Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-nzzs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-23T02:22:35.762Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Effect of an audience in public goods provision

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Emel Filiz-Ozbay*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Maryland, 3114 Tydings Hall, 20742 College Park, MD, USA
Erkut Y. Ozbay*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Maryland, 3114 Tydings Hall, 20742 College Park, MD, USA

Abstract

This paper investigates a novel public goods game where contributions to the public goods require effort that is observable. When the players are observed, they exert more effort to contribute to the public goods, and free-riding diminishes significantly compared to the no observer case. These effects are absent when no effort is required in order to contribute to the public goods. Furthermore, in the presence of an audience, the contributions to the public goods do not diminish when the game is repeated in the effort-required environment. Being observed does not affect the performance of the players if there is no strategic aspect of the game, in other words, when they play a private goods game. These results indicate that an individual wants to avoid appearing lazy when her effort helps the society.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2013 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-013-9363-y) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37(3), 291304. 10.1016/0047-2727(88)90043-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 14471458. 10.1086/261662CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464477. 10.2307/2234133CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Bernheim, B. D. (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: a theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77(5), 16071636. 10.3982/ECTA7384Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Petrie, R. (2004). Public goods experiments without confidentiality: a glimpse into fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 16051623. 10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00040-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D., Bracha, A., & Meier, S. (2009). Doing good or doing well? Image motivation and monetary incentives in behaving prosocially. The American Economic Review, 99(1), 544555. 10.1257/aer.99.1.544CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazerman, M., Loewenstein, G., & Blount-White, S. (1992). Reversals of preference in allocation decisions: judging an alternative versus choosing among alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(2), 220240. 10.2307/2393222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, L., & Berkowitz, L. (1972). Social norms, feelings, and other factors affecting helping and altruism. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Benabou, R. J., & Tirole, J. (2006). Incentives and prosocial behavior. The American Economic Review, 96(5), 16521678. 10.1257/aer.96.5.1652CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. (1994). A theory of conformity. Journal of Political Economy, 102(5), 841877. 10.1086/261957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. D., & Serverinov, S. (2003). Bequests as signals: an explanation for the puzzle of equal division. Journal of Political Economy, 111(4), 733764. 10.1086/375383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M., & Gravel, N. (2004). Voluntary provision of a public good and individual morality. Journal of Public Economics, 88(3–4), 645666. 10.1016/S0047-2727(02)00178-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broucek, F. J. (1991). Shame and the Self, New York: The Guilford Press.Google Scholar
Carstensen, L. L., Isaacowitz, D. M., & Charles, S. T. (1999). Taking time seriously: A theory of socioemotional selectivity. American Psychologist, 54, 165181. 10.1037/0003-066X.54.3.165CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chaudhuri, A. (2011). Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: a selective survey of the literature. Experimental Economics, 14(1), 4783. 10.1007/s10683-010-9257-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T. L., Kroll, S., & Shogren, J. F. (2005). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57, 357365. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.11.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dana, J., Cain, D. M., & Dawes, R. M. (2006). What you don’t know won’t hurt: costly but quiet exit in a dictator game. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 1002, 193201. 10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Della Vigna, S., List, J. A., & Malmendier, U. (2012). Testing for altruism and social pressure in Charitable Giving. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1156. 10.1093/qje/qjr050CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ekstrom, M. (2012). Do watching eyes affect charitable giving? Evidence from a field experiment. Experimental Economics, 15(3), 530546. 10.1007/s10683-011-9312-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glazer, A., & Konrad, K. A. (1996). A signaling explanation for charity. The American Economic Review, 86(4), 10191028.Google Scholar
Grossman, Z. (2010). Self-signaling versus social-signaling in giving. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Harbaugh, W. T. (1998). The prestige motive for charitable transfers. The American Economic Review, 88(2), 277282.Google Scholar
Harbaugh, W. T. (1998). What do donations buy: a model of philanthropy based on prestige and warm glow. Journal of Public Economics, 67, 269284. 10.1016/S0047-2727(97)00062-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, H. (1990). A social exchange approach to voluntary contribution. The American Economic Review, 80, 11571167.Google Scholar
Liu, W., & Aaker, J. (2008). The happiness of giving: the time-ask effect. Journal of Consumer Research, 35, 543557. 10.1086/588699CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Thompson, L., & Bazerman, M. (1989). Social utility and decision making in interpersonal contexts. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57(3), 426441. 10.1037/0022-3514.57.3.426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Read, D., & Baumeister, R. (2003). Time and Decision: Economic and Psychological Perspectives on Intertemporal Choice, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Nathanson, D., & Lewis, H. B. (1987). The shame/pride axis. The Role of Shame in Symptom Formation, Hillsdale: Erlbaum.Google Scholar
Niederle, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 10671101. 10.1162/qjec.122.3.1067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rege, M. (2004). Social norms and private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 6(1), 6577. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2004.00157.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rege, M., & Telle, K. (2004). The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 16251644. 10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00021-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soetevent, A. R. (2005). Anonymity in giving in a natural context: a field experiment in 30 churches. Journal of Public Economics, 89(11–12), 23012323. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soetevent, A. R. (2011). Payment choice, image motivation and contributions to charity: evidence from a field experiment. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 3(1), 180205.Google Scholar
Stoop, J., Noussair, C., & van Soest, D. (2012). From the lab to the field: cooperation among fishermen. Journal of Political Economy, 120(6), 10271056. 10.1086/669253CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, R. (1984). Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contributions. Economic Journal, 94, 772782. 10.2307/2232294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, S. (2008). The power of shame and the rationality of trust. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Van Boven, L., & Gilovich, T. (2003). To do or to have: That is the question. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 85(6), 11931202. 10.1037/0022-3514.85.6.1193CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Vohs, K. D., Mead, N. L., & Goode, M. R. (2006). The psychological consequences of money. Science, 314, 11541156. 10.1126/science.1132491CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yao, D. (2006). Microsoft-designed school opens in Philadelphia, Associated Press Newswires, September. http://www.microsoft.com/presspass/presskits/sotf/default.mspx.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Filiz-Ozbay and Ozbay supplementary material

Filiz-Ozbay and Ozbay supplementary material
Download Filiz-Ozbay and Ozbay supplementary material(File)
File 101.4 KB