Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-22T22:08:59.132Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A general revealed preference test for quasilinear preferences: theory and experiments

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Marco Castillo*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station, USA Melbourne Institute, University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Australia IZA, Bonn, Germany
Mikhail Freer*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Essex, Wivenhoe Park, UK

Abstract

We provide a generalized revealed preference test for quasilinear preferences. The test applies to nonlinear budget sets and non-convex preferences as those found in taxation and nonlinear pricing contexts. We study the prevalence of quasilinear preferences in a laboratory real-effort task experiment with nonlinear wages. The experiment demonstrates the empirical relevance of our test. We find support for either convex (non-separable) preferences or quasilinear preferences but weak support for the hypothesis of both quasilinear and convex preferences.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2023.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Supplementary Information The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-023-09790-1.

References

Afriat, S. N. (1967). The construction of utility functions from expenditure data. International Economic Review, 8, 6777. 10.2307/2525382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Afriat, S. N. (1973). On a system of inequalities in demand analysis: An extension of the classical method. International Economic Review, 14, 460472. 10.2307/2525934CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allcott, H., & Taubinsky, D. (2015). Evaluating behaviorally motivated policy: Experimental evidence from the lightbulb market. American Economic Review, 105, 25012538. 10.1257/aer.20131564CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R., & Rehbeck, J. (2018). Assessing misspecification and aggregation for structured preferences.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to garp: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70, 737753. 10.1111/1468-0262.00302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Sprenger, C. (2012). Estimating time preferences from convex budgets. American Economic Review, 102, 3333–56 10.1257/aer.102.7.3333CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Augenblick, N., Niederle, M., & Sprenger, C. (2015). Working over time: Dynamic inconsistency in real effort tasks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130, 10671115. 10.1093/qje/qjv020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Augenblick, N., & Rabin, M. (2019). An experiment on time preference and misprediction in unpleasant tasks. Review of Economic Studies, 86, 941975. 10.1093/restud/rdy019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 10631093. 10.1086/260265CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T. C., & Cornes, R. C. (1983). Independence of allocative efficiency from distribution in the theory of public goods. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 51, 17531765. 10.2307/1912115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, D. J., & Calsamiglia, C. (2007). The nonparametric approach to applied welfare analysis. Economic Theory, 31, 183188. 10.1007/s00199-006-0087-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrera, M., Royer, H., Stehr, M., Sydnor, J., & Taubinsky, D. (2022). Who chooses commitment? Evidence and welfare implications. Review of Economic Studies, 89, 12051244. 10.1093/restud/rdab056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cesarini, D., Lindqvist, E., Notowidigdo, M. J., & Östling, R. (2017). The effect of wealth on individual and household labor supply: Evidence from Swedish lotteries. American Economic Review, 107, 3917–46 10.1257/aer.20151589CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, C. P., & Echenique, F. (2016). Revealed preference theory, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chambers, C. P., & Echenique, F. (2017). A characterization of combinatorial demand. Mathematics of Operations Research.Google Scholar
Chen, D. L., Schonger, M., & Wickens, C. (2016). otree—An open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherchye, L., De Rock, B., & Vermeulen, F. (2012). Married with children: A collective labor supply model with detailed time use and intrahousehold expenditure information. American Economic Review, 102, 33773405. 10.1257/aer.102.7.3377CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cherchye, L., Demuynck, T., & De Rock, B. (2015). Is utility transferable? A revealed preference analysis. Theoretical Economics, 10, 5165. 10.3982/TE1560CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherchye, L., Demuynck, T., De Rock, B., & Lanier, J. (2020). Are consumers rational? shifting the burden of proof. FEB Research Report Department of Economics.Google Scholar
Cherchye, L., Demuynck, T., De Rock, B., & Vermeulen, F. (2017). Household consumption when the marriage is stable. American Economic Review, 107, 1507–34 10.1257/aer.20151413CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, S., Fisman, R., Gale, D., & Kariv, S. (2007). Consistency and heterogeneity of individual behavior under uncertainty. American Economic Review, 97, 19211938. 10.1257/aer.97.5.1921CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deb, R., Kitamura, Y., Quah, J. K. H., & Stoye, J. (2018). Revealed price preference: theory and empirical analysis. arXiv preprint arXiv: 1801.02702.Google Scholar
Dembo, A. (2019). Rationality and error in individual choice data: a revealed preferences approach. Technical Report. Working paper.Google Scholar
Domencich, T. A., & McFadden, D. (1975). Urban travel demand-a behavioral analysis. Technical report.Google Scholar
Dziewulski, P. (2020). Just-noticeable difference as a behavioural foundation of the critical cost-efficiency index. Journal of Economic Theory, 188, 105071 10.1016/j.jet.2020.105071CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Echenique, F. (2014). Testing for separability is hard. arXiv preprint arXiv: 1401.4499 .Google Scholar
Fishburn, P. C. (1990). Utility theory and decision theory. Palgrave Macmillan UK.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R., Kariv, S., & Markovits, D. (2007). Individual preferences for giving. The American Economic Review, 97, 18581876. 10.1257/aer.97.5.1858CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forges, F., & Minelli, E. (2009). Afriat’s theorem for general budget sets. Journal of Economic Theory, 144, 135145. 10.1016/j.jet.2008.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giupponi, G. (2019). When income effects are large: Labor supply responses and the value of welfare transfers.Google Scholar
Golosov, M., Graber, M., Mogstad, M., & Novgorodsky, D. (2021). How Americans Respond to Idiosyncratic and Exogenous Changes in Household Wealth and Unearned Income. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical Report.Google Scholar
Green, J., & Laffont, J. J. (1977). Characterization of satisfactory mechanisms for the revelation of preferences for public goods. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 45, 427438. 10.2307/1911219CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houtman, M., & Maks, J. (1985). Determining all maximal data subsets consistent with revealed preference. Kwantitatieve methoden, 19, 89104.Google Scholar
Kleven, H. J. (2016). Bunching. Annual Review of Economics, 8, 435464. 10.1146/annurev-economics-080315-015234CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, V. (2009). Auction theory, Academic Press.Google Scholar
Matzkin, R. L. (1991). Axioms of revealed preference for nonlinear choice sets. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 59, 17791786. 10.2307/2938290CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, R. B. (1981). Optimal auction design. Mathematics of Operations Research, 6, 5873. 10.1287/moor.6.1.58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nocke, V., & Schutz, N. (2017). Quasi-linear integrability. Journal of Economic Theory, 169, 603628. 10.1016/j.jet.2017.03.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piaw, T. C., & Vohra, R. V. (2003). Afriat’s theorem and negative cycles. preprint.Google Scholar
Polisson, M. (2018). A lattice test for additive separability.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M., & Adams, A. (2015). For love or reward? characterising preferences for giving to parents in an experimental setting. The Economic Journal, 126, 24242445. 10.1111/ecoj.12248CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Richter, M. K. (1966). Revealed preference theory. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 34, 635645. 10.2307/1909773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochet, J. C. (1987). A necessary and sufficient condition for rationalizability in a quasi-linear context. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 16, 191200. 10.1016/0304-4068(87)90007-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockafellar, R. T. (1970). Convex analysis, Princeton University Press 10.1515/9781400873173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strack, P., & Taubinsky, D. (2021). Dynamic preference “reversals” and time inconsistency. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical Report.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toussaert, S. (2018). Eliciting temptation and self-control through menu choices: A lab experiment. Econometrica, 86, 859889. 10.3982/ECTA14172CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R. (1983). Nonparametric tests of models of investor behavior. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 18, 269278. 10.2307/2330718CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Castillo and Freer supplementary material

Castillo and Freer supplementary material
Download Castillo and Freer supplementary material(File)
File 145.7 KB