science Review, 91: 1 (1997), pp. 1527 Google Scholar.

48 Moravcsik, A., ‘Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International Politics’, International Organization, 51: 4 (1997), pp. 513–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

49 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 48.

50 Ibid., p. 41.

51 Naurin, ‘Why Give Reason?’, p. 563.

52 Margalit, On Compromise, p. 41.

53 Golding, ‘The Nature of Compromise’, p. 16.

54 Benditt, ‘Compromising Interests’, p. 26.

55 We paraphrase here Michael Sandel's famous plea for ‘the possibility that when politics goes well, we can know a good in common that we cannot know alone’ (M. Sandel, Liberalism and the Limits of Justice, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1982, p. 183). However, we follow Henry Richardson in regarding compromise as providing a less romanticized version of that possibility than Sandel's communitarian civic republicanism (H. Richardson, Democratic Autonomy: Public Reasoning about the Ends of Policy, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2002, p. 153).