Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T22:07:44.619Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The timing of the popping: using the log-periodic power law model to predict the bursting of bubbles on financial markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 August 2016

Marcus Gustavsson
Affiliation:
Linköping University
Daniel Levén
Affiliation:
Linköping University
Hans Sjögren*
Affiliation:
Linköping University
*
Marcus Gustavsson, Daniel Levén and Hans Sjögren, Department of Management and Engineering, Linköping University, SE-581 83 Linköping, Sweden. Corresponding author: Hans Sjögren, email [email protected]

Abstract

The occurrence and unpredictability of speculative bubbles on financial markets, and their accompanying crashes, have confounded economists and economic historians worldwide. We examine the ability of the log-periodic power law model (LPPL-model) to accurately predict the end dates of speculative bubbles on financial markets through modeling of asset price dynamics on a selection of historical bubbles. The method is based on a nonlinear least squares estimation that yields predictions of when the bubble will change regime. Previous studies have only presented results where the predictions turn out to be successful. This study is the first to highlight both the potential and the limitations of the LPPL-model. We find evidence that supports the characteristic patterns as proposed by the LPPL-framework leading up to the change in regime; asset prices during bubble periods seem to oscillate around a faster-than-exponential growth. In most cases the estimation yields accurate predictions, although we conclude that the predictions are quite dependent on the point in time at which they are conducted. We also find that the end of a speculative bubble seems to be influenced by both endogenous speculative growth and exogenous factors. For this reason we propose a new way of interpreting the predictions of the model, where the end dates should be interpreted as the start of a time period where the asset prices are especially sensitive to exogenous events. We propose that negative news during this time period results in a regime shift and the bursting of the bubble. Thus, the model has the ability to predict sensitivity to exogenous events ex ante.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Sources

The Economist Google Scholar

References

Abreu, D. and Brunnermeier, M. K. (2003). Bubbles and crashes. Econometrica, 71, pp. 173204.Google Scholar
Blakey, G. G. (2010/2011). A History of the London Stock Market 1945–2009, 6th edn. London: Harriman House.Google Scholar
Elliot, R. N. (1938/2012). The Wave Principle. New York: Snowball Publishing.Google Scholar
Filimonov, V. and Sornette, D. (2013). A stable and robust calibration scheme of the log-periodic power law model. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Applications, 392, pp. 3698–707.Google Scholar
Geraskin, P. and Fantazzini, D. (2011). Everything you always wanted to know about log-periodic power laws for bubble modeling but were afraid to ask. European Journal of Finance, 19, pp. 366–91.Google Scholar
Gustavsson, M. and Levén, D. (2015). The predictability of speculative bubbles: an examination of the log-period power law model. Master's thesis, Business and Economics Programme, Linköping University.Google Scholar
Johansen, A. and Sornette, D. (2010). Endogenous versus exogenous crashes in financial markets. Brussels Economic Review, 53, pp. 201–53.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. and Aliber, R. Z. (1978/2011). Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises , 6th edn. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lowenstein, R. (2004). Origins of the Crash: The Great Bubble and Its Undoing. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Mizen, P. (2008). The credit crunch of 2007–2008: a discussion of the background, market reactions, and policy responses. Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Reviews, 90, pp. 53167.Google Scholar
Nofsinger, J. R. and Sias, R. W. (1999). Herding and feedback trading by institutional and individual investors. The Journal of Finance, 54, pp. 2263–95.Google Scholar
Robles, M., Torero, M. and von Braun, J. (2009). When speculation matters. IFPRI Brief 57.Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (1984). Stock prices and social dynamics. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 457510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational Exuberance. New York: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sornette, D., Johansen, A. and Bouchaud, J. (1996). Stock market crashes, precursors and replicas. Journal de Physique I, 6, pp. 167–75.Google Scholar
Sornette, D., Woodard, R., Yan, W. and Zhou, W.-X. (2013). Clarifications to questions and criticisms on the Johansen-Ledoit-Sornette bubble model. Physica A, 392, pp. 4417–28.Google Scholar
Sornette, D., Woodard, R. and Zhou, W.-X. (2009). The 2006–2008 oil bubble: evidence of speculation and prediction. Physica A, 388, pp. 1571–6.Google Scholar
Vandewalle, N., Ausloos, M., Boveroux, P. and Minguet, A. (1999). Visualizing the logperiodic pattern before crashes. European Physics Journal B, 9, pp. 355–9.Google Scholar
Zhou, W.-X. and Sornette, D. (2008). Analysis of the real estate market in Las Vegas: bubble, seasonal patterns, and prediction of the CSW indexes. Physica A, 387, pp. 243–60.Google Scholar