Article contents
Capture or agreement? Why Spanish banking was regulated under the Franco regime, 1939–751
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 12 September 2008
Abstract
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History 1999
References
2 Gowland, D., The Regulation of Financial Markets in the 1990s (Worcester, 1990)Google Scholar, or Balternsperger, E. and Dermine, J., ‘Banking deregulation in Europe’, Economic Policy, 4 (1987).Google Scholar
3 Dowd, K., Laissez-faire Banking (London/New York, 1993), p. 303.Google Scholar
4 In markets with imperfect information, when the public doubts a bank's solvency, many raise their estimate of the probability that other banks will also fail. As Balternsperger explains, runs occur because a cooperative solution among depositors cannot be enforced. Collectively, depositors have no incentive to run but, individually, each will try to be the first to collect deposits at their full value. See Balternsperger, E., ‘The economic theory of banking regulation’, in Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (eds), The Economics and Law of Banking Regulation (Saarbrücken, 1990), p. 5.Google Scholar
5 This idea of ‘regulatory capture’ is associated especially with Downs, A., An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York, 1957)Google Scholar; and Stigler, G. J., ‘A theory of oligopoly’, Journal of Political Economy, 72 (1964)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and idem, ‘The economic theory of regulation’, Bell Journal of Economics, 2 (1971).Google Scholar
6 Peltzman, S., ‘Toward a more general theory of regulation’, Journal of Law and Economics, 19 (1976), p. 213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7 Sáez de Ibarra, L., La regulación de la banca en España (Consejo Superior Bancario, Madrid, 1954)Google Scholar; or Eguilaz, H. Paris, ‘El problema de la reforma bancaria en Espa˜a’, Anales de Economía, 26 (1947).Google Scholar
8 de Ibarra, Sáaez, La regulation de la banca, p. 23.Google Scholar
9 This institution's main function was to advise the Minister of Finance. The President of the Supreme Banking Council was Director of the General Directorate of Banks and Stock Exchanges and the Vice-President was the Deputy Governor of the Bank of Spain. It comprised one representative of each public bank, ten for the private banks and two for the Sindicato Nacional de Banca γ Bolsa.
10 Bank of Spain Archives [hereafter BoS]: Actas del Banco de España (Secretaría), 1947, file 2785.
11 Lukauskas affirms that the decision to close the banking sector to new entities was politically motivated. The Franco government restricted competition, believing it a necessary condition to assure political stability: Lukauskas, A., The political economy of financial deregulation: the case of Spain, dissertation (University of Pennsylvania, 1992), pp. 177–8.Google Scholar
12 Alhadeff, D. A., Competition and Controls in Banking, a Study of the Regulation of Bank Competition in Italy, France and England (Los Angeles, 1968), p. 189.Google Scholar
13 Ibid. pp. 189–90; or Collins, M., Money and Banking in the UK: A History (London, 1990), p. 111.Google Scholar
14 ibid., p. 448.
15 There is no agreement about the existence of scale economies in the banking sector, and when the scale diseconomies appear. See Revel, J., Mergers and the Role of Large Banks (Institute of European Finance, Research Monographs in Banking and Finance, 2, 1985)Google Scholar; or Lawrence, C., ‘Banking costs: generalized functional forms and estimations of economies of scale and scope’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 21 (1989).Google Scholar
16 In 1965, Banco Central and Banco Hispanoamericano tried to merge, but the Finance Ministry opposed it and in fact fixed a tax to be paid on the merger that was confiscatory. See Ruiz, J. L. García and Tortella, G., Divergent, parallel and convergent trajectories: the history of the Hispanoamericano and the Banco Central, 1901–1965, paper presented to Colloquium of the European Association for Banking History (Zurich, 1993), p. 30.Google Scholar
17 Ministry of Finance, Memorandum del Ministerio de Hacienda sobre el Sistema Bancario γ Creditido e Informes sobre el mismo de los siguientes organismos: Banco de España, Consejo Superior Bancario, Organización Sindical, Instituto de Estndios Políticos, Cámaras de Comercio, Industrie γ Navcgación, CECA γ Consejo de Economía National (1961).
18 Report of the Chambers of Commerce (1961), p. 4Google Scholar; and Report of the Supreme Banking Council (1961), p. 29.Google Scholar
19 Report of the Trade Unions (1961), p. 5Google Scholar; and Report of the Institute of Political Studies (1961), p. 8.Google Scholar
20 Report of the Chambers of Commerce (1961), p. 4Google Scholar; and Report of the Supreme Banking Council (1961), p. 23.Google Scholar
21 Report of the Bank of Spain (1961), p. 14.Google Scholar
22 Report of the Central Committee of Syndicates (1961), p. 5Google Scholar; and Report of the Institute of Political Studies (1961), p. 7.Google Scholar
23 The poor results of this initiative meant that the distinction between the two types of banks was abolished in 1974.
24 The Economist (12 May 1962), p. 586.Google Scholar
25 BoS: Informe sobre el Proγecto de Ley de Ordenación Bancaria de. 1946, p. 14.Google Scholar The Supreme Banking Council donated their own archives to the Bank of Spain in 1996; unfortunately, they have not been catalogued.
26 The Bank of Spain only allows consultation of private information up to 1956.
27 New banks faced other difficulties as legal barriers of more than 20 years had given existing banks substantial advantages in terms of customer loyalty.
28 We can speak about a ‘good’ result because bank failures impose serious costs on depositors and shareholders.
29 From 1940 to 1970 there were 109 mergers; most occurred between 1940 and 1950: 52 mergers 1940–50, 38 1950–60 and 19 during the last part of the period.
30 Clayton, G., ‘Spain’, in Sayers, R. S. (ed.), Banking in Western Europe (Oxford, 1962), p. 358.Google Scholar
31 Risky and bad banking practices were not the only cause of the banking crisis. Other variables, such as the oil crisis or the links between banks and industry, must also be taken into account. However, these were reinforced by the lack of prudence on the part of certain bank directors. See Cuervo, A., ‘Banca, industria y crisis bancarias’, Economía Industrial, 272 (1990), p. 66.Google Scholar
32 BoS: Informe del Consejo Superior Bancario sobre el Proγecto de Leγ de Ordenación Bancaria de 1946, pp. 8–9Google Scholar; and Infonne del Banco de Vizcaya sobre el Proyecto de Leγ de Ordenación Bancaria de 1946.
33 BoS: Informe del Consejo Superior Bancario sobre el Proγecto de Leγ de Ordenación Bancaria de 1946, p. 8.Google Scholar
34 The Superior Banking Council was used as an intermediary between the Bank of Spain and private banks. See Olariaga, L., ‘La liquidabilidad de los bancos de depósitos españoles’, Moneda γ Crédito, 38 (1951), pp. 17–18.Google Scholar
35 For example, Supreme Banking Council Circular 509 (22 Dec. 1953) indicates that the Bank of Spain conceded some economic advantages to all private banks which had 35 per cent of total deposits invested in public bonds.
36 Arrate, J. Prados, El sistema bancario español (Madrid, 1958), p. 97.Google Scholar
37 In Oct. 1938 the nationalist authorities froze deposits taken by financial institutions after 18 Jul. 1938. For earlier deposit accounts, the authorities froze the increase after 18 Jul. 1938. After the Civil War, the Franco government estimated that the purchasing powers of the nationalist and the republican pesetas was different and used a percentage conversion scale or ‘table of equivalence’ between both coins. See BoS: Report D–6402/03, 1938.
38 Sardá, J., El Banco Ae España, 1930–62. Una Historia Económica (Madrid, 1968), p. 449.Google Scholar
39 BoS: Report D-6824, 1941.
40 Fernández, V., ‘La deuda pública’, in Datos básicos para la Historia financiera de España (IEF, 1975), pp. 678–9.Google Scholar
41 HMSO, Overseas Economic Surveys for Spain (London, 1956), p. 88.Google Scholar
42 BoS: Report, D-6421, 1946.
43 ibid., p. 6.
44 Bank of England Archives [hereafter BoE]: OV61/4, 12 Mar. 1951, p. 4.Google Scholar
45 González, M. J., La economía política del franquismo (1940–70) (Madrid, 1979), p. 45.Google Scholar
46 BoS: Report, 0–6421, 1946.
47 Eguilaz, Paris, ‘El problema de la reforma bancaria’, pp. 188–90.Google Scholar
48 Velarde, J., ‘Banca e industrialización: la etapa autarquica (1939–59)’, in Mañas, A. Torrero (ed.)/Banco Español de Credito, Banca e Industria en España: presente, pasade y futuro (Madrid, 1988), p. 58.Google Scholar
49 HMSO, Overseas Economic Survey for Spain (London, 1956), p. 5.Google Scholar
50 HMSO, Overseas Economic Survey for Spain (London, 1951), p. 17.Google Scholar
51 Anadon, R. Poveda, ‘Funcionamiento del mercado financiero español’, Papeles de Economía, 9 (1981), p. 43Google Scholar; or Rojo, L. A., ‘La política monetaria’, in Qintana, E. Fuentes (ed.), El desarrollo económico de España (Madrid, 1963), p. 98.Google Scholar
52 Collins, , Money and Banking, p. 329.Google Scholar
53 Eguilaz, Paris, ‘El problema de la reforma bancaria’, pp. 186–7.Google Scholar
54 HMSO, Overseas Economic Survey for Spain (London, 1948), pp. 15–16.Google Scholar
55 HMSO, Overseas Economic Survey for Spain (London, 1951), p. 17.Google Scholar
56 BoE:OV/61/8, 1963, pp. 4–6.
57 Eguilaz, Paris, ‘El problema de la reforma bancaria’, p. 43.Google Scholar
58 ibid., pp. 222–3.
59 ibid., p. 197.
60 BoS: Informe del Consejo Superior Bancario sobre el Proyecto de Ley de Ordenación Bancaria de 1946, p. 7.Google Scholar
61 Supreme Banking Council, Circular 431 (1 Dec. 1952).
62 In addition to these general agreements among private banks to fix interest rates, some banks concluded pacts. For example, in 1944 Banco Urquijo and Banco Hispanoamericano signed the Pacto de Jarillas to collaborate in their activities. Similarly, Banco de Valencia, Banco Central, Banco Hispano Colonial and Crédito Zaragozano created Bancor, a banking association. Unfortunately, texts of these agreements were never published and it is very difficult to evaluate their real influence.
63 In part, this is the reason why the Franco authorities introduced other complementary credit controls to guarantee banking funds to some sectors.
64 García, and Tortella, , Divergent, parallel and convergent trajectories, p. 21.Google Scholar
65 Eguilaz, Paris, ‘El problema de la reforma bancaria’, pp. 196–7.Google Scholar
66 HMSO, Overseas Economic Surveys for Spain (London, 1956), p. 77.Google Scholar
67 Roura, J. R. Cuadrado, ‘Financiación privilegiada al sector privado y desequilibrios regionales’, Informatión Comercial Española, 526–7 (1977), p. 120.Google Scholar
68 González, La economía política.
69 ibid., p. 321.
70 In non-democratic regimes, the authorities have only an incentive to supply particularistic benefits – those benefiting those groups supporting the regime.
71 Pi-Sunyer, C. Viver, El personal político de Franco (1936–1945). Contribución empírica a una teoría del régimen franquista (Barcelona, 1978).Google Scholar
72 ibid., pp. 266–7.
73 Lukauskus, , Political economy of financial deregulation, p. 138.Google Scholar
74 The Law of Protection and Development of National Industry (24 Oct. 1939), and the Law of Regulation and Defence of National Industry (24 Nov. 1939).
75 BoS: Informe del Consejo Superior Bancario sobre el Proyecto de Ley de Ordenación Bancaria de 1946, p. 14.Google Scholar
76 Following Lukauskus, the limit on dividends was politically and economically motivated. First, it was a concession to an important group in the regime, the Falangists, who were pressuring Franco to limit the dominant position of banks and to control profits. Second, it was an indirect mechanism to encourage banks to invest their profits. See Lukauskus, , Political economy of financial deregulation, p. 180.Google Scholar
77 As García and Tortella indicate, ‘many Falangists concurred wholeheartedly, seeing the banks as bulwarks of “international capitalism” and thinking that the regime had gone soft on “plutocrats” and forgotten the “social revolution”, a vague concept that figured prominently in the Falange's programme and that the regime had supposedly embraced': García and Tortella, Divergent, parallel and convergent trajectories, p. 29. That is why many Falangists agreed with the nationalisation of the Spanish banking sector.
78 ibid., pp. 29–30.
79 Roman, E. San, El nacimiento de la SEAT (Fundación Empresa Pública. Documento de Trabajo, 1995), p. 88.Google Scholar
80 Arriba (to May 1950).
81 BoE: OV61/4, 16 May 1945, p. 1.
82 Unfortunately, with this reform, the scope of discretion was enlarged. The Law was very ambiguous; on one hand, it remarked on the lack of financing of small- and medium-sized firms and the bad performance of the market. On the other, the authorities declared as national interest the capital goods, exports and shipbuilding sectors, where firms had the biggest average size.
83 Fontana, J. and Nadal, J., ‘España’, in Cipolla, C. M. (ed.), Historia de Europa, 6 (Barcelona, 1980), p. 146.Google Scholar
84 BoS: Report 0–1191, Informe del Comité Económico sobre la Ejecución del Plan de Estabilización del Gobierno Español, 1960, section 8.
85 BoE: OV61, 21 Nov. 1962, p. 1.
86 Lukauskas, , Political economy of financial deregulation, p. 515.Google Scholar
87 Muñoz, J., El poder de la banca en España (Madrid, 1969)Google Scholar; or Braña, J., Buesa, M. and Molero, J., El Estado y el cambio tecnológico en la industrialización tardía (Madrid, 1984).Google Scholar
88 ibid., p. 170.
89 García, and Tortella, , Divergent, parallel and convergent trajectories, pp. 22–7.Google Scholar
- 11
- Cited by