Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-28T08:07:02.542Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Free banking and bank entry in nineteenth-century New York

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 October 2008

Howard Bodenhorn
Affiliation:
Clemson University and [email protected]

Abstract

Previous studies of entry under New York's free banking law of 1838 have generated conflicting results. This article shows that different measures of entry lead to different conclusions about the competitive effects of the law. Measured by the entry of new banks, New York's free banking law led to increased rates of entry relative to other states. Free banking did not, however, lead to significant increases in capital accumulation in the industry. This paradoxical outcome resulted from the regulatory features of free banking, especially the bond security feature, which reduced profitability and incentives to invest in banking.

Résumés

Des études précédentes conduites selon la loi bancaire libre de New York de 1838 ont produit des résultats contradictoires. Cette communication montre que des mesures différentes d'entrée mènent à des conclusions différentes sur les effets compétitifs de la loi. Mesurée par l'entrée de nouvelles banques, la loi bancaire libre de New York a entraîné des taux élevés d'entrée par rapport aux autres états. Cependant, les opérations bancaires libres n'ont pas entraîné d'augmentation importante dans l'accumulation de capital dans l'industrie. Ce résultat paradoxal provient des caractéristiques réglementaires des opérations bancaires libres, en particulier la fonction de sécurité du titre, qui a réduit la profitabilité et les d'incitations à l'investissement dans le secteur bancaire.

Abstrakte

Bisherige Studien zum Eintritt von Banken in das Banksystem unter der New Yorker Freibankgesetzgebung von 1838 haben widersprüchliche Ergebnisse hervor gebracht. Dieser Artikel zeigt, dass die unterschiedlichen Maßstäbe, die für den Eintritt in den Markt angelegt werden, zu unterschiedlichen Schlussfolgerungen über die Wirksamkeit der Gesetzgebung führen. Wenn man die Anzahl der Bankneuzugänge betrachtet, so bewirkte die New Yorker Freibankgesetzgebung – im Vergleich zu anderen Staaten – erhöhte Bankeintrittsraten. Die Freibankgesetzgebung führte jedoch nicht zu einer signifikanten Erhöhung der Kapitalakkumulation in der Branche. Dieses paradoxe Ergebnis entstand infolge der regulatorischen Elemente des Freibankwesens – insbesondere des Elements der Bürgschaftswechsel, die die Rentabilität und die Anreize einer Investition in das Bankwesen senkten.

Resúmenes

Estudios previos sobre la entrada de la ley de la banca libre en Nueva York en 1838 han generado resultados contradictorios. Este artículo muestra que las diferentes medidas de entrada nos llevan a diferentes conclusiones sobre los efectos competitivos de la ley. Medidos por la entrada de nuevos bancos, la ley de la banca libre en Nueva York, provocó un aumento de las tasas de entrada con relación a otros estados. Sin embargo, la banca libre no llevó a un aumento importante de la acumulación de capital en la industria. Este resultado paradójico se produjo a causa de las características reguladoras de la banca libre, especialmente la seguridad de los bonos, la cual redujo los beneficios y los incentivos para invertir en la banca.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 I thank Mike Bordo, Hugh Rockoff, David Weiman, Eugene White and two anonymous referees for many helpful comments and suggestions. Pam Bodenhorn provided invaluable research assistance. This article was thoroughly revised while visiting Yale University in 2006–7 and I would like to thank Tim Guinnane and the economics department for their generosity and the many courtesies extended during the year. All remaining errors in fact and interpretation are, of course, my own.

2 Hammond, J., The History of Political Parties in the State of New York, 3 vols. (Syracuse, NY, 1852)Google Scholar; Hammond, B., Banks and Politics in America from the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton, 1957)Google Scholar; Benson, L., The Concept of Jacksonian Democracy: New York as a Test Case (Princeton, 1961)Google Scholar; Miller, N., The Enterprise of a Free People: Aspects of Economic Development in New York during the Canal Period Ithaca, NY, 1962)Google Scholar; Rockoff, H., The Free Banking Era: a Reexamination (New York, 1975)Google Scholar.

3 Rockoff, H., ‘The free banking era: a reexamination’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 6 (1974), pp. 141–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar; King, R., ‘The economics of private money’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12 (1983), pp. 127–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rolnick, A. and Weber, W., ‘The causes of free bank failures: a detailed examination’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 14 (1984), pp. 267–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

4 Hammond, Banks and Politics, p. 572.

5 Ng, K., ‘Free banking and barriers to entry in banking, 1838–1860’, Journal of Economic History, 48 (1988), pp. 877–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Bodenhorn, H., ‘The business cycle and entry into early American banking markets’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 75 (1993), pp. 531–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Economopoulos, A. and O'Neill, H., ‘Bank entry during the antebellum era’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 27 (1995), pp. 1071–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 It should be kept in mind throughout that a direct entry restriction represented just one of many margins across which states could influence entry. Usury laws, reserve and capital requirements and a host of other regulations could be tightened or relaxed to induce or deter entry. Although it was not the only regulatory innovation introduced in the period, free banking was the most significant change. Maximum legal interest rates, for example, changed little in the late antebellum era, though usury penalties generally declined. New York, on the other hand, increased the usury ceiling from 6 to 7 per cent in 1837, but increased penalties for violations. For macroeconomic analyses of nineteenth-century usury laws see H. Rockoff, ‘Prodigals and projectors: an economic history of usury laws in the United States from colonial times to 1900’, NBER working paper 9742 (2003) and E. Benmelech and T. J. Moskowitz, ‘The political economy of financial regulation: evidence from US state usury laws in the 19th century’, NBER working paper 12851 (2007). For a microeconomic analysis of New York's usury law see Bodenhorn, H., ‘Usury ceilings and bank lending behavior: evidence from nineteenth-century New York’, Explorations in Economic History, 42 (2007), pp. 179202CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 Economopoulos and O'Neill, ‘Bank entry’, recognise this as well.

10 Rockoff, ‘Reexamination’, p. 150.

11 Redlich, F., The Molding of American Banking: Men and Ideas (New York, 1968)Google Scholar; Bodenhorn, H., ‘Bank chartering and political corruption in antebellum New York: free banking as reform’, in Glaeser, E. L. and Goldin, C. (eds.), Corruption and Reform: Lessons from America's Economic History (Chicago, 2006)Google Scholar.

12 Although Michigan adopted free banking a year before New York, Michigan is better viewed as follower than leader. Its 1837 law was modelled after a bill previously debated but rejected by the New York legislature.

13 Sylla, R., Legler, J. B. and Wallis, J. J., ‘Banks and state public finance in the new republic: the United States, 1790–1860’, Journal of Economic History, 47 (1987), pp. 391403CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wallis, J. J., Sylla, R. and Legler, J. B., ‘The interaction of taxation and regulation in nineteenth-century US banking’, in Goldin, C. and Libecap, G. D. (eds.), The Regulated Economy: a Historical Approach to Political Economy (Chicago, 1994), pp. 121–44Google Scholar.

14 Holdsworth, J. T., Financing an Empire: History of Banking in Pennsylvania (Chicago, 1928)Google Scholar.

15 T. Wang, ‘Courts, banks, and credit markets in early American development’, unpublished PhD thesis (Stanford University, 2006), ch. 2.

16 Rhode Island General Assembly, Report of the Committee Appointed by the General Assembly of the State of Rhode-Island and Providence Plantations, to Visit and Examine the Banks in this State (Providence, RI, 1836), p. 11.

17 Knox, J. J., A History of Banking in the United States (New York, 1903), p. 391Google Scholar.

18 Handlin, O. and Handlin, M. F., Commonwealth: a Study of the Role of Government in the American Economy: Massachusetts, 1774–1861 (Cambridge, 1947), p. 113Google Scholar argued that Massachusetts had a long-standing commitment to freedom of corporate association and Wallis, Sylla and Legler, ‘Interaction of taxation and regulation’, suggest that Massachusetts's liberal incorporation policy followed from its tax on bank capital. More banks and more bank capital implied more tax revenues.

19 Goldsmith, R. W., Financial Structure and Development (New Haven, CT, 1969)Google Scholar; Gurley, J. G. and Shaw, E. S., ‘Financial aspects of economic development’, American Economic Review, 45 (September 1955), pp. 515–38Google Scholar.

20 Barnard, D. D., Speeches and Reports of the Assembly of New-York at the Annual Session of 1838 (Albany, 1838), p. 166Google Scholar; Gurley, J. G. and Shaw, E. S., ‘Financial intermediaries and the saving–investment process’, Journal of Finance, 2 (May 1956), pp. 257–76Google Scholar. In their cross-country study of countries after 1960, Levine, R. and King, R., ‘Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (August 1993), pp. 717–37Google Scholar find somewhat higher money–income ratios. Fast-growing countries had average money–income ratios of 0.4; slow growers, 0.3 and very slow-growing countries, 0.2. It seems unlikely that nineteenth-century economies, even fast-growing ones, would have realised the measured level of monetisation seen in modern economies, due in part to the concurrent use of specie and bank money as currency. National estimates of the quantity of specie in circulation exist for the nineteenth century, but none at the state level.

21 The literature investigating the finance–growth nexus is voluminous, and generally finds that finance leads economic growth. See Levine, R., ‘Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda’, Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (1997), pp. 688726Google Scholar, for a concise discussion of the issues and a review of the early literature. For discussions of the finance–growth nexus in an historical context see Bodenhorn, History of Banking, ch. 2; and Rousseau, P. L. and Sylla, R., ‘Emerging financial markets and early US growth’, Explorations in Economic History, 42 (2005), pp. 126CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 New York State Legislature, Assembly, ‘Annual report of the bank commissioners’, Assembly Document No. 74 (January 1835).

23 Handlin and Handlin, Commonwealth.

24 See, for example, Report and Observations, on the Banks, and Other Incorporated Institutions, in the State of New-York (New York, 1828), p. 13.

25 Ibid., p. 20.

26 Quoted in Gouge, W. M., A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United States (Philadelphia, 1833), p. 79Google Scholar.

27 This Bank of America has no relationship with the modern Bank of America. The modern Bank of America is the progeny of Amadeo Giannini's Bank of Italy, which originated in San Francisco, California in 1904.

28 Cole, D. B., Martin Van Buren and the American Political System (Princeton, 1984), pp. 27–8Google Scholar.

29 See Bodenhorn, ‘Bank chartering and political corruption’, for a more complete description of Van Buren's harnessing of the banking sector to his faction's advantage.

30 See Chaddock, R. E., The Safety Fund System in New York, 1829–1866 (Washington, DC, 1910)Google Scholar; Calomiris, C. W., ‘Deposit insurance: lessons from the record’, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives, 13 (May/June 1989), pp. 1030Google Scholar; and Bodenhorn, State Banking in Early America: a New Economic History (New York and Oxford, 2003), ch. 7.

31 Report and Observations, p. 9.

32 New York General Assembly, ‘Annual report of the bank commissioners’, Assembly Document No. 78 (January 1837), pp. 6–7.

33 New York Senate, ‘Report of the select committee on the bill to repeal the laws restraining private banking’, Senate Document No. 42 (February 1838).

34 Friedman, M., A Program for Monetary Stability (New York, 1960)Google Scholar.

35 Diamond, D. W. and Dybvig, P. H., ‘Banking theory, deposit insurance, and bank regulation’, Journal of Business, 59.1 (January 1986), pp. 5568CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Smith, B. D., ‘Monetary policy, banking crises, and the Friedman rule’, American Economic Review, 92.2 (May 2002), pp. 128–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Cary, T. G., A Practical View of the Business of Banks (Boston, 1845)Google Scholar and Johnson, A. B., A Treatise on Banking (Utica, NY, 1850)Google Scholar. An exception is Lord, E., Capital, Currency and Banking, 2nd edition (New York, 1834), p. 84Google Scholar. He advocated a 100 per cent reserve system without the right of note issue.

37 See, for example, Barnard, Speeches.

38 Ibid., pp. 197–8.

39 Carey, H. C., Answers to the Questions: What Constitutes Currency?: What are the Causes of Unsteadiness of Currency?: and What is the Remedy? (Philadelphia, 1840), p. 62Google Scholar.

40 Tucker, G., Theory of Money and Banks Investigated (Boston, 1839), pp. 228–9Google Scholar.

41 For a review of the literature see, Cagan, P. and Schwartz, A. J., ‘The national bank note puzzle reinterpreted’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 23 (August 1991), pp. 293307CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 Bodenhorn, H. and Haupert, M., ‘Was there a note issue conundrum in the free banking era’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 27 (1995), pp. 702–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar; idem., ‘The note issue paradox in the free banking era’, Journal of Economic History, 56 (1996), pp. 687–93.

43 Albany Evening Journal (3 January 1837). That William L. Marcy, Democratic governor and one-time Bucktail power broker and originator of the phrase, ‘to the victors go the spoils’, would utter such a sentiment reveals the extent to which Jacksonianism, generally, and the free banking impulse, specifically, had changed 1830s New York political rhetoric.

44 New York Senate, ‘Report of the select committee consisting of one senator from each senate district, on sundry petitions for the passage of a law creating a general system of private banking’, Senate Document No. 55 (March 1837), p. 2.

45 Gunn, L. R., The Decline of Authority: Public Economic Policy and Political Development in New York State, 1800–1860 (Ithaca, NY, 1988), p. 229Google Scholar.

46 See, for example, Economopoulos and O'Neill, ‘Bank entry’.

47 Sedgwick, T., What is a Monopoly? Or Some Considerations Upon the Subject of Corporations and Currency by a Citizen of New York (New York, 1835), pp. 1213Google Scholar.

48 Schwartz, A. J., ‘The beginning of competitive banking in Philadelphia, 1782–1809’, Journal of Political Economy, 55 (1947), pp. 417–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

49 Gouge, W., A Short History of Paper Money and Banking in the United States (Philadelphia, 1833), pp. 117–19Google Scholar.

50 Willson, M., A Treatise on Civil Polity and Political Economy (New York, 1838), p. 275Google Scholar.

51 Albany Evening Journal, 8 Feb. 1837.

52 Pennsylvania House of Representatives, ‘Report of the committee on banks’, House Report No. 126 (1832/3).

53 Massachusetts Senate, ‘Report of the joint standing committee on banks and banking’, Senate Report No. 85 (March 1853).

54 Ibid., p. 11.

55 A more complete empirical specification would include supply-side factors, such as local returns to capital and observable costs important to entrepreneurs. I have not been able to identify any such variables at a sufficiently low level of aggregation to include them here. Parameter estimates will suffer from omitted variable bias, relative to a complete specification. They, nevertheless, remain useful in that they account for most of the variables of concern to legislators in granting charters.

56 The entry data are gathered from a number of sources, including Fentermaker, J. V., The Development of American Commercial Banking: 1782–1837 (Kent, OH, 1965)Google Scholar and individual chartering Acts. See notes to Figure 1 for details.

57 I use the change in per capita bank capital rather than the percentage change because many counties in which a bank is opened begin with zero per capita bank capital. The resulting percentage change is infinitely large, which raises several estimation issues. In using the absolute of the change, which is sometimes negative, rather than the percentage change, OLS remains a viable technique. Moreover, contemporaries were seemingly more concerned with the absolute scale of financial operations rather than its growth rate.

58 Sokoloff, K., ‘Inventive activity in early industrial America: evidence from the patent records, 1790–1846’, Journal of Economic History, 48 (1988), pp. 813–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar. I include canals rather than navigable bodies of water because canals purposely altered the commercial landscape after their completion in the 1820s.

59 The coefficients reported from a Poisson or negative binomial regression are interpreted as the difference in the natural log of the expected counts (dependent variable) due to a one unit change in the independent variable of interest, holding all others constant. Formally, this may written as β = ln(μ|x + 1) − ln(μ|x), where μ is the expected count and x is the relevant independent variable. Recall that the difference of two logs can be rewritten as the logarithm of the ratio, or β = ln[ (μ|x + 1) / (μ|x)]. The reported incidence rate ratio is then exp(β) = (μ|x + 1) / (μ|x). If exp(β) = 2, for example, the incidence rate ratio can be interpreted as a one unit increase in the independent variable increases the incidence rate of the dependent variable by a factor of 2.

60 See Hammond, Banks and Politics; Redlich, Molding of American Banking; Bodenhorn, State Banking; Sylla, Legler and Wallis, ‘Banks and state public finance’; and Wallis, Sylla and Legler, ‘Interaction of taxation and regulation’.

61 New York, ‘Report of the New York State bank commissioners for 1840’, reprinted in Raguet, Condy, A Treatise on Currency and Banking, 2nd edition (Philadelphia, 1840), pp. 312–13Google Scholar.

62 Bodenhorn and Haupert, ‘Conundrum’ and ‘Note issue paradox’.

63 Cary, Practical View, p. 8.

64 Johnson, Treatise on Banking.

65 Johnson ignores capital gains, but assumed that the hypothetical bank paid out all its current net profits as current dividends.

66 Bodenhorn, H., ‘Usury ceilings and bank lending behavior: evidence from nineteenth-century New York’, Explorations in Economic History, 44 (2007), pp. 179202CrossRefGoogle Scholar, shows that at least one bank selectively violated the usury law. Nevertheless, most loans were made at or below the legal ceiling rate.

67 In 1856, the ratio of circulation to circulation plus deposits was about 0.10 among New York City banks; 0.40 at banks in five cities of 25,000 or more inhabitants (Albany, Brooklyn, Buffalo, Rochester and Troy); and about 0.55 in banks in smaller cities and towns. Author's calculation from information reported in New York State Banking Department, Annual Report of the Superintendent of the Banking Department of the State of New York, Transmitted to the Legislature, January 7, 1857 (Albany, 1857).

68 Author's calculations from data reported in Johnson, Treatise, p. 10.

69 Sylla, R., The American Capital Market, 1846–1914: a Study of the Effects of Public Policy on Economic Development (New York, 1975)Google Scholar; Lamoreaux, N., Insider Lending: Banks, Personal Connections, and Economic Development in Industrial New England (New York, 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lamoreaux, N. and Glaisek, C., ‘Vehicles of privilege or mobility? Banks in Providence, Rhode Island, during the age of Jackson’, Business History Review, 65 (1991), pp. 502–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

70 Green, G. D., Finance and Economic Development in the Old South: Louisiana Banking, 1804–1861 (Stanford, CA, 1972)Google Scholar.