Hostname: page-component-669899f699-ggqkh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-04-24T14:55:03.267Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Position uncertainty in a sequential public goods game: an experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Chowdhury Mohammad Sakib Anwar*
Affiliation:
Business School, Faculty of Business and Digital Technology, University of Winchester, Winchester SO22 4NR, UK
Konstantinos Georgalos*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Lancaster University Management School, Lancaster LA1 4YX, UK

Abstract

Gallice and Monzón (Econ J 129(621):2137–2154, 2019) present present a natural environment that sustains full co-operation in one-shot social dilemmas among a finite number of self-interested agents. They demonstrate that in a sequential public goods game, where agents lack knowledge of their position in the sequence but can observe some predecessors’ actions, full contribution emerges in equilibrium due to agents’ incentive to induce potential successors to follow suit. In this study, we aim to test the theoretical predictions of this model through an economic experiment. We conducted three treatments, varying the amount of information about past actions that a subject can observe, as well as their positional awareness. Through rigorous structural econometric analysis, we found that approximately 25% of the subjects behaved in line with the theoretical predictions. However, we also observed the presence of alternative behavioural types among the remaining subjects. The majority were classified as conditional co-operators, showing a willingness to cooperate based on others’ actions. Some subjects exhibited altruistic tendencies, while only a small minority engaged in free-riding behaviour.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2024

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Anderson, J, Burks, SV, Carpenter, J, Götte, L, Maurer, M, & Nosenzo, D et al. . (2013). Self-selection and variations in the laboratory measurement of other-regarding preferences across subject pools: Evidence from one college student and two adult samples. Experimental Economics, 16, 170189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, Brown, PM, & Vesterlund, L. (2002). What makes an allocation fair? Some experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 40, 1, 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansink, E, Koetse, M, Bouma, J, Hauck, D, & van Soest, D. (2022). Crowdfunding conservation (and other public goods). Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 9, 3, 565602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Athey, S, & Ellison, G. (2014). Dynamics of open source movements. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 23, 2, 294316.Google Scholar
Au, WT, & Ngai, MY. (2003). Effects of group size uncertainty and protocol of play in a common pool resource dilemma. Group Processes & Intergroup Relations, 6, 3, 265283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azrieli, Y, Chambers, CP, & Healy, PJ. (2018). Incentives in experiments: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 126, 4, 14721503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azrieli, Y, Chambers, CP, & Healy, PJ. (2020). Incentives in experiments with objective lotteries. Experimental Economics, 23, 1, 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N. (2000). Control without deception: Individual behaviour in free-riding experiments revisited. Experimental Economics, 3, 215240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N, & Moffatt, PG. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: Inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62, 1, 161193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellemare, C, & Kröger, S. (2007). On representative social capital. European Economic Review, 51, 1, 183202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belot, M, Duch, R, & Miller, L. (2015). A comprehensive comparison of students and non-students in classic experimental games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 113, 2633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhattacharya, R, Devinney, TM, & Pillutla, MM. (1998). A formal model of trust based on outcomes. The Academy of Management Review, 23, 3, 459472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bianchi, E, & Brockner, J. (2012). The influence of dispositional trust on perceptions of procedural and interactional fairness. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 118, 4659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bigoni, M, Casari, M, Skrzypacz, A, & Spagnolo, G. (2015). Time horizon and cooperation in continuous time. Econometrica, 83, 2, 587616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bland, JR. (2020). Heterogeneous trembles and model selection in the strategy frequency estimation method. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 6, 113124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Charness, G. (2000). Hot vs. cold: Sequential responses in simple experimental games. Experimental Economics, 2, 227238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Charness, G. (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14, 375398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breitmoser, Y. (2015). Cooperation, but no reciprocity: Individual strategies in the repeated prisoner's dilemma. American Economic Review, 105, 9, 28822910.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budescu, D, Suleiman, R, & Rapoport, A. (1995). Positional order and group size effects in resources dilemmas with uncertain resources. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 61, 3, 225238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budescu, DV, & Au, WT. (2002). A model of sequential effects in common pool resource dilemmas. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 1, 3763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J, & Seki, E. (2011). Do social preferences increase productivity? Field experimental evidence from fishermen in toyama bay. Economic Inquiry, 49, 2, 612630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartwright, E, & Patel, A. (2010). Imitation and the incentive to contribute early in a sequential public good game. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12, 4, 691708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, DL, Schonger, M, & Wickens, C. (2016). otree-an open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9, 8897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coats, JC, Gronberg, TJ, & Grosskopf, B. (2009). Simultaneous versus sequential public good provision and the role of refunds-an experimental study. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 1–2, 326335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, P, & Fréchette, GR. (2019). Strategy choice in the infinitely repeated prisoner's dilemma. American Economic Review, 109, 11, 39293952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, P, & Fréchette, GR. (2011). The evolution of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: Experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 101, 1, 411–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R. (1980). Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 169193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drichoutis, AC, Lusk, JL, & Nayga, RM Jr. (2015). The veil of experimental currency units in second price auctions. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 182196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Wilson, RK. (2004). Is trust a risky decision?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55, 4, 447465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emonds, G, Declerck, CH, Boone, C, Seurinck, R, & Achten, R. (2014). Establishing cooperation in a mixed-motive social dilemma. An fmri study investigating the role of social value orientation and dispositional trust. Social Neuroscience, 9, 1, 1022.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erev, I, & Rapoport, A. (1990). Provision of step-level public goods: The sequential contribution mechanism. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34, 3, 401425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Exadaktylos, F, Espín, AM, & Brañas-Garza, P. (2013). Experimental subjects are not different. Scientific Reports, 3, 1213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fetchenhauer, D, & Dunning, D. (2009). Do people trust too much or too little?. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30, 3, 263276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figuieres, C, Masclet, D, & Willinger, M. (2012). Vanishing leadership and declining reciprocity in a sequential contribution experiment. Economic Inquiry, 50, 3, 567584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U, & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100, 1, 541–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U, Gächter, S, & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71, 3, 397404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fréchette, GR, & Yuksel, S. (2017). Infinitely repeated games in the laboratory: Four perspectives on discounting and random termination. Experimental Economics, 20, 2, 279308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D, Rand, DG, & Dreber, A. (2012). Slow to anger and fast to forgive: Cooperation in an uncertain world. American Economic Review, 102, 2, 720–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S, Herrmann, B, & Thöni, C. (2004). Trust, voluntary cooperation, and socio-economic background: Survey and experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55, 4, 505531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S, Nosenzo, D, Renner, E, & Sefton, M. (2010). Sequential vs. simultaneous contributions to public goods: Experimental evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 7–8, 515522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallice, A, & Monzón, I. (2019). Co-operation in social dilemmas through position uncertainty. Economic Journal, 129, 621, 21372154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, E, Laibson, D, Scheinkman, J, & Soutter, C. (2000). Measuring trust. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 811846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with orsee. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 1, 114125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guzmán, R, Harrison, R, Abarca, N, & Villena, MG. (2020). A game-theoretic model of reciprocity and trust that incorporates personality traits. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 84, 101497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S, Nosenzo, D, Renner, E, & Sefton, M. (2012). Who makes a good leader? Cooperativeness, optimism, and leading-by-example. Economic Inquiry, 50, 4, 953967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W, Levati, V, Sutter, M, & van der Heijden, E. (2007). Leading by example with and without exclusion power in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 10231042.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hancock, PA, Kessler, TT, Kaplan, AD, Stowers, K, Brill, JC, Billings, DR, Schaefer, KE, & Szalma, JL. (2023). How and why humans trust: A meta-analysis and elaborated model. Frontiers in Psychology, 14, 1081086.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann, B, & Thöni, C. (2009). Measuring conditional cooperation: A replication study in Russia. Experimental Economics, 12, 1, 8792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hudik, M, & Chovanculiak, R. (2018). Private provision of public goods via crowdfunding. Journal of Institutional Economics, 14, 1, 2344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katuščák, P, & Miklánek, T. (2023). What drives conditional cooperation in public good games?. Experimental Economics, 26, 2, 435467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keser, C, Kliemt, H. Charness, G, & Pingle, M (2021). The strategy method as an instrument for the exploration of limited rationality in oligopoly game behavior (strategiemethode zur erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen verhaltens im rahmen eines oligopolexperimentes). The Art of Experimental Economics: Twenty Top Papers Reviewed, 1Routledge 3037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keser, C, & van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102, 1, 2339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocher, MG, Cherry, T, Kroll, S, Netzer, RJ, & Sutter, M. (2008). Conditional cooperation on three continents. Economics Letters, 101, 3, 175178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, DM, & Wilson, R. (1982). Sequential equilibria. Econometrica, 50, 4, 863894.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, J, & Tirole, J. (2002). Some simple economics of open source. Journal of Industrial Economics, 50, 2, 197234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levati, MV, Sutter, M, & Van der Heijden, E. (2007). Leading by example in a public goods experiment with heterogeneity and incomplete information. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51, 5, 793818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinsson, P, Pham-Khanh, N, & Villegas-Palacio, C. (2013). Conditional cooperation and disclosure in developing countries. Journal of Economic Psychology, 34, 148155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moxnes, E, & Van der Heijden, E. (2003). The effect of leadership in a public bad experiment. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47, 6, 773795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, J, Sefton, M, & Vesterlund, L. (2005). After you-endogenous sequencing in voluntary contribution games. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 8, 13991419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, J, Sefton, M, & Vesterlund, L. (2007). Leading-by-example and signaling in voluntary contribution games: An experimental study. Economic Theory, 33, 1, 169182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Préget, R, Nguyen-Van, P, & Willinger, M. (2016). Who are the voluntary leaders? Experimental evidence from a sequential contribution game. Theory and Decision, 81, 4, 581599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A. (1997). Order of play in strategically equivalent games in extensive form. International Journal of Game Theory, 26, 1, 113136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A, & Boebel, RB. (1992). Mixed strategies in strictly competitive games: A further test of the minimax hypothesis. Games and Economic Behavior, 4, 2, 261283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A, Budescu, D, & Suleiman, R. (1993). Sequential requests from randomly distributed shared resources. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 37, 241265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A, Erev, I. Schulz, U, Albers, W, & Mueller, U (1994). Provision of step-level public goods: Effects of different information structures. Social Dilemmas and Cooperation, New YorkSpringer-Verlag 5573.Google Scholar
Romano, R, & Yildirim, H. (2001). Why charities announce donations: A positive perspective. Journal of Public Economics, 81, 3, 423447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotter, J. (1967). A new scale for the measurement of interpersonal trust. Journal of Personality, 35, 651665.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Selten, R. (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments, TübingenMohr 136168.Google Scholar
Stiver, A, Barroca, L, Minocha, S, Richards, M, & Roberts, D. (2015). Civic crowdfunding research: Challenges, opportunities, and future agenda. New Media & Society, 17, 2, 249271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suleiman, R, Budescu, DV, Rapoport, A. Schulz, U, Albers, W, & Mueller, U (1994). The position effect: The role of a player's serial position in a resource dilemma game. Social Dilemmas and Cooperation, New YorkSpringer-Verlag 5573.Google Scholar
Suleiman, R, Budescu, DV, & Rapoport, A. (2001). Provision of step-level public goods with uncertain provision threshold and continuous contribution. Group Decision and Negotiation, 10, 253274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suleiman, R, Rapoport, A, & Budescu, D. (1996). Fixed position and property rights in sequential resource dilemmas under uncertainty. Acta Psychologica, 93, 229245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutter, M, Rivas, MF. Van Lange, PAM, Rockenbach, B, & Yamagishi, T (2014). Leadership, reward and punishment in sequential public goods experiments. Reward and Punishment in Social Dilemmas, Oxford University Press 133157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teyssier, S. (2012). Inequity and risk aversion in sequential public good games. Public Choice, 151, 1, 91119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thöni, C, & Volk, S. (2018). Conditional cooperation: Review and refinement. Economics Letters, 171, 3740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tung, A. W. & Budescu, D. V. (2013). Sequential effects in give-some and take-some social dilemmas, Resolving social dilemmas, Psychology Press, pp. 8799.Google Scholar
Van Dijk, E., Wit, A., Wilke, H. & Budescu, D. V. (2004). What we know (and do not know) about the effects of uncertainty on behavior in social dilemmas, Contemporary psychological research on social dilemmas, pp. 315331.Google Scholar
Varian, HR. (1994). Sequential contributions to public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 2, 165186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vesterlund, L. (2003). The informational value of sequential fundraising. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 3–4, 627657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Von Krogh, G, Spaeth, S, & Lakhani, KR. (2003). Community, joining, and specialization in open source software innovation: A case study. Research Policy, 32, 7, 12171241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, L, Nian, T, & Cabral, L. (2020). What makes geeks tick? A study of stack overflow careers. Management Science, 66, 2, 587604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yamagishi, T. (1986). The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51, 110116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material

Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material 1
Download Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material(File)
File 9.5 MB
Supplementary material: File

Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material

Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material 2
Download Anwar and Georgalos supplementary material(File)
File 736.8 KB