Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T00:18:41.439Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Agencification in the United States and Germany and What the EU Might Learn From It

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 March 2019

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

In the European Union the legislature has, in the past years, established an increasing number of agencies, granting them increasingly important powers. This phenomenon of agencification is legally problematic because it does not have a legal basis in the EU Treaties. In order to better understand the challenges posed by EU agencification, this Article looks at similar agencification processes in two other federal-type polities, the U.S. and Germany. Germany is especially relevant to understanding the vertical (federal) dimension to EU agencification, while the U.S. experience can inform us about the horizontal (separation of powers) dimension. This is done by looking at three distinct issues: The question of the initial establishment of a new body at the EU (federal) level, the extent to which powers can be entrusted to such a body, and the degree to which the decisions adopted by such bodies are judicially scrutinized. The Article concludes that EU agencification poses a greater risk than agencification in Germany or the US because control is partially less well-established (compared to Germany) and because the EU polity is much less mature (compared to the U.S.).

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2016 by German Law Journal GbR 

References

1 For a general discussion of the phenomenon of agencification in the EU legal order, see Merijn Chamon, EU Agencies: Legal and Political Limits to the Transformation of the EU Administration (forthcoming 2016).Google Scholar

2 See generally Zwart, Tom, Independent Regulatory Agencies in the US, in Agencies in European and Comparative Law 3 (Tom Zwart & Luc Verheij eds., 2003); Hubert Delzangles, L'encadrement des agences américaines de régulation, un modèle pour l'Europe ?, in La legistique dans le systeme de l'Union europeenne: quelle nouvelle approche 163 (Fabienne Peraldi Leneuf & Jacques Normand eds., 2012).Google Scholar

3 See Chamon, Merijn, The Empowerment of Agencies under the Meroni Doctrine and Article 114 TFEU: Comment on United Kingdom v. Parliament and Council (Short-Selling) and the Proposed Single Resolution Mechanism, 39 Eur. L. Rev. 380, 380 n.1 (2014).Google Scholar

4 Scott earlier rejected the notion of decentralization to describe EU agencification. See Colin Scott, Agencies for European Regulatory Governance: A Regimes Approach, in Regulation through Agencies in the EU: A New Paradigm of European Governance 70–71 (Damien Geradin, Rodolphe Muñoz & Nicolas Petit eds., 2005).Google Scholar

5 See Bach, also Tobias & Jann, Werner, Des animaux dans un zoo administratif: le changement organisationnel et l'autonomie des agences en Allemagne, 76 Revue Internationale des Sciences Administratives 469, 470–71 (2010).Google Scholar

6 Kelemen, Daniel & Tarrant, Andrew, The Political Foundations of the Eurocracy, 34 W. Eur. Pol. 922, 923 (2011); Mark Thatcher, The Creation of European Regulatory Agencies and its Limits: A Comparative Analysis of European Delegation, 18 J. Eur. Pub. Pol'y 790, 791 (2011).Google Scholar

7 See Majone, Giandomenico, The Agency Model: The Growth of Regulation and Regulatory Institutions in the European Union, 3 EIPASCOPE 1, 16 (1997). See generally Jacqueline Dutheil de la Rochère, EU Regulatory Agencies: What Future do They Have?, in Views of European Law from the Mountain 355 (Mielle Bulterman et al. eds., 2009).Google Scholar

8 See Wittinger, Michaela, Europäische Satelliten: Anmerkungen zum Europäischen Agentur(un)wesen und zur Vereinbarkeit Europäischer Agenturen mit dem Gemeinschaftsrecht, 42 Europarecht 618, 618 (2008); Isabelle Muller-Quoy, L'apparition et le développement des Agences de l'Union européenne, in Les Agences de l'Union européenne: Recherche sur les organismes communautaires décentralisés 17 (Jean-Francois Couzinet ed., 2002); Martijn Groenleer, The European Commission and Agencies, in The European Commission 163 (David Spence ed., 2006); Michael Berger, Vertraglich nicht vorgesehene Einrichtungen des Gemeinschaftsrechts mit eigener Rechtspersönlichkeit 89–90 (1999).Google Scholar

9 Treaty of Lisbon Amending the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty Establishing the European Community, Dec. 13, 2007, 2007 O.J. (C. 306) Art. 17 [hereinafter TFEU Art. 17].Google Scholar

10 See sources cited infra note 48.Google Scholar

11 Case C-359/92, Germany v. Council, 1994 E.C.R. I-3681, para. 38.Google Scholar

12 Case C-270/12, United Kingdom v. Parliament and Council, ECLI:EU:C:2014:18 [hereinafter Short-selling].Google Scholar

13 Apart from the English language version, the Bulgarian, Danish, Estonian, Greek, Gaelic, Slovenian, Slovak, Romanian, and Swedish language versions also refer to “agencies.”Google Scholar

14 See Short-selling, supra note 12.Google Scholar

15 Case 9/56, Meroni & Co. v. High Authority, 1957–1958 E.C.R. 133, 153.Google Scholar

16 See Short-selling, supra note 12“ para. 53.Google Scholar

17 Even if the Court in Short-selling still confirmed that EU agencies cannot exercise discretionary powers.Google Scholar

18 See Short-selling, supra note 12, at para. 53.Google Scholar

19 For a discussion of this case and its possible repercussions, see sources cited infra note 110; Chamon, supra note 3. See generally Rob Van Gestel, European Regulatory Agencies Adrift?, 21 Maastricht J. Eur. & Comp. L. 188 (2014).Google Scholar

20 U.S. Const. art. II, §§ 1, 3.Google Scholar

21 U.S. Const. art. II, § 2.Google Scholar

22 See United States v. Germaine, 99 U.S. 508, 509–10 (1878) (confirming the distinction between inferior and principal offers). A clear definition of the constitutional notion of “inferior officers” is still lacking.Google Scholar

23 See Custos, Dominique, The Rulemaking Power of Independent Regulatory Agencies, 54 Am. J. Comp. L. 615, 615 (2006).Google Scholar

24 Steele, Charles & Bowman, Jeffrey, The Constitutionality of Independent Regulatory Agencies under the Necessary and Proper Clause: The Case of the Federal Election Commission, 4 Yale J. on Reg. 363, 369 (1987).Google Scholar

25 Maryland, McCulloch v., 17 U.S. 316, 415 (1819).Google Scholar

26 Although there is no general consensus on exact terminology in the U.S., three basic groups of agencies are generally distinguished: Cabinet agencies (e.g. the Food and Drug Administration), executive agencies (e.g. the Environmental Protection Agency), and independent agencies (e.g. the Federal Trade Commission). See Abraham Ribicoff, Congressional Oversight and Regulatory Reform, 28 Admin. L. Rev. 415, 416 (1976); Peter Strauss, The Place of Agencies in Government: Separation of Powers and the Fourth Branch, 84 Colum. L. Rev. 573, 583 (1984). The cabinet agencies operate under a regular department, whereas the latter two do not. Yet, both the cabinet and executive agencies should be situated within the executive branch.Google Scholar

27 President's Committee on Administrative Management, Report on the Administrative Management in the Government of the United States, U.S. Sen., 29 (1937).Google Scholar

28 Myers v. United States, 272 U.S. 52, 163–64 (1926).Google Scholar

29 Humphrey's Ex'r v. United States, 295 U.S. 602, 629 (1935). A unified “for cause” standard does not exist. The legislator may be more or less specific in its statutes as to the grounds on which an officer may be removed. See Kent Barnett, Avoiding Independent Agency Armageddon, 87 Notre Dame L. Rev. 1349, 1352 (2012).Google Scholar

30 Humphrey's Ex'r v. United States, 295 U.S. 602, 625–26 (1935).Google Scholar

31 Id. at 628.Google Scholar

32 Davidson, Peter, Chipping Away at the President's Control over His Administration: An Analysis of Morrison v. Olson and Beyond, 6 J. L. & Pol. 205, 217 (1989). As Davidson remarks, this was further confirmed in Wiener. See Wiener v. United States, 357 U.S. 349 (1958).Google Scholar

33 However, in a concurring opinion, Justice Stevens rejected the qualification of the Comptroller General's powers as “executive” in nature. See Bowsher v. Synar, 478 U.S. 714, 757 (1986).Google Scholar

34 Bowsher, 478 U.S. at 734. As Stack observes, the Reagan administration hoped that the Court would rule the President may remove the Comptroller General at will, possibly setting a precedent for other independent agencies. See Kevin Stack, Obama's Equivocal Defense of Agency Independence, 26 Const. Comment. 583, 590 (2010).Google Scholar

35 Olson, Morrison v., 487 U.S. 654, 689 (1988).Google Scholar

36 Id. at 691.Google Scholar

37 Id. at 691–92.Google Scholar

38 See Stack, , supra note 34, at 594.Google Scholar

39 See id. Google Scholar

40 See Free Enterprise Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd., 561 U.S. 477 (2010).Google Scholar

41 Id. at 484.Google Scholar

42 Id. at 497–498. Huq criticized the Court's opinion arguing that (1) “control” should not be reduced to the power of removal and (2) the link between Presidential control and democratic accountability is not that strong. See Aziz Huq, Removal as a Political Question, 65 Stan. L. Rev. 1, 3 (2013).Google Scholar

43 See Free Enterprise Fund, 561 U.S. at 520.Google Scholar

45 Chief Justice Roberts further contemplated the idea of a multiple, rather than a double-layered protection, using the metaphor of a matryoshka doll. See Free Enterprise Fund, 561 U.S. at 496.Google Scholar

46 See infra Part E.I.Google Scholar

47 See infra Part E.II.Google Scholar

48 See generally Geradin, Damien, The Development of European Regulatory Agencies: What the EU Should Learn from the American Experience, 11 Colum. J. Eur. L. 1 (2004); François van der Mensbrugghe, The Danger of Excessive Delegations to Independent Administrative Agencies: The Example of the U.S.A., in European Regulatory Agencies 113 (Giacinto Della Cananea ed., 2005); Christian Stoffaës, Network Regulation on a Federal Scale: Lessons for Europe from the American Perspective, in European Regulatory Agencies 137 (Giacinto Della Cananea ed., 2005); Miroslava Scholten, The Political Accountability of EU Agencies: Learning from the US Experience (2014). Shapiro does take note of this issue. See Martin Shapiro, A Comparison of US and European Independent Agencies, in Comparative Administrative Law 300 (Susan Rose-Ackerman & Peter Lindseth eds., 2010).Google Scholar

49 See, e.g., Calabresi, , infra note 94; Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 922–23 (1997).Google Scholar

50 See, e.g., Olson, Morrison v., 487 U.S. 654, 689 (1988); A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 542 (1935).Google Scholar

51 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BVerfG] [Federal Constituional Court] Dec. 20, 2007, Hartz IV-Arbeitsgemeinschaften, 119 Entscheidungen Des Bundesverfassungsgerichts [BVerfGE] 331, 365.Google Scholar

52 The German Parliament provides an English translation of the Grundgesetz. See Grundgesetz [GG] [Basic Law], translation at http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de/englisch_gg/englisch_gg.html#p0060.Google Scholar

53 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII.Google Scholar

54 Fisher, Howard, The German Legal System and Legal Language: A General Survey Together with Notes and German Vocabulary 5–6, 11 (4th ed. 2002).Google Scholar

55 See, e.g., Wentzel, Joachim, Agenturen im deutschen Verwaltungskontext: Nachzügler oder Vorreiter?, 63 Die Öffentliche Verwaltung 768 (2010).Google Scholar

56 A Quango is a quasi-autonomous non-governmental organization in the U.K. See Kristian Fischer, Quangos—An Unknown Species in German Public Law? German Report on the Rulemaking Power of Independent Administrative Agencies, in Recent Trends in German and European Constitutional Law 153, 195–60 (Eibe Riedel & Rudiger Wolfrum eds., 2006). Bach also stresses that the bodies of indirect administration are typically not involved in core public-sector functions. See Tobias Bach, Germany, in Government Agencies: Practices and Lessons from 30 Countries 166, 167–69 (Koen Verhoest et al. eds., 2012).Google Scholar

57 The following are some of the bodies other than ministries, representing Germany in EU agencies: Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht [BaFin] [Federal Financial Supervisory Authority] which is an Anstalt; and Bundesinstitut für Arzneimittel und Medizinprodukte [BfArM] [Federal Institute for Drugs and Medical Devices], Eisenbahn-Bundesamt [EBA] [Federal Railway Authority], Bundesnetzagentur [BNetzA] [Federal Network Agency], and Bundesamt für Sicherheit in der Informationstechnik [BSI] [Federal Office for Information Security] which are selbständige Bundesoberbehörde. Google Scholar

58 Ziller, Jacques, Multilevel Governance and Executive Federalism: Comparing Germany and the European Union, in The European Union Legal Order After Lisbon 265 (Patrick Birkinshaw & Mike Varney eds., 2010).Google Scholar

59 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BVerfG] [Federal Constitutional Court] Feb. 28, 1961, 1. Rundfunkentscheidung, 12 BVerfGE 205, 229.Google Scholar

60 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 83.Google Scholar

61 This is the so called Ausführung als eigene Angelegenheit. Google Scholar

62 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 85. For a more elaborate discussion of these two types of Bundesverwaltung, see Ziller, supra note 58, at 268–74.Google Scholar

63 The Bundeseigene Verwaltung therefore is one possible form of Bundesverwaltung, next to the options under Article 84 GG and Article 85 GG.Google Scholar

64 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 87 (3).Google Scholar

65 Bundesverfassungsgericht [BVerfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], July 24, 1962, Kreditwesen, 14 BVerfGE 197, 202 [hereinafter Kreditwesen]. Google Scholar

66 Id. at 210.Google Scholar

67 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 73, 74.Google Scholar

68 Kalkbrenner, Helmut, Zur Errichtung von Bundesoberbehörden nach Art. 87 III GG, 7 Juristenzeitung [JZ] 211 (1963).Google Scholar

69 Hömig, Dieter, Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland 515 (2010).Google Scholar

70 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BVerfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Dec. 5, 2001, Moratorium Gorleben, 104 BVerfGE 238, 247 (own translation).Google Scholar

71 Hans-Jürgen Papier, Die Regionalisierung der gesetzlichen Rentenversicherung aus verfassungsrechtlicher Sicht, 4 Neue Zeitschrift für Sozialrecht 6, 242 (1995).Google Scholar

72 Ibler, Martin, Artikel 87 GG, in Grundgesetz: Kommentar, München, Beck, Ergänzungslieferung 64, 205 (Theodor Maunz & Günter Dürig eds., 2012). In case the matter falls with a concurring competence, the conditions for using such a competence should of course also be met. Focusing on the Erforderlichkeitsklausel, see Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 72 (2).Google Scholar

73 See Ibler, , supra note 72, at 209.Google Scholar

74 It should be noted that the original draft of the Basic Law prescribed the consent of the Bundesrat for laws establishing Bundesoberbehörden. In the end, this provision did not make it to the final version. Further on this and on the proposed amendment in the 1990's, see id. at 198–201.Google Scholar

75 Id. at 205.Google Scholar

76 Ibler, , supra note 72, at 210–11.Google Scholar

77 Kreditwesen at 213–14.Google Scholar

78 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII, art. 80 (1). The Bundesverwaltungsgericht [Federal Administrative Court] has confirmed that an Anstalt may be empowered either through (1) its establishing law, (2) a subsequent law, or (3) a Rechtsverordnung. See Bundesverwaltungsgericht, [1996] 102 BVerwGE 119, 126. Appel and Eding conclude that Bundesoberbehörden may also be empowered through Rechtsverordnungen. See generally Markus Appel & Annegret Eding, Verfassungsrechtliche Fragen der Verordnungsermächtigung des § 2 II NABEG, 6 Neue Zeitschrift für Verwaltungsrecht [NVwZ] 344 (2012).Google Scholar

79 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Besoldungsgesetz von Nordrhein-Westfalen, Dec. 1, 1954, 4 BVerfGE 115, 140; Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Volksbefragung Hessen, July 30, 1958, 8 BVerfGE 122, 138–39.Google Scholar

80 See Ibler, , supra note 72, at pp. 211–12.Google Scholar

81 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Zollkriminalamt, Mar. 3, 2004, 110 BVerfGE 33, 49; Kreditwesen at 211.Google Scholar

82 See Reicherzer, Max, Bundesoberbehörden: Trojanische Pferde für den Föderalismus? Zur Verfassungsmäßigkeit der Zuständigkeitsbestimmungen im TEHG, 8 NVwZ 877 (2005).Google Scholar

83 Reicherzer specifically takes issue with the Court's “blunt” a contrario reasoning. To Reicherzer, it follows from the exceptional character of Article 87 (3) first sentence that the pouvoir constituant would have intended the provision to be used only when a clear need can be shown, albeit that the threshold required should not be as high as that of Article 87 (3) GG in the second sentence. See Reicherzer, supra note 82.Google Scholar

84 See id. at 877–80.Google Scholar

85 Atlas Roofing Co., Inc. v. Occupational Safety Comm'n, 430 U.S. 442, 455 (1977).Google Scholar

86 Humphrey's Ex'r v. United States, 295 U.S. 602, 625–26 (1935).Google Scholar

87 INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919, 984–86 (1983) (White, J., dissenting).Google Scholar

88 Union Bridge Co. v. United States, 204 U.S. 364, 385 (1907).Google Scholar

89 Stranahan, Buttfield v., 192 U.S. 470, 496 (1904).Google Scholar

90 Union Bridge Co. v. United States, 204 U.S. 364, 385 (1907) (emphasis added).Google Scholar

91 United States v. Chicago, 282 U.S. 311, 324 (1931).Google Scholar

92 Hampton & Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 394, 409 (1928).Google Scholar

93 N.Y. Central S. Corp. v. United States, 287 U.S. 12, 25 (1932); Federal Radio Comm'n v. Nelson Bros. B. & M. Co., 289 U.S. 266, 285 (1933).Google Scholar

94 Sometimes it may be debated whether a delegation problem is at issue or not. For instance, in Clinton v. City of New York, the U.S. Supreme Court held part of the Line Item Veto Act of 1996 unconstitutional because it created a new procedure to pass legislation. Calabresi argued that this case was not about legislative procedure but about a delegation of powers from Congress to the President. See Steven Calabresi, Separation of Powers and the Rehnquist Court: The Centrality of Clinton v. City of New York, 99 Nw. U. L. Rev. 77, 8586 (2004). Justice Scalia, writing for the minority indeed argued as such. See Clinton v. City of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 465 (1988).Google Scholar

95 Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.S. 388, 415 (1935).Google Scholar

96 Id. at 426.Google Scholar

97 A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 542 (1935). Justice Cardozo, who dissented in Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, wrote a concurring opinion, setting out why he thought the two delegations were different and why the Schechter delegation did not conform to the limits he set out in Panama. See id. at 551–55.Google Scholar

98 See also Schütze, Robert, “Delegated” Legislation in the (New) European Union: A Constitutional Analysis, 74 Mod. L. Rev. 5, 664 (2011).Google Scholar

99 See United States v. Chicago, 282 U.S. 311, 324 (1931).Google Scholar

100 See INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 985 (1983).Google Scholar

101 Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 310 U.S. 381, 398–99 (1940).Google Scholar

102 Yukas v. United States, 321 U.S. 414, 425–26 (1944).Google Scholar

103 See van der Mensbrugghe, supra note 48, at 118.Google Scholar

104 See, for example Brown & Williamson, where the Supreme Court held that the FDA was not competent to regulate tobacco products: given tobacco's cultural and economic importance it could not be assumed that Congress had implicitly granted jurisdiction to the FDA. FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 529 U.S. 120, 159–60 (2000).Google Scholar

105 United States v. Delaware & Hudson Co., 213 U.S. 366, 408–09 (1909).Google Scholar

106 Indus. Union Dep't, AFL-CIO v. Am. Petrol. Inst., 448 U.S. 607, 646 (1980).Google Scholar

107 Cluff, Brigham, American Trucking and the Nondelegation Doctrine: A New Twist on an Old Doctrine, 40 Jurimetrics 485, 491–93 (2000).Google Scholar

108 Case 25/70, Köster, 1970 E.C.R. 1161.Google Scholar

109 See Short-selling, supra note 12, paras 41–53.Google Scholar

110 Ohler, Christoph, Rechtsetzungsbefugnisse der Europäischen Wertpapier- und Marktaufsichtsbehörde (ESMA), 69 JZ 5, 251 (2014); Magdalena Skowron, Kapitalmarktrecht: Rechtmäßigkeit der Eingriffsbefugnisse der ESMA nach Art. 28 Leerverkaufsverordnung, 25 Europäische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht [EuZW] 349, 353 (2014).Google Scholar

111 Ibler, , supra note 72, at 218–20.Google Scholar

112 See Ruffert, Matthias, Regulierung im System des Verwaltungsrechts - Grundstrukturen des Privatisierungsfolgerechts der Post und Telekommunikation, 124 Archiv des öffentlichen Rechts 237, 277 n.176 (1999).Google Scholar

113 Halberstam also notes that the birth of the Bundesnetzagentur was not the result of an indigenous development but followed from EU law requirements. See Daniel Halberstam, The Promise of Comparative Administrative Law: A Constitutional Perspective on Independent Agencies, in Edward Elgar, Comparative Administrative Law 197 (Susan Rose-Ackerman & Peter Lindseth eds., 2010).Google Scholar

114 Ludwigs, Markus, Die Bundesnetzagentur auf dem Weg zur Independent Agency? Europarechtliche Anstöße und verfassungsrechtliche Grenzen, 44 Die Verwaltung 1, 41 (2011).Google Scholar

115 Id. at 42.Google Scholar

116 This is of course relevant to all EU Member States.Google Scholar

117 Case C-518/07, Commission v. Germany, 2010 E.C.R. I-1885, para. 1.Google Scholar

118 AG Mazàk further noted that the problem in this case also related to the conflict between the traditional concept of administration and the (more modern) concept based on decentralization. See Opinion of Advocate General Mazák, Case C-518/07, Commission v. Germany, 2010 E.C.R. I-1885, para. 8; sources cited supra note 6.Google Scholar

119 Case C-518/07 at para. 42.Google Scholar

120 See Case C-424/07, Commission v. Germany, 2009 E.C.R. I-11431.Google Scholar

121 A number of German authors have therefore criticized Short-selling for its lack of attention to the repercussions on the Demokratieprinzip. See Ohler, supra note 110, at 250–52.Google Scholar

122 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Lippeverband, Dec. 5, 2002, 107 BVerfGE 59, 87-88 [hereinafter Lippeverband]; Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constitutional Court], Mitbestimmungsgesetz Schleswig-Holstein, May 24, 1995, 93 BVerfGE 37, 67.Google Scholar

123 Wiedemann, Richard, Unabhängige Verwaltungsbehörden und die Rechtsprechung des BVerfG, in Unabhängige Regulierungsbehörden: Organisationsrechtliche Herausforderungen in Frankreich und Deutschland 46–47 (Johannes Masing & Gérard Marcou eds., 2010).Google Scholar

124 Lippeverband, at 122.Google Scholar

125 Ludwigs, , supra note 114, at 47.Google Scholar

126 According to Ludwigs, if independence is absolutely necessary (zwingend erforderlich) for an authority to achieve its policy objectives, this could also justify a Demokratiedefizit. Id. at 48.Google Scholar

127 See Wiedemann, , supra note 123, at 48. On the power to issue directives, see Georg Hermes, Abhängige und unabhängige Verwaltungsbehörden - ein Überblick über die Bundesverwaltung, in Unabhängige Regulierungsbehörden: Organisationsrechtliche Herausforderungen in Frankreich und Deutschland 68 (Johannes Masing & Gérard Marcou eds., 2010).Google Scholar

128 Madison, Marbury v., 5 U.S. 137, 177 (1803).Google Scholar

129 In addition, when Congress explicitly delegated the power to interpret or refine the law to an agency, courts deferred under an arbitrary and capricious test of the Administrative Procedure Act. See 5 U.S.C. § 706 (2012).Google Scholar

130 Jellum, Linda, The Impact of the Rise and Fall of Chevron on the Executive's Power to Make and Interpret Law, 44 Loy. U. Chicago. L.J. 141, 160–61 (2012).Google Scholar

131 Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 323 U.S. 134, 136–37 (1944).Google Scholar

132 Id. at 139–40.Google Scholar

133 Id. at 140.Google Scholar

134 See Krueger, Matthew, In Search of the Modern Skidmore Standard, 107 Colum. L. Rev. 1235, 1239 (2007).Google Scholar

135 See Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984).Google Scholar

136 See Jellum, , supra note 130, at 165.Google Scholar

137 See Farina, Cynthia, Statutory Interpretation and the Balance of Power in the Administrative State, 89 Colum. L. Rev. 452, 466 (1989).Google Scholar

138 Gosset, David, Chevron, Take Two: Deference to Revised Agency Interpretations of Statutes, 64 U. Chi. L. Rev. 681, 688–90 (1997).Google Scholar

139 Chevron, 467 U.S. 837 at 840.Google Scholar

140 Id. at 840 n.2.Google Scholar

141 Id. at 842–43.Google Scholar

142 Sunstein, Cass, Law and Administration After Chevron, 90 Colum. L. Rev. 2071, 2075 (1990).Google Scholar

143 Merril, Thomas, Judicial Deference to Executive Precedent, 101 Yale L.J. 969, 969–70 (1992). But Merril himself rejects the idea of Chevron as a counter-Marbury. Later, the U.S. Supreme Court also ruled that Chevron deference trumps stare decisis when an agency interprets ambiguous text previously interpreted by a court. See National Cable & Telecommunications Association et al. v. Brand X Internet Services et al., 545 U.S. 967, 982–83 (2005).Google Scholar

144 Merril, Thomas & Hickman, Kristin, Chevron's Domain, 89 Geo. L.J. 833, 873 (2001).Google Scholar

145 It is not clear what is to be understood by the force of law and in Christensen, but especially in United States v. Mead Corp., 533 U.S. 218 (2001), the Court further complicated the issue. See also Linda Jellum, United States Court of Appeals for Veterans Claims: Has It Mastered Chevron's Step Zero, 3 Veterans L. Rev. 1, 8797 (2011).Google Scholar

146 The deference in Chevron was not only based on the agency's expertise, but also on its political accountability, coming under the authority of the President. Evidently this second element applies much less to the independent agencies but the U.S. Supreme Court has still afforded Chevron deference to independent agencies. For a discussion, see Randolph May, Defining Deference Down: Independent Agencies and Chevron Deference, 58 Admin. L. Rev. 429, 429–53 (2006).Google Scholar

147 See Christensen v. Harris County, 529 U.S. 576 (2000).Google Scholar

148 Id. at 587. In his concurring opinion, Justice Scalia dismissed Skidmore as an anachronism, arguing that Chevron deference should be applied in this case as well. Justice Scalia still concurred, because he found the interpretation of the Department of Labor unreasonable in any case. Id. at 589–91.Google Scholar

149 See United States v. Mead Corp., 533 U.S. 218 (2001).Google Scholar

150 Id. at 229–31.Google Scholar

151 Id. at 229.Google Scholar

152 Id. at 229–31.Google Scholar

153 Id. at 245.Google Scholar

154 Sunstein, Cass, Chevron Step Zero, 92 Va. L. Rev. 187, 216 (2005).Google Scholar

155 See Walton, Barnhart v., 535 U.S. 212 (2002).Google Scholar

156 In MCI, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that where an agency has the authority to “modify” certain requirements in a section of the basic statute this cannot be understood as granting the power to fundamentally alter that section, because “modifying” is commonly understood as (only) “changing slightly or incrementally.” See MCI Telecomm. Corp. v. Am. Telephone & Telegraph Co., 512 U.S. 218, 225–26 (1994); FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 529 U.S. 120, 160 (2000).Google Scholar

157 Sunstein proposes to include these questions in Chevron step One, because this would otherwise mean that courts become competent to solve major questions for which they have no superior claim than the executive branch. See Sunstein, supra note 154, at 243.Google Scholar

158 See Merril and Hickman, supra note 144.Google Scholar

159 A search in the HeinOnline database for the query “Chevron deference” results in hundreds of academic contributions discussing (and generally criticizing) Chevron and the cases which followed it.Google Scholar

160 See Short-selling, supra note 12, para. 53.Google Scholar

161 See Case T-187/06, Schräder v. CPVO, 2008 E.C.R. II-3151, para. 59; Case T-96/10, Rütgers Germany GmbH e.a. v. ECHA, ECLI:EU:T:2013:109, para. 134.Google Scholar

162 See Chamon, Merijn, EU Agencies: Does the Meroni Doctrine Make Sense?, 17 Maastricht J. Eur. & Comp. L. 281, 294 (2010).Google Scholar

163 For a discussion, see generally Merijn Chamon, EU Risk Regulators and EU Procedural Law, 5 Eur. J. Risk Reg. 3 (2014).Google Scholar

164 For a discussion, see Heinrich Amadeus Wolff, Nachprüfung von Ermessensentscheidungen, in Verwaltungsgerichtsordnung: VwGO 2395 (Helge Sodan & Jan Ziekow eds., 2014).Google Scholar

165 However, Ludwigs notes that EU legislation does not require national judges to be deferential to regulatory authorities, as is also apparent from the discussion of Arcor, since it only deals with the NRA's relationship with the legislator. See Ludwigs, supra note 114, at 68–69.Google Scholar

166 See Wieland, Joachim, Regulierungsermessen im Spannungsverhältnis zwischen deutschem und Unionsrecht, 64 Die Öffentliche Verwaltung 705, 706 (2011).Google Scholar

167 Case C-55/06, Arcor AG & Co. KG, 2008 E.C.R. I-2931, para. 39.Google Scholar

168 Id. at para. 159.Google Scholar

169 Id. at para. 170.Google Scholar

170 Verwaltungsgericht Köln [Cologne Administrative Court], Aug. 27, 2009, 1 K 3427/01, para. 121. See also Ludwigs, supra note 114, at 66.Google Scholar

171 Bundesverwaltungsgericht [BverwG] [Federal Administrative Court] Nov. 23, 2011, 6 C 13.10, para. 38.Google Scholar

172 See Attendorn, Thorsten, Das “Regulierungsermessen” Ein deutscher “Sonderweg” bei der gerichtlichen Kontrolle tk-rechtlicher Regulierungsentscheidungen?, 12 MultiMedia und Recht 238, 239 (2009).Google Scholar

173 Ludwigs, Markus, Das Regulierungsermessen als Herausforderung für die letztentscheidungsdogmatik im Verwaltungsrecht, 64 JZ 6, 292–94 (2009); see also Matthias Jestaedt, Maßstäbe des Verwaltungshandelns, in Allgemeines Verwaltungsrecht 351 (Hans-Uwe Erichsen ed., 2010).Google Scholar

174 Wimmer, Norbert, Kontrolldichte - Beobachtungen zum richterlichen Umgang mit Entscheidungsprärogativen, 65 JZ 433, 433 (2010).Google Scholar

175 Grundgesetz für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland [Grundgesetz] [GG] [Basic Law], May 23, 1949, BGBI. VIII. Art. 19(4).Google Scholar

176 See Bundesverfassungsgericht [BverfG] [Federal Constituional Court] 1973, 119 BverfGE 263, 274.Google Scholar

177 See Opinion of Advocate General Jacobs in Case C-269/90, Technische Universität München, 1991 E.C.R. I-5469, para. 11. Note the Bundesfinanzhof's problem with the well-established limited review standard of the Court of Justice in Technische Universität München. Google Scholar

178 Wimmer, , supra note 174, at 435.Google Scholar

179 See id. at 438; see also Attendorn, supra note 172, at 241.Google Scholar

180 Case C-424/07, Commission v. Germany, 2009 E.C.R. I-11431.Google Scholar

181 Id. at paras 53–100.Google Scholar

182 Gärditz, Klaus Ferdinand, Anmerkung zur Rechtssache C-424/07, 65 JZ 198, 200 (2010).Google Scholar

183 Ludwigs, , supra note 114, at 68.Google Scholar

184 See for example the Court's observation in Mistretta: “[O]ur jurisprudence has been driven by a practical understanding that in our increasingly complex society … Congress simply cannot do its job absent an ability to delegate power.” See Mistretta v. United States, 488 U.S. 361, 372 (1989).Google Scholar

185 Geradin, , supra note 48, at 13.Google Scholar

186 See Marshall, William, Eleven Reasons Why Presidential Power Inevitably Expands and Why It Matters, 88 B.U. L. Rev. 505, 507–09 (2008).Google Scholar

187 See id. at 509.Google Scholar

188 On the new—more permissive—delegation doctrine resulting from Short-selling, see Miroslava Scholten & Marloes Van Rijsbergen, The Limits of Agencification in the European Union, 15 German L.J. 1223, 1249 (2014).Google Scholar

189 European Commission, European Governance - A White Paper, at 24, COM (2001) 428 final (Mar. 29, 2016).Google Scholar