Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9k27k Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-21T15:02:03.079Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Elicitation of expectations using Colonel Blotto

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Ronald Peeters*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand
Leonard Wolk*
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands

Abstract

We develop a mechanism based on the Colonel Blotto game to elicit (subjective) expectations in a group-based manner. In this game, two players allocate resources over possible future events. A fixed prize is awarded based on the amounts the players allocate to the realized event. We consider two payoff variations: under the proportional-prize rule, the award is split proportionally to the resources that players allocate to the realized event; under the winner-takes-all rule, the full award is given to the player who allocate the most resources to the realized event. When probabilities by which events realize are common knowledge to the players, both games are Bayesian–Nash incentive compatible in the sense that (expected) equilibrium allocations perfectly reflect the true realization probabilities. By means of a laboratory experiment, we find that in a setting where realization probabilities are common knowledge the game with the proportional-prize rule (Prop) elicits better distributions compared to both the winner-takes-all variation (Win) and a benchmark mechanism based on an individual-based proper scoring rule (Ind). Without common knowledge of realization probabilities Prop is at least as good as Ind, showing that it is possible to use a game to elicit expectations in a similar fashion to using a proper scoring rule.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9596-x) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

We thank Matt Embrey, Glenn Harrison, Georgia Kosmopoulou, Carlos Lamarche, Josh Miller, Paulo Somaini, Martin Strobel, Alexander Westkamp, the editor, two anonymous referees, and the audiences at the CEREC Workshop in Economics (Brussels, 2015), the Conference on Auctions, Competition, Regulation, and Public Policy (Lancaster, 2015), the Behavioral and Experimental Economics Symposium (Maastricht, 2015), the Experimental Finance Conference (Tucson, 2016; Heidelberg, 2018), the Australasian meeting of the Econometric Society (Auckland, 2018), VU Amsterdam as well as UMass-Lowell for very helpful comments and suggestions.

References

Ames, C (1984). Achievement attributions and self-instructions under competitive and individualistic goal structures. Journal of Educational Psychology, 76(3), 478487. 10.1037/0022-0663.76.3.478CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avrahami, J, & Kareev, Y (2009). Do the weak stand a chance? Distribution of resources in a competitive environment. Cognitive Science, 33, 940950. 10.1111/j.1551-6709.2009.01039.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avrahami, J, Kareev, Y, Todd, PM, & Silverman, B (2014). Allocation of resources in asymmetric competitions: How do the weak maintain a chance of winning?. Journal of Economic Psychology, 42, 161174. 10.1016/j.joep.2013.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baillon, A (2017). Bayesian markets to elicit private information. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 114(30), 79587962. 10.1073/pnas.1703486114CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Birgé, L (1986). On estimating a density using Hellinger distance and some other strange facts. Probability Theory and Related Fields, 71(2), 271291. 10.1007/BF00332312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brier, GW (1950). Verification of forecasts expressed in terms of probability. Monthly Weather Review, 78, 13. 10.1175/1520-0493(1950)078<0001:VOFEIT>2.0.CO;22.0.CO;2>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J, Holmes, J, & Matthews, PH (2008). Charity auctions: A field experiment. Economic Journal, 118(525), 92113. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02105.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvalho, A (2016). An overview of applications of proper scoring rules. Decision Analysis, 13(4), 223242. 10.1287/deca.2016.0337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, K-Y, & Plott, CR (2002). Information aggregation mechanisms: Concept, design and implementation for a sales forecasting problem, New York City: Mimeo, Inc..Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S, Kovenock, D, & Sheremeta, R (2013). An experimental investigation of Colonel Blotto games. Economic Theory, 52(3), 833886. 10.1007/s00199-011-0670-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowgill, B, Wolfers, J, & Zitzewitz, E (2009). Using prediction markets to track information flows: Evidence from Google, New York City: Mimeo, Inc..Google Scholar
Duffy, J, & Matros, A (2017). Stochastic asymmetric Blotto games: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 139, 88105. 10.1016/j.jebo.2017.05.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dreber, A, Pfeiffer, T, Almenberg, J, Isaksson, S, Wilson, B, Chen, Y, Nosek, BA, & Johannesson, M (2015). Using prediction markets to estimate the reproducibility of scientific research. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112(50), 1534315347. 10.1073/pnas.1516179112CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figlewski, S (1979). Subjective information and market efficiency in a betting market. Journal of Political Economy, 87(1), 7588. 10.1086/260740CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). zTree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, R, Nelson, F, Neumann, GR, & Wright, R (1992). Anatomy of an experimental political stock market. American Economic Review, 82(5), 11421161.Google Scholar
Friedman, L (1958). Game-theory models in the allocation of advertising expenditures. Operations Research, 6(5), 699709. 10.1287/opre.6.5.699CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillen, BJ, Plott, CR, & Shum, M (2017). A pari-mutuel-like mechanism for information aggregation: A field test inside Intel. Journal of Political Economy, 125(4), 10751099. 10.1086/692714CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, O (1950). The symmetric Blotto game. RAND RM-2242, Santa Monica: RAND Corporation.Google Scholar
Harrison, GW, Martinez-Correa, J, Swarthout, JT, & Ulm, ER (2017). Scoring rules for subjective probability distributions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 134, 430448. 10.1016/j.jebo.2016.12.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellinger, E (1909). Neue Begründung der Theorie quadratischer Formen von unendlichvielen Veränderlichen. Journal für die reine und angewandte Mathematik, 136, 210271. 10.1515/crll.1909.136.210CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kovenock, D., & Roberson, B. (2015). Generalizations of the General Lotto and Colonel Blotto games. Working paper.Google Scholar
Laslier, JF (2002). How two-party competition treats minorities. Review of Economic Design, 7(3), 297307. 10.1007/s100580200083CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niederle, M, & Vesterlund, L (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 10671101. 10.1162/qjec.122.3.1067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T, Sonnemans, J, van de Kuilen, G, & Wakker, PP (2009). A truth serum for non-Bayesians: Correcting proper scoring rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 14611489. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00557.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peeters, R, & Wolk, L (2017). Eliciting interval beliefs: An experimental study. PLoS ONE, 12(4), e0175163 10.1371/journal.pone.0175163CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Plott, CR, Wit, J, & Yang, WC (2003). Parimutuel betting markets as information aggregation devices: Experimental results. Economic Theory, 22(3), 311–251 10.1007/s00199-002-0306-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prelec, D (2004). A Bayesian truth serum for subjective data. Science, 306(5695), 462466. 10.1126/science.1102081CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robson, A. (2005). Multi-item contests. Working paper.Google Scholar
Thaler, R, & Ziemba, WT (1988). Parimutuel betting markets: Racetracks and lotteries. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(2), 161174. 10.1257/jep.2.2.161CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, CD (2018). N-dimensional Blotto games with heterogeneous battlefield values. Economic Theory, 65(3), 509544. 10.1007/s00199-016-1030-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, X, Yu, K, Zhang, T, & Huang, TS (2010). Image classification using super-vector coding of local image descriptors. ECCV 2010. Lecture Notes in Computer Science, 6315, 141154. 10.1007/978-3-642-15555-0_11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Peeters and Wolk supplementary material

Peeters and Wolk supplementary material
Download Peeters and Wolk supplementary material(File)
File 1.5 MB