Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-24T02:57:16.123Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Self-confidence and strategic behavior

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Gary Charness*
Affiliation:
University of California at Santa Barbara, Santa Barbara, CA, USA
Aldo Rustichini*
Affiliation:
University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, USA
Jeroen van de Ven*
Affiliation:
University of Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam, The Netherlands

Abstract

We suggest that overconfidence (conscious or unconscious) is motivated in part by strategic considerations, and test this experimentally. We find compelling supporting evidence in the behavior of participants who send and respond to others’ statements of confidence about how well they have scored on an IQ test. In two-player tournaments where the higher score wins, a player is very likely to choose to compete when he knows that his own stated confidence is higher than the other player’s, but rarely when the reverse is true. Consistent with this behavior, stated confidence is inflated by males when deterrence is strategically optimal and is instead deflated (by males and females) when luring (encouraging entry) is strategically optimal. This behavior is consistent with the equilibrium of the corresponding signaling game. Overconfident statements are used in environments that seem familiar, and we present evidence that suggests that this can occur on an unconscious level.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9526-3) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Barber, BM, & Odean, T (2001). Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 261292. 10.1162/003355301556400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumeister, RF Gilbert, D, Fiske, S, & Lindzey, G (1998). The self. The handbook of social psychology, Boston: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Benoit, Jean-Pierre, & Dubra, Juan (2011). Apparent overconfidence. Econometrica, 79(5), 15911625. 10.3982/ECTA8583Google Scholar
Berglas, S, & Jones, E (1978). Drug choice as a self-handicapping strategy in response to noncontingent success. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36, 405417. 10.1037/0022-3514.36.4.405CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Burks, S, Carpenter, J, Goette, L, & Rustichini, A (2009). Cognitive abilities explain economic preferences, strategic behavior and job performance. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106(19), 77457750. 10.1073/pnas.0812360106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burks, S, Carpenter, J, Goette, L, & Rustichini, A (2013). Overconfidence and social signaling. The Review of Economic Studies, 80(3), 949983. 10.1093/restud/rds046CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C, & Lovallo, D (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 89, 306318. 10.1257/aer.89.1.306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Gneezy, U (2010). Portfolio choices and risk attitudes. Economic Inquiry, 48, 133146. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00219.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Gneezy, U (2012). Strong evidence for gender differences in risk-taking. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 83, 5058. 10.1016/j.jebo.2011.06.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., Rustichini, A., & van de Ven, J. (2013). Self-Confidence and Strategic Behavior, CESifo Working paper no. 4517.Google Scholar
Clark, J., & Friesen, L. (2009). Overconfidence in forecasts of own performance: An experimental study. Economic Journal, 119(354), 229251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Compte, O, & Postlewaite, A (2004). Confidence-enhanced performance. American Economic Review, 94(5), 15361557. 10.1257/0002828043052204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V, & Iriberri, N (2007). Level-k auctions: Can boundedly rational strategic thinking explain the winner’s curse and overbidding in private-value auctions. Econometrica, 75, 17211770. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2007.00810.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V., & Sobel, J (1982). Strategic information transmission. Econometrica, 50(6), 14311451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunning, D, Meyerowitz, JA, & Holzberg, AD (1989). Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57(6), 10821090. 10.1037/0022-3514.57.6.1082CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ewers, M. (2012). Information and competition entry. IZA discussion paper, 6411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ewers, M., & Zimmerman, F. (2015). Image and misreporting. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13(2), 363380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, Niederle, M, & Rustichini, A (2003). Performance in competitive environments: Gender differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(3), 10491074. 10.1162/00335530360698496CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, & Rustichini, A (2004). Gender and competition at a young age. American Economic Review, 94(2), 377381. 10.1257/0002828041301821CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurdal, M., Miller, J., & Rustichini, A. (2013). Why Blame?. Journal of Political Economy, 121(6), 12051247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heger, S., & Papageorge, N. (2015). We should totally open a restaurant: How optimism and overconfidence affect beliefs. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Hoelzl, E, & Rustichini, A (2005). Overconfident: Do you put your money on it?. Economic Journal, 115(503), 305318. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.00990.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jehiel, P (2005). Analogy-based expectation equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 123(2), 81104. 10.1016/j.jet.2003.12.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kartik, N (2009). Strategic communication with lying costs. Review of Economic Studies, 76, 13591395. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00559.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolditz, TA, & Arkin, RM (1982). An impression management interpretation of the self-handicapping strategy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 43, 492502. 10.1037/0022-3514.43.3.492CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koszegi, B (2006). Ego utility, overconfidence, and task choice. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(4), 673707. 10.1162/JEEA.2006.4.4.673CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruger, J (1999). Lake Wobegon be gone! The below-average effect and the egocentric nature of comparative ability judgements. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77(2), 221232. 10.1037/0022-3514.77.2.221CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leary, M. (1999). The social and psychological importance of self-esteem. In Kowalski, R. M. Leary, M. R. (Eds.), The social psychology of emotional and behavioral problems: Interfaces of social and clinical psychology (pp. 197222).Google Scholar
Leary, MR, Tambor, S Terdal, & Downs, D (1995). Self-esteem as an interpersonal monitor. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 68, 518530. 10.1037/0022-3514.68.3.518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludwig, S., & Thoma, C. (2012). Do women have more shame than men: An Experiment. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Lundeberg, M, Fox, P, & Puncochar, J (1994). Highly confident but wrong: Gender differences and similarities in confidence judgments. Journal of Educational Psychology, 86(1), 114121. 10.1037/0022-0663.86.1.114CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, D, & Healy, PJ (2008). The trouble with overconfidence. Psychological Review, 115(2), 502517. 10.1037/0033-295X.115.2.502CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Myerson, R (1991). Game theory: Analysis of conflict, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Niederle, M, & Vesterlund, L (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 10671101. 10.1162/qjec.122.3.1067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M, & Schrag, J (1999). First impressions matter: A model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 3782. 10.1162/003355399555945CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raven, JC (2000). Ravens advanced progressive matrices (APM), Upper Saddle River: Pearson.Google Scholar
Samuelson, L (2001). Analogies, adaptation, and anomalies. Journal of Economic Theory, 97(2), 320366. 10.1006/jeth.2000.2754CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shipman, C, & Kay, K (2009). Womenomics, New York: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Svenson, O (1981). Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers?. Acta Psychologica, 47, 143148. 10.1016/0001-6918(81)90005-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, R (1985). Social evolution, Menlo Park, CA: Benjamin Cummings.Google Scholar
Van den Steen, E (2004). Rational overoptimism (and other biases). American Economic Review, 94(4), 11411151. 10.1257/0002828042002697CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vialle, I., Santos-Pinto, L., & Rullière, J. L. (2011). Self-confidence and teamwork: An experimental test. Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weinstein, ND (1980). Unrealistic optimism about future life events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39(5), 806820. 10.1037/0022-3514.39.5.806CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zábojník, J (2004). A model of rational bias in self-assessments. Economic Theory, 23(2), 259282. 10.1007/s00199-003-0382-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Charness et al. supplementary material

Appendix A-E
Download Charness et al. supplementary material(File)
File 584.3 KB