Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-6tpvb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-23T00:45:34.250Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Public goods provision, inequality and taxes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Neslihan Uler*
Affiliation:
Research Center for Group Dynamics, Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, USA

Abstract

The impact of redistributive policies on voluntary contributions is still not well understood. While a higher level of redistributive taxation decreases the price of voluntary giving, it also changes the income distribution by decreasing income inequality. This paper provides a controlled laboratory experiment to investigate the net impact of the tax rate on public goods provision. The experimental findings show that while the participants decrease their voluntary contributions as the pre-tax income distribution becomes more equal, they increase their contributions with taxation. These findings have important implications for government policies regarding privately provided public goods.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2010 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am grateful to Andrew Schotter, Debraj Ray and Guillaume Frechette for their constant support throughout the project. I thank Jacob Goeree and two anonymous referees for their extensive and helpful comments. I also thank Marina Agranov, Abigail Brown, Mark Dean, Pinar Derin, Basak Gunes, Kyle Hyndman, Silvana Krasteva, Kai-Uwe Kuhn, Yusufcan Masatlioglu, Doug Smith, Ariel Rubinstein and Chloe Tergiman for helpful comments. This research was supported by the C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics and the Center for Experimental Social Science at New York University.

References

Alm, J., & Jacobson, S. (2007). Using laboratory experiments in public economics. Natl. Tax J., LX(1), 129152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J.M., & Milyo, J. (2004). Inequality and public good provision: an experimental analysis. Working Paper. College of William and Mary.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. J. Polit. Econ., 97(6), 14471458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving. Econ. J., 100, 464477.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (2006). Philanthrophy. In Kolm, S.-C. & Ythier, J. M. (Eds.), Handbook of giving, reciprocity and altruism (pp. 12011269). Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Bergstrom, T. (1996). Do government subsidies increase the private supply of public goods. In Public choice, Vol. 88(3-4) (pp. 295308). New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Q. J. Econ., 116(1), 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auten, G. E., Sieg, H., & Clotfelter, C. T. (2002). Charitable giving, income and taxes: an analysis of panel data. Am. Econ. Rev., 92(1), 371382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S., (1981). Altruism in the family and selfishness in the market place. Economica, 48(189), 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. J. Public Econ., 29, 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A., (2000). A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. Am. Econ. Rev., 90, 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckley, E., & Croson, R. (2006). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the voluntary provision of linear public goods. J. Public Econ., 90, 935955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1996). The voluntary provision of public goods under varying income distributions. Can. J. Econ., 29(1), 5469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1999). Heterogeneity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Exp. Econ., 2(1), 530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. F. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. Am. Econ. Rev., 92(4), 12181221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clotfelter, C. T. (1985). Federal tax policy and charitable giving. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clotfelter, C. T. (1990). The Impact of Tax Reform on Charitable Giving: A 1989 Perspective. In Slemrod, J. (Ed.), Do taxes matter (pp. 203235). Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (2000). Pareto-improving redistribution and pure public goods. Ger Econ. Rev., 1(2), 169186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. D., Millner, E. L., & Reilly, R. J. (2005). Subsidy schemes and charitable contributions: a closer look. Exp. Econ., 8, 85106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. D., & Millner, E. L. (2005). Rebates and matches and consumer behavior. South. Econ. J., 72, 410421.Google Scholar
Derin, P., & Uler, N. (2007). Inequality aversion and public goods provision. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Easterly, W., & Rebelo, S. (1993a). Fiscal policy and economic growth: an empirical investigation. J. Monet. Econ., 32, 417458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W., & Rebelo, S. (1993b). Marginal income tax rates and economic growth in developing countries. Eur. Econ. Rev., 37, 409417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2003). Rebate versus matching: does how we subsidize charitable contributions matter? J. Public Econ., 87(3-4), 681701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2006a). Do donors care about subsidy type? An experimental study. In Davis, D. & Isaac, M. (Eds.), Research in experimental economics, Vol. 11. Experiments investigating fundraising and charitable contributions (pp. 163182). New York: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2006b). Subsidizing charitable giving with rebates or matching: further laboratory evidence. South. Econ. J., 72(4), 794807.Google Scholar
Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). Subsidizing charitable contributions: a natural field experiment comparing matching and rebate subsidies. Exp. Econ., 11, 234252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Milano, A. (2007). Is more information always better? An experimental study of charitable giving and Hurricane Katrina. South. Econ. J., 74(2), 388411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erkal, N., Gangadharan, L., & Nikiforakis, N. (2010). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. Working Paper. University of Melbourne.Google Scholar
Falkinger, J. (1996). Efficient private provision of public goods by rewarding deviations from average. J. Public Econ., 62, 413422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falkinger, J., Fehr, E., Gaechter, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2000). A simple mechanism for the efficient provision of public Goods: experimental evidence. Am. Econ. Rev., 90(1), 247264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Q. J. Econ., 114(3), 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Rev. Econ. Stud., 60, 3552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., & Smith, V. (1994). Preference, property rights and anonymity in bargaining games. Games Econ. Behav., 7, 346380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1988). Group size effects in public good provision: the voluntary contributions mechanism. Q. J. Econ., 103(1), 179199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Itaya, J., Meza, D., & Myles, G. D. (1997). In praise of inequality: public good provision and income distribution. Econ. Lett., 57, 289296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlan, D., & List, J. A. (2007). Does price matter in charitable giving? Evidence from a large-scale natural field experiment. Am. Econ. Rev., 97(5), 17741793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konow, J. (2000). Fair shares: accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions. Am. Econ. Rev., 90(4), 10721091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ledyard, J. (1995). Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In Roth, & Kagel, (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nalbantian, H., & Schotter, A. (1997). Productivity under group incentives: an experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev., 87(3), 314341.Google Scholar
Noussair, C., Plott, C., & Riezman, R. (1995). An experimental investigation of the patterns of international trade. Am. Econ. Rev., 85(3), 462491.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olszewski, W., & Rosenthal, H. (2004). Politically determined income inequality and the provision of public goods. J. Public Econ. Theory, 6(5), 707735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oxoby, R. J., & Spraggon, J. (2008). Mine and yours: Property rights in dictator games. J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 65, 703713.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peloza, J., & Steel, P. (2005). The price elasticities of charitable contributions: a meta analysis. J. Public Policy Mark., 24(2), 260272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randolph, W. (1995). Dynamic income, progressive taxes, and the timing of charitable contributions. J. Polit. Econ., 103(4), 709738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A., & Suleiman, R. (1993). Incremental contribution in step-level public goods games with asymmetric players. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., 55, 171194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, D., & Ueda, K. (1996). Egalitarianism and incentives. J. Econ. Theory, 71(2), 324348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey-Biel, P., Sheremeta, R., & Uler, N. (2010). Rewarding effort and/or luck: a cross-cultural study. Working paper.Google Scholar
Saint Paul, G., & Verdier, T. (1996). Inequality, redistribution and growth: a challenge to the conventional political economy approach. Eur. Econ. Rev., 40, 719728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sala-i-Martin, X. (1996). Transfers, social safety nets, and economic growth, IMF Working Paper No. 96/40. Available at SSRN. http://ssrn.com/abstract=882940.Google Scholar
Uler, N. (2009). Public goods provision and redistributive taxation. J. Public Econ., 93(3-4), 440453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warr, P. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Econ. Lett., 13, 207211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vesterlund, L. (2006). Why do people give. In Steinberg, R. & Powell, W. W. (Eds.), The nonprofit sector, (2nd edn.). New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar