Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-hpxsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-21T15:14:32.615Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Higher order risk attitudes and prevention under different timings of loss

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Takehito Masuda*
Affiliation:
Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University, Mihogaoka 6-1, Ibaraki, Osaka 567-0047, Japan
Eungik Lee
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Seoul National University, Gwanak-ro 1, Gwanak-gu Seoul, South Korea

Abstract

This paper provides experimental evidence of the role of higher order risk attitudes—especially prudence—in prevention behavior. Prudence, under an expected utility framework, increases (decreases) self-protection effort compared to the risk neutral level when the risk of losing part of an income exists in a future (the same) period. Motivated by these predictions that give the exact test on prudence, an experiment was designed where subjects go through higher order risk attitude elicitation and make a self-protection decision. In contrast to the expected utility theory, the observed efforts are less than the risk neutral level, regardless of the timing of loss. This violation of expected utility predictions can be explained by probability weighting.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9588-x) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Bleichrodt, H., & van Bruggen, P. (2018). Higher order risk preferences for gains and losses. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Cardella, E, & Kitchens, C (2017). The impact of award uncertainty on settlement negotiations. Experimental Economics, 20(2), 333367. 10.1007/s10683-016-9486-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courbage, C, Rey, B, & Treich, N (2013). Prevention and precaution. Handbook of insurance, New York, NY: Springer 185204. 10.1007/978-1-4614-0155-1_8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deck, C, & Schlesinger, H (2010). Exploring higher order risk effects. The Review of Economic Studies, 77(4), 14031420. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00605.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deck, C, & Schlesinger, H (2014). Consistency of higher order risk preferences. Econometrica, 82(5), 19131943. 10.3982/ECTA11396Google Scholar
Ebert, S, & Wiesen, D (2011). Testing for prudence and skewness seeking. Management Science, 57(7), 13341349. 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1354CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebert, S, & Wiesen, D (2014). Joint measurement of risk aversion, prudence, and temperance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 48(3), 231252. 10.1007/s11166-014-9193-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Grossman, PJ (2008). Men, women and risk aversion: Experimental evidence. Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, 1, 10611073. 10.1016/S1574-0722(07)00113-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eeckhoudt, L, & Gollier, C (2005). The impact of prudence on optimal prevention. Economic Theory, 26(4), 989994. 10.1007/s00199-004-0548-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eeckhoudt, L. R., Laeven, R. J., & Schlesinger, H. (2017). Risk apportionment: The dual story. arXiv preprint arXiv: 1712.02182.Google Scholar
Eeckhoudt, L, & Schlesinger, H (2006). Putting risk in its proper place. The American Economic Review, 96(1), 280289. 10.1257/000282806776157777CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollier, C (2004). The economics of risk and time, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gollier, C, Hammitt, JK, & Treich, N (2013). Risk and choice: A research saga. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47(2), 129145. 10.1007/s11166-013-9175-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollier, C, Jullien, B, & Treich, N (2000). Scientific progress and irreversibility: an economic interpretation of the ‘Precautionary Principle’. Journal of Public Economics, 75(2), 229253. 10.1016/S0047-2727(99)00052-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haering, A., Heinrich, T., & Mayrhofer, T. (2017). Exploring the consistency of higher-order risk preferences (No. 688). Ruhr Economic Papers.Google Scholar
Heinrich, T, & Mayrhofer, T (2018). Higher-order risk preferences in social settings. Experimental Economics, 21(2), 434445. 10.1007/s10683-017-9541-4CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kahneman, D, & Tversky, A (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263292. 10.2307/1914185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimball, MS (1990). Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 58(1), 5373. 10.2307/2938334CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocher, MG, Pahlke, J, & Trautmann, ST (2015). An experimental study of precautionary bidding. European Economic Review, 78, 2738. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.04.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krieger, M, & Mayrhofer, T (2017). Prudence and prevention: An economic laboratory experiment. Applied Economics Letters, 24(1), 1924. 10.1080/13504851.2016.1158909CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leland, HE (1968). Saving and uncertainty: The precautionary demand for saving. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82(3), 465473. 10.2307/1879518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menegatti, M (2009). Optimal prevention and prudence in a two-period model. Mathematical Social Sciences, 58(3), 393397. 10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2009.07.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noussair, CN, Trautmann, ST, & Van de Kuilen, G (2014). Higher order risk attitudes, demographics, and financial decisions. Review of Economic Studies, 81(1), 325355. 10.1093/restud/rdt032CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peter, R (2017). Optimal self-protection in two periods: On the role of endogenous saving. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 137, 1936. 10.1016/j.jebo.2017.01.017CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prelec, D (1998). The probability weighting function. Econometrica, 66(3), 497527. 10.2307/2998573CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, U, Starmer, C, & Sugden, R (2008). Third-generation prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(3), 203 10.1007/s11166-008-9040-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stott, HP (2006). Cumulative prospect theory’s functional menagerie. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 32(2), 101130. 10.1007/s11166-006-8289-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautmann, ST, & van de Kuilen, G (2018). Higher order risk attitudes: A review of experimental evidence. European Economic Review, 103, 108124. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2018.01.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A, & Kahneman, D (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297323. 10.1007/BF00122574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wakker, PP (2010). Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 10.1017/CBO9780511779329CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, L (2008). Prudence in bargaining: The effect of uncertainty on bargaining outcomes. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(1), 211231. 10.1016/j.geb.2006.11.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Masuda and Lee supplementary material

Online Appendix for: Higher order risk attitudes and prevention under different timings of loss
Download Masuda and Lee supplementary material(File)
File 1.2 MB