Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T01:25:03.506Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Esposito's temporality of finance: Endogeneity and revisability in derivative transactions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

Conor Husbands*
Affiliation:
Independent scholar, UK
*
Corresponding author: Conor Husbands, 4C Breakspears Road, Lewisham, London SE4 1UW, UK. Email: [email protected].
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Recent years have seen greater interest in the theoretical foundations of abstract finance and their intersection with questions of philosophy and sociology. In particular, exchanges between authors such as Donald MacKenzie, Timothy Johnson, Elie Ayache, and others have debated the deterministic or contingent dynamics of markets, as well as their interdependency with the theories that purport to describe them. Working in this tradition, Elena Esposito raises a novel question in her 2011 book, The Future of Futures: could the exchange of derivative securities within financial markets entail not so much the provision of liquidity, but the transaction of time? In this article, I reconstruct Esposito's analysis, arguing that the proper response to this question should be affirmative. Particular emphasis is laid on what I take to be the two fundamental and controversial premises which support this argument: first, the endogeneity of time-relations involved in financial markets; and second, the revisability of these time- relations. The advantage of recasting Esposito's position in this way is the defence it enables against various criticisms articulated in theory and philosophy circles, such as those of Ray Brassier. Finally, I discuss the significance of Esposito's theory, not only for this class of financial transactions, but also for certain issues in the philosophy of time.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-No Derivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits noncommercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© 2020 The Author(s)

References

Alexander, H. (1956) The Leibniz-Clarke Correspondence. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Ayache, E. (2010) The Blank Swan: The End of Probability. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Ayache, E. (2015) The Medium of Contingency: An Inverse View of the Market. Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayache, E. (2016) Response to Johnson: A random sample versus the radical event. Finance and Society, 2(2): 205–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckert, J. (2014) Capitalist dynamics: Fictional expectations and the openness of the future. MPIfG Discussion Papers, 14(7): 118.Google Scholar
Brassier, R. (2011) Ray Brassier interviewed by Marcin Rychter: I am a nihilist because I still believe in truth. Kronos, 16(1): n.p.Google Scholar
Brassier, R. (2017) Pricing time: Outline and discussion on Suhail Malik's ‘The ontology of finance’. Identities, 14(1): 84128.Google Scholar
Ennis, P. (2010) Continental Realism. Winchester: Zero Books.Google Scholar
Esposito, E. (2011) The Future of Futures: The Time of Money in Financing and Society, translated by Esposito, E.. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, C. and Ossandón, J. (2013) Book review: The Future of Futures: The Time of Money in Financing in Society. Organization Studies, 34(2): 277–79.Google Scholar
Galison, P. (2003) Einstein's Clocks, Poincaré’s Maps: Empires of Time. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Gratton, P. (2014) Speculative Realism: Problems and Prospects. London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
Hull, J. (2002) Options, Futures and Other Derivatives, 5th edition. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Johnson, T. (2016) The necessity of multi-disciplinary scholarship for finance: On Ayache and Roffe. Finance and Society, 2(2): 189204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knorr Cetina, K. and Bruegger, U. (2002) Global microstructures: The virtual societies of financial markets. American Journal of Sociology, 107(4): 905–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, N. (1981) Temporalstrukturen des Handlungssystems. In: Soziologische Aufklärung 3: Soziales System, Gesellschaft, Organisation. Opladen: Westdeutsche Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, N. (1991) Risk: A Sociological Theory, translated by R. Barrett. Berlin: De Gruyter.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. (2006) An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malik, S. (2014) The ontology of finance: Price, power, and the Arkhéderivative. Collapse: Philosophical Research and Development, 8: 629812.Google Scholar
Meillassoux, Q. (2008) After Finitude: An Essay on the Necessity of Contingency, translated by Brassier, R.. London: Continuum.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitzan, J. and Bichler, S. (2009) Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roffe, J. (2015) Abstract Market Theory. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, B. (1913) Mysticism and Logic and Other Essays. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Soros, G. (1987) The Alchemy of Finance: Reading the Mind of the Market. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar