Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-22T05:44:05.291Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Re-matching, information and sequencing effects in posted offer markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Douglas Davis*
Affiliation:
Virginia Commonwealth University, Richmond, VA 23284-4000, USA
Oleg Korenok*
Affiliation:
Virginia Commonwealth University, Richmond, VA 23284-4000, USA
Robert Reilly*
Affiliation:
Virginia Commonwealth University, Richmond, VA 23284-4000, USA

Abstract

This paper evaluates the effects of some standard procedural variations on outcomes in posted offer oligopoly experiments. Variations studied include the presence or absence of market information, the use of re-matched or fixed seller pairs and alterations in the order of sequencing. Experimental results indicate that such variations can have first order effects on outcomes. For this reason, we recommend that results in oligopoly experiments be carefully interpreted in light of the procedures selected.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2008 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-008-9195-3) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Braumoeller, B. (2004). Hypothesis testing and multiplicative interaction terms. International Organization, 58, 807820.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T., & Datta, S. (2006). An experimental study of price dispersion in an optimal search model with advertising. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 639665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J., & Walker, M. (1998). Learning to play Cournot duopoly strategies. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 36, 141161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Datta, S., & Dechenaux, E. (2006). Price leadership and firm size asymmetry. An Experimental Analysis. Manuscript, University of Richmond.Google Scholar
Davis, D. (2007). Pure numbers effects, market power and tacit collusion in posted offer markets. Manuscript, Virginia Commonwealth University.Google Scholar
Davis, D. (2002). Strategic interactions, market information and mergers in differentiated product markets. An experimental investigation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20, 12771312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D., & Holt, C. (1994). Market power and mergers in laboratory markets with posted prices. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 467487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D., & Korenok, O. (2007, forthcoming). Posted-offer markets in near continuous time. An experimental investigation. Economic Inquiry.Google Scholar
Davis, D., Reilly, R., & Wilson, B. (2003). Cost structures and Nash play in repeated Cournot games. An experimental investigation. Experimental Economics, 6, 209226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D., & Wilson, B. (2007, forthcoming). Strategic buyers, horizontal mergers and synergies. An experimental investigation. International Journal of Industrial Organization.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deck, C., & Wilson, B. (2006, forthcoming). Experimental gasoline markets. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.Google Scholar
Deck, C., & Wilson, B. (2002). The effectiveness of low price matching in mitigating the competitive pressure in low friction electronic markets. Electronic Commerce Research, 2, 385398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolbear, F., Lave, L., Bowman, G., Lieberman, A., Prescott, E., Rueter, F., & Sherman, R. (1968). Collusion in oligopoly. An experiment on the effect of numbers and information. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82, 240259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Gneezy, U. (2000). Price competition and market concentration. An experimental study. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, C. (2006). How much collusion? A meta-analysis on oligopoly experiments. Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fonseca, M., Müller, W., & Normann, H. (2006). Endogenouos timing in duopoly. Experimental evidence. International Journal of Game Theory, 34, 443456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fouraker, L., & Siegel, S. (1963). Bargaining behavior. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Holt, C. (1985). An experimental test of the consistent conjectures hypothesis. American Economic Review, 75,314-325.Google Scholar
Huck, S., Müller, W., & Normann, H. (2001). Stackelberg beats cournot. On collusion and efficiency in experimental markets. The Economic Journal, 111, 749761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huck, S., Normann, H., & Oechssler, J. (2004). Two are few and four are many. Number effects in experimental oligopolies. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 53, 435446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huck, S., Normann, H., & Oechssler, J. (2000). Does information about competitors’ actions increase or decrease competition in experimental oligopoly markets? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 3957.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruse, J., Rassenti, S., Reynolds, S., & Smith, V. (1994). Bertrand-Edgeworth competition in experimental markets. Econometrica, 62, 343371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, C., & Phillips, O. (1997a). Mitigating the tragedy of the commons through cooperation. An experimental evaluation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 34, 148172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, C., & Phillips, O. (1997b). Information and cost asymmetry in experimental duopoly markets. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 290299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, S., Normann, H., & Snyder, C. (2001). Vertical foreclosure in experimental markets. RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 667685.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Normann, H. (2006). Vertical mergers, foreclosure and raising rivals’ costs—experimental evidence. Manuscript, Royal Holloway College.Google Scholar
Orzen, H. (2006). Counterintuititve number effects in experimental oligopolies. Manuscript, University of Nottingham.Google Scholar
Rice, W. (1989). Analyzing tables of statistical tests. Evolution, 43, 223225.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Snyder, C., Ruffle, B., & Normann, H. (2006, forthcoming). Do buyer-size discounts depend on the curvature of the surplus function? Experimental tests of bargaining models. RAND Journal of Economics.Google Scholar
Smith, V. (2003). Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. American Economic Review, 93, 465508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, A., & Smith, V. (1984). Cyclical double-auction markets with and without speculators. The Journal of Business, 57, 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, B. (1998). What collusion? Unilateral market power as a catalyst for countercyclical markups. Experimental Economics, 1(2), 133145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Davis et al. supplementary material

Appendix A1
Download Davis et al. supplementary material(File)
File 27.7 KB