Hostname: page-component-669899f699-tpknm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-04-26T01:55:47.314Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A mechanism requesting prices and quantities may increase the provision of heterogeneous public goods

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Federica Alberti
Affiliation:
Faculty of Business and Law, University of Portsmouth, Portsmouth, UK
César Mantilla*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Universidad del Rosario, Calle 12C # 4-69 Bogotá, Colombia

Abstract

We study the provision problem of an asymmetrically valued public project using a novel mechanism proposed by Van Essen and Walker (2017). Under this mechanism, each player simultaneously submits a price (either a contribution or a requested compensation) and a desired project quantity. In our context, two non-hosts interact with the project’s host, who gets harmed by provision. The minimum submitted quantity is provided if the contributions are sufficient to cover the building costs and the host’s requested compensation. We test the efficiency-enhancing effects of communication and find that, although it led to larger provided quantities, the probability of provision is unaffected, and the non-hosts kept most of the efficiency surplus. Moreover, the effect of communication disappears in settings where the host demands a larger compensation in equilibrium. The coding of chat logs reveals that veto threats are rare (1%), although the mechanism allows to do so. Reaching non-binding agreements and the host’s engagement with communication are positively correlated with the probability of provision.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

Footnotes

The data, code, and instructions can be found in the online repository https://osf.io/c6v4w/. The study was funded through the University of Portsmouth, Faculty of Business and Law Research Project Fund and the program “Inclusión productiva y social: programas y políticas para la promoción de una economía formal, código 60185, que conforma la Alianza EFI, bajo el Contrato de Recuperación Contingente No. FP44842-220-2018.” We gratefully acknowledge the research assistance provided by Steffanny Romero, Silvia Ortíz, Sofia Almeida, and Andrés Zambrano, as well as the comments received in the BEBES-Seminar. We are also very thankful with the Editors of the special issue and the anonymous reviewers for their comments.

A correction to this article is available online at https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-023-09807-9.

References

Agranov, M., & Tergiman, C. (2019). Communication in bargaining games with unanimity. Experimental Economics, 22(2), 350368. 10.1007/s10683-018-9571-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Rao, J. M. (2011). The power of asking: How communication affects selfishness, empathy, and altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7–8), 513520. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.12.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Varian, H. (1999). Preplay contracting in the prisoners’ dilemma. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 96(19), 1093310938 1:CAS:528:DyaK1MXmtFKjtrw%3D 10.1073/pnas.96.19.10933 1999PNAS...9610933ACrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Arkes, H. R., Kagel, J. H., & Mezhvinsky, D. (2017). Effects of a management-labor context and team play on ultimatum game outcomes. Southern Economic Journal, 83(4), 9931011. 10.1002/soej.12187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagnoli, M., & Lipman, B. L. (1989). Provision of public goods: Fully implementing the core through private contributions. The Review of Economic Studies, 56(4), 583601 1023839 10.2307/2297502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balliet, D. (2010). Communication and cooperation in social dilemmas: A meta-analytic review. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 54(1), 3957. 10.1177/0022002709352443CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, J. S., Plott, C. R., & Porter, D. P. (1988). An experimental analysis of unanimity in public goods provision mechanisms. The Review of Economic Studies, 55(2), 301322. 10.2307/2297583CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baranski, A. (2016). Voluntary contributions and collective redistribution. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 8(4), 149–73.Google Scholar
Baranski, A., & Kagel, J. H. (2015). Communication in legislative bargaining. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 5971. 10.1007/s40881-015-0011-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bochet, O., Page, T., & Putterman, L. (2006). Communication and punishment in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60(1), 1126. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.06.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E., Chatterjee, K., & McGinn, K. L. (2003). How communication links influence coalition bargaining: A laboratory investigation. Management Science, 49(5), 583598. 10.1287/mnsc.49.5.583.15148CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J., & Cooper, D. J. (2018). Truth be told: An experimental study of communication and centralization. Technical report.Google Scholar
Brandts, J., Cooper, D. J., Rott, C. Schram, A., & Ule, A. (2019). Communication in laboratory experiments. Handbook of research methods and applications in experimental economics, Edward Elgar Publishing 401418.Google Scholar
Buchholz, W., & Peters, W. (2007). Justifying the Lindahl solution as an outcome of fair cooperation. Public Choice, 133(1), 157169. 10.1007/s11127-007-9184-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1999). Heterogeneity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Experimental Economics, 2(1), 530. 10.1023/A:1009984414401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G. (2012). Communication in bargaining experiments. In The Oxford handbook of economic conflict resolution.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74(6), 15791601 2268410 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2010). Bare promises: An experiment. Economics Letters, 107(2), 281283. 10.1016/j.econlet.2010.02.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaudhuri, A. (2011). Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: A selective survey of the literature. Experimental Economics, 14(1), 4783 1132600 10.1007/s10683-010-9257-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, D. L., Schonger, M., & Wickens, C. (2016). oTree-an open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9, 8897. 10.1016/j.jbef.2015.12.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Y. (2002). A family of supermodular Nash mechanisms implementing Lindahl allocations. Economic Theory, 19(4), 773790 1906930 10.1007/s001990100174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Y., & Tang, F-F (1998). Learning and incentive-compatible mechanisms for public goods provision: An experimental study. Journal of Political Economy, 106(3), 633662. 10.1086/250024CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D. J., & Kagel, J. H. (2005). Are two heads better than one? team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95(3), 477509. 10.1257/0002828054201431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D. J., & Kagel, J. H. (2016). A failure to communicate: An experimental investigation of the effects of advice on strategic play. European Economic Review, 82, 2445. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.10.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1989). Communication in the battle of the sexes game: some experimental results. The RAND Journal of Economics, 568587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1992). Communication in coordination games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 739771. 10.2307/2118488CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(2), 286298 1613712 10.1006/jeth.1997.2359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dannenberg, A., Lange, A., & Sturm, B. (2014). Participation and commitment in voluntary coalitions to provide public goods. Economica, 81(322), 257275. 10.1111/ecca.12073CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dekel, S., & Fischer, S. (2017). Potential pareto public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 146, 8796. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2016.12.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J., & Rabin, M. (1996). Cheap talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103118. 10.1257/jep.10.3.103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, J., Isaac, R. M., Schatzberg, J. W., & Walker, J. M. (1995). Heterogeneous demand for public goods: Effects on the voluntary contribution mechanism. Public Choice, 85, 34. 10.1007/BF01048198CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gáfaro, M., & Mantilla, C. (2020). Land division: A lab-in-the-field bargaining experiment. Journal of Development Economics, 102525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallier, C., Kesternich, M., & Sturm, B. (2017). Voting for burden sharing rules in public goods games. Environmental and Resource Economics, 67(3), 535557. 10.1007/s10640-016-0022-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gangadharan, L., Nikiforakis, N., & Villeval, M. C. (2017). Normative conflict and the limits of self-governance in heterogeneous populations. European Economic Review, 100, 143156. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2017.07.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandjean, G., Mantovani, M., Mauleon, A., & Vannetelbosch, V. (2017). Communication structure and coalition-proofness-experimental evidence. European Economic Review, 94, 90102. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2017.02.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4 2015awse.book.....GCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B., Caravella, M., & Roth, A. E. (2014). Is avatar-to-avatar communication as effective as face-to-face communication? An ultimatum game experiment in first and second life. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 374382. 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.01.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Healy, P. J. (2006). Learning dynamics for mechanism design: An experimental comparison of public goods mechanisms. Journal of Economic Theory, 129(1), 114149 2239838 10.1016/j.jet.2005.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1988). Communication and free-riding behavior: The voluntary contribution mechanism. Economic Inquiry, 26(4), 585608. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01519.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. H. (2020). 7. Auctions: A survey of experimental research, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kagel, J. H., Sung, H., & Winter, E. (2010). Veto power in committees: An experimental study. Experimental Economics, 13(2), 167188. 10.1007/s10683-010-9234-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kesternich, M., Lange, A., & Sturm, B. (2018). On the performance of rule-based contribution schemes under endowment heterogeneity. Experimental Economics, 21(1), 180204. 10.1007/s10683-017-9535-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, T. (1993). A stable Nash mechanism implementing Lindahl allocations for quasi-linear environments. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 22(4), 359371 1221211 10.1016/0304-4068(93)90023-ECrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleindorfer, P. R., & Sertel, M. R. (1994). Auctioning the provision of an indivisible public good. Journal of Economic Theory, 64(1), 2034. 10.1006/jeth.1994.1052CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koukoumelis, A., Levati, M. V., & Weisser, J. (2012). Leading by words: A voluntary contribution experiment with one-way communication. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(2), 379390. 10.1016/j.jebo.2011.11.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunreuther, H., Kleindorfer, P., Knez, P. J., & Yaksick, R. (1987). A compensation mechanism for siting noxious facilities: Theory and experimental design. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 14(4), 371383. 10.1016/0095-0696(87)90027-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunreuther, H., & Kleindorfer, P. R. (1986). A sealed-bid auction mechanism for siting noxious facilities. The American Economic Review, 76(2), 295299.Google Scholar
Ledyard, O. (1995). Public goods: Some experimental results. Handbook of Experimental Economics, 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lescop, D. (2007). Optimal mechanisms for siting noxious facilities. Review of Economic Design, 10(4), 273284 2310078 10.1007/s10058-006-0018-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lundquist, T., Ellingsen, T., Gribbe, E., & Johannesson, M. (2009). The aversion to lying. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(1–2), 8192. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.02.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masuda, T., Okano, Y., & Saijo, T. (2014). The minimum approval mechanism implements the efficient public good allocation theoretically and experimentally. Games and Economic Behavior, 83, 7385 3151995 10.1016/j.geb.2013.10.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minehart, D., & Neeman, Z. (2002). Effective siting of waste treatment facilities. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(2), 303324. 10.1006/jeem.2000.1180CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orzen, H. (2008). Fundraising through competition: Evidence from the lab. Technical report, CeDEx Discussion Paper Series.Google Scholar
O’Sullivan, A. (1993). Voluntary auctions for noxious facilities: Incentives to participate and the efficiency of siting decisions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 25(1), S12S26. 10.1006/jeem.1993.1030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popper, F. J. (1983). LULUs: Locally unwanted land uses. Resources, 73.Google Scholar
Quah, E. T., & Yong, J. (2008). An assessment of four popular auction mechanisms in the siting of NIMBY facilities: Some experimental evidence. Applied Economics, 40(7), 841852. 10.1080/00036840600758509CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. (1985). Toward a focal point theory of bargaining. Game-Theoretic Models of Bargaining, 259, 265267.Google Scholar
Roth, A. E., & Roth, A. (1987). Bargaining phenomena and bargaining theory. Laboratory experimentation in economics: Six points of view, Cambridge University Press 1441. 10.1017/CBO9780511528316.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. Roth, A., & Kagel, J. (1995). Bargaining experiments. The handbook of experimental economics, Princeton University Press 253348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schively, C. (2007). Understanding the NIMBY and LULU phenomena: Reassessing our knowledge base and informing future research. Journal of Planning Literature, 21(3), 255266. 10.1177/0885412206295845CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, A., & Sopher, B. (2007). Advice and behavior in intergenerational ultimatum games: An experimental approach. Games and Economic Behavior, 58(2), 365393 2293263 10.1016/j.geb.2006.03.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1979). An experimental comparison of three public good decision mechanisms. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 81, 198251. 10.2307/3439960CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1980). Experiments with a decentralized mechanism for public good decisions. The American Economic Review, 70(4), 584599.Google Scholar
Tavoni, A., Dannenberg, A., Kallis, G., & Löschel, A. (2011). Inequality, communication, and the avoidance of disastrous climate change in a public goods game. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(29), 1182511829 1:CAS:528:DC%2BC3MXps1ektr4%3D 10.1073/pnas.1102493108 2011PNAS..10811825TCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Essen, M., Lazzati, N., & Walker, M. (2012). Out-of-equilibrium performance of three Lindahl mechanisms: Experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 74(1), 366381 2885385 10.1016/j.geb.2011.04.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Essen, M., & Walker, M. (2017). A simple market-like allocation mechanism for public goods. Games and Economic Behavior, 101, 619 3613372 10.1016/j.geb.2016.02.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Essen, M., & Walker, M. (2019). Are we there yet? mechanism design beyond equilibrium. In Social design (pp. 205215). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, M. (1981). A simple incentive compatible scheme for attaining Lindahl allocations. Econometrica, 49(1), 6571 604799 10.2307/1911126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Alberti and Mantilla supplementary material

Alberti and Mantilla supplementary material
Download Alberti and Mantilla supplementary material(File)
File 331.9 KB