Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-22T05:56:33.053Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Perceived inequality and variability in the expression of parochial altruism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2025

Cody T. Ross*
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture, Leipzig, Germany
Anne C. Pisor
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology, Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture, Leipzig, Germany Department of Anthropology and Social Science Research Institute, The Pennyslvania State University, University Park, PA, USA Department of Anthropology, Washington State University, Pullman, WA, USA
*
Corresponding author: Cody T. Ross; Email: [email protected]

Abstract

It is commonly argued that humans have generalised predispositions for within-group favouritism and between-group animus (i.e. that humans are parochially altruistic), leading to higher levels of internal conflict in societies with greater diversity. Other research, however, has questioned both the ubiquity of parochial altruism and the role of diversity per se in causing social discord. Here, we use ethnographic, social network and experimental economic game data to explore this topic in two multi-ethnic Colombian communities. We examine the extent to which Afrocolombian and Emberá residents express parochial altruism, finding appreciable variability between communities, and across individuals within communities. When present, parochial altruism appears to be driven by divergent perceptions of group-based economic need, not group identity per se. Our results suggest that diversity may be less likely to cause social discord than past work has suggested, as long as group-based inequalities in wealth, well-being and representation – that can destabilise positive inter-group relationships – are minimised.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press

Social media summary: Perceived inequality affects expression of parochial altruism in Afrocolombian and Emberá communities in rural Colombia.

1. Introduction

Humans sometimes behave in a parochially altruistic manner (Bowles, Reference Bowles2008) – that is, they engage in within-group cooperation coupled with some degree of out-group hostility or animus (see Supporting Information, SI, Section 1.1 for notes on terminology). However, the intensity and prevalence of such parochial altruism appear to vary, sometimes substantially, across human groups and across contexts (de Dreu et al., Reference de Dreu, Balliet and Halevy2014; Böhm et al., Reference Böhm, Rusch and Baron2020). While some of this variation is probably due to variability in the methods used to study the phenomena (Pisor & Ross, Reference Pisor and Ross2023), variation in the socio-ecological context of inter-group relations seems to have profound effects on inter-personal behaviour. At times, markers of identity – e.g. language, ethnic background, or religion – come to delineate hard boundaries that structure behaviour, while in other cases potential markers of identity do not lead to pronounced differences in how people treat one another. The relationship between identity group (see SI, Section 1.2), the structuring of cooperation and conflict, and resultant socio-cultural outcomes thus remains a central focus of study across the social sciences – from anthropology to political science and economics.

Controversial work in the 1990s and 2000s found identity-group diversity (specifically ethnic diversity) to be negatively associated with a variety of socio-cultural outcomes serving as proxies of ‘the public good’ (e.g. see Easterly & Levine, Reference Easterly and Levine1997; Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999; Alesina & Ferrara, Reference Alesina and Ferrara2005). These arguments posit that where identity-group diversity is high, individuals of a particular group will cooperate amongst themselves, while competing with individuals of other groups, in turn leading to less efficient systems at some higher level of organisation (like the county, or nation). These studies, however, have been critiqued, with researchers arguing that diversity per se may not have negative impacts on higher-level socio-cultural outcomes, but rather that perceptions of zero-sumness between groups and structures of group-based dominance (e.g. discriminatory legal frameworks, apartheid systems, and unjust power or resource imbalances) – that sometimes arise in the presence of diversity – lead to such outcomes (e.g. Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013; Wimmer et al., Reference Wimmer, Cederman and Min2009; Beheim & Bell, Reference Beheim and Bell2024). In other words, identity-group diversity itself may pose little threat to wide-scale cooperation if institutions ensuring just treatment of diverse ethnic or other identity groups are maintained. Empirical work has since explored the effects of ethnically-structured inequality on higher-order socio-cultural outcomes (e.g. Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Michalopoulos and Papaioannou2016), finding evidence that between-group inequality may indeed play a mediating role in the correlation between ethnic diversity and adverse socio-cultural outcomes uncovered in earlier work.

Most empirical test of these ideas, however, do not directly assess the underlying causal model by measuring both: (i) whether cooperation and animus are structured by group-identity in real-world social networks; and (ii) whether inter-group relations are causal in the resulting socio-cultural outcomes. Instead, ecological regressions and rather coarse, national or administrative-district data are used to test if aggregate-level indicators of socio-cultural outcomes are associated with aggregate-level metrics of diversity (Pisor & Ross, Reference Pisor and Ross2023). Such approaches are subject to unmeasured confounding (Wakefield, Reference Wakefield2003) and the ecological inference problem (see Piantadosi et al., Reference Piantadosi, Byar and Green1988; Wakefield, Reference Wakefield2004; Lawson et al., Reference Lawson, James and Ngadaya2015; Ross & Winterhalder, Reference Ross and Winterhalder2016).

In this paper, we focus on point (i) – whether cooperation and animus are structured by group identity in real-world social networks. We designed a fine-scale, quantitative study of how identity-group structures both positive and negative social ties in a near-complete census of two rural, multi-ethnic, Colombian communities. More specifically, we draw on social network data and network-structured economic games to explore variation in the expression of, and preferences for, parochial altruism in two populations composed of Afrocolombian and Indigenous Emberá individuals. To measure variation in overt behaviour, we draw on network analysis methods to study structure in social and food/money sharing networks (Koster & Leckie, Reference Koster and Leckie2014). To measure variation in preferences for cooperation with, exploitation of, and animus towards others, we draw on network-structured variants of classic economic games (see Gervais, Reference Gervais2017). Additionally, we integrate qualitative methods to assess how site-level variables might influence the degree to which parochial altruism is expressed.

As we are interested in how different contexts of inter-ethnic interaction impact expression of parochial altruism, we selected two study sites in Colombia – one on the ethnic boundary between Afrocolombian and Emberá groups, and one in a territory where Afrocolombians have demographic prominence. The sites differ in key ways, especially in the perceptions of between group wealth inequality, as we describe in more detail later on. To guide our interpretation of statistical differences between sites, we draw on ethnographic observations and qualitative interviews with respondents (Geertz, Reference Geertz1973), gathered over periods of several months living in these communities. In what remains of the paper, we review the literature on inter-group relations and then present our empirical work on perceived between-group wealth inequality and parochial altruism in rural Colombia. We conclude by commenting on the potential value of individual-level, network-based approaches for studying inter-group relations and socio-cultural outcomes more broadly.

1.1. Conflict and cooperation between groups

When parochial altruism emerges with particular intensity, it can drive some of the most abhorrent of human behaviours: warfare, apartheid and genocide all stem from behavioural processes in which cooperation – or in a weaker sense, coordination – between in-group members is used to compete with or harm out-group members (see SI, Section 1.3). Such behaviours seem omnipresent in human history: antisemitism against European Jews has been present from the Edict of Expulsion in 1290 to the Holocaust in the 1940s and beyond (Brustein & King, Reference Brustein and King2004); in the 1840s to the 1870s in California, settlers and government actors engaged in the genocide of Native Americans (Lindsay, Reference Lindsay2012; Madley, Reference Madley2016); in 1904–1908, Germans occupying what is now Namibia did the same to Herero and Namaqua groups (Erichsen & Olusoga, Reference Erichsen and Olusoga2010); from the 1940s to the 1990s an Apartheid regime in South Africa institutionalised a brutal system of racial segregation (Clark & Worger, Reference Clark and Worger2013); and, in 1994, in the span of only a few months, Hutu militias in Rwanda killed several hundred thousand members of Tutsi and Twa ethnic groups, nearly a sixth of the country's population (Magnarella, Reference Magnarella2005).

Given such a history of between-group conflicts, some scholars have come to view parochial altruism, or at least predispositions towards it, as something of a universal of human psychology, arguing that cognitive mechanisms that lead us to value in-group members and devalue out-group members have a deep evolutionary history, and are nearly inexorable (Clark et al., Reference Clark, Liu and Winegard2019). This view, however, has also been challenged for some time (e.g. Cashdan, Reference Cashdan2001, see also Sections 5.3 and 5.4).

Cases of inter-group cooperation – although perhaps less studied and more prosaic – seem just as omnipresent in human history (Fearon & Laitin, Reference Fearon and Laitin1996; Glowacki, Reference Glowacki2022). Even in the cases of violence described above, parochialism was not universal among members of the aggressing groups – and cosmopolitan altruism (Galston, Reference Galston1993) could be found undergirding incredible acts of bravery. Yad Vashem – The World Holocaust Remembrance Center – has officially recognised more than 27,000 individuals from more than 50 countries as rescuers who risked their own lives to protect Jewish individuals from Nazis and fascists (Fogelman, Reference Fogelman2011). In Rwanda too, the same heroism was shown by some Hutu, with some rescuers going as far as claiming (Rothbart & Cooley, Reference Rothbart and Cooley2016: 92):

I would lock the house with my family [and a rescued Tutsi child] inside, and I'd stand outside. I would tell them, ‘If you are going to kill her, then go ahead and burn the entire house, throw a grenade and kill all of them! They are all my children! If you are going to kill her, then kill me too!’

and many moderate Hutu were themselves murdered by other Hutu precisely because they risked everything to defend out-group members (Rothbart & Cooley, Reference Rothbart and Cooley2016). Many white South Africans rose in resistance to racist policies, and nearly a third of the anti-apartheid activists tried for high treason in the 1956 Treason Trial were of white or Indian background (Shimoni, Reference Shimoni1988). More than 100 years after the genocide in Namibia, representatives in Germany, hearing the calls from the Herero people, began to work towards formally accepting historic and moral responsibility for their nation's actions (Sarkin & Fowler, Reference Sarkin and Fowler2008), and pledged 1.1 billion Euros towards aid programmes in Nambia as a gesture of reconciliation (Dagdelen et al., Reference Dagdelen, Hänsel and Nastic2021).

1.2. Valuation of out-group members

Although inter-group relations are often viewed broadly through the lens of parochial altruism (Böhm et al., Reference Böhm, Rusch and Baron2020), intergroup relations are not always competitive or hostile (Fearon & Laitin, Reference Fearon and Laitin1996; Brewer, Reference Brewer, Baumeister and Finkel2010; Jha, Reference Jha2013). An individual's attitude about an out-group member – that is, the value they place on them (e.g. Gervais & Fessler, Reference Gervais and Fessler2017) – can be positive, neutral, or negative. In most parts of the world, there are routine interactions between individuals of differing identity groups. Fearon (Reference Fearon2003), for example, studied ethnic diversity across 160 countries and found 822 ethnic groups with population sizes reaching at least 1% of their host countries’ total population, and remarks that in places like Papua New Guinea, ethnic diversity is so high that no group is large enough to make up even 1% of the population. Similarly, Eberhard et al. (Reference Eberhard, Simons and Fennig2021) suggest that there are more than 7,000 languages spoken around the world, and Hunter (Reference Hunter2014) argues that there are more than 4,000 religious identity groups. While all of these estimates are sensitive to methodology – especially the lumping vs. splitting of group identities – they highlight the order of human cultural diversity (see also Bell et al., Reference Bell, Richerson and McElreath2009; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini and Bell2016). In spite of this diversity, most interactions in most human societies are characterised by tolerance, if not outright cooperation, rather than animus (Fearon & Laitin, Reference Fearon and Laitin1996); see also Brewer (Reference Brewer, Baumeister and Finkel2010), Böhm et al. (Reference Böhm, Rusch and Baron2020) and Riek et al. (Reference Riek, Mania and Gaertner2006) for relevant reviews. It is thus important to identify the mechanisms which lead to a breakdown of congenial relationships across identity boundaries, rather than viewing parochial altruism as a condicio sine qua non.

In some contexts, especially when population sizes are small, individuals may judge others on the basis of individual-level traits, regardless of identity-group similarity or dissimilarity. However, in larger populations, often characterised by a ‘small-world’ network structure (Watts & Strogatz, Reference Watts and Strogatz1998) – where tight, homophilic clusters are linked by cross-cluster ties – individuals begin using heuristics to judge anonymous alters on the basis of their social group (Dunbar, Reference Dunbar2008). Out-groups may become cognitively represented as single entities, and a valuation – positive, neutral, or negative – may then be extended to all group members (Pietraszewski, Reference Pietraszewski2021). When an out-group is negatively valued, individuals of a focal group may treat out-group members with contempt, hold and spread derogatory stereotypes of them, and even dehumanise them (see Moffett, Reference Moffett2013; Haslam, Reference Haslam2006, for reviews). Negative stereotypes often frame out-group members as competitors who can inflict costs on in-group members (Riek et al., Reference Riek, Mania and Gaertner2006; Brewer, Reference Brewer, Baumeister and Finkel2010; Böhm et al., Reference Böhm, Rusch and Baron2020). Parochial altruism appears most likely to arise in contexts where individuals generalise negative evaluations across anonymous out-group individuals (see de Dreu et al., Reference de Dreu, Balliet and Halevy2014, for discussion). However, what social forces might cause negative evaluations of out-group members to be more likely?

1.3. Mechanisms of interest

There are at least three widely studied (and often overlapping) families of theoretical models linking diversity, out-group valuations, and resultant socio-cultural outcomes: (i) models based on norm differences and coordination; (ii) models based on between-group resource inequality or other forms of inter-group dominance; and (iii) models based on demographic characteristics and perceptions of ‘out-group threat’.

1.3.1. Norm/preference heterogeneity and miscoordination

In the 1990s, economists focused on understanding local-level variation in the funding of public programmes in the United States came to suspect that ethnic diversity might be associated with reduced contributions to the public good (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999). Although the implications of this work have been somewhat controversial, Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999) were intent on understanding the cause of biased behaviour: their data showed that white Americans decrease investment in public programmes as the demographic prominence of other ethnic groups in a given region increases. In their model, a population of voters can decide on the level of investment in public goods (i.e. a tax rate) and on the types of public goods funded through taxation; as the population becomes more fragmented (in terms of norms/preferences for types of public investments), overall public investment by the majority group decreases. However, diversity in group identity will not cause norm disalignment as in the Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999) model unless norms strongly covary with group-identity empirically.

Recognising that norms – and even group identity itself – are often flexible social constructs subject to change (e.g. during enculturation), anthropologists developed mathematical models to explore inter-ethnic coordination in the more general case where norms are dynamic, but nevertheless impact pay-offs in coordination games (e.g. see McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003). In this family of models, identity-group diversity is not assumed to imply norm diversity a priori as in Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999); instead, norms are frequency dependent and dynamic, so that if migration rates into an area are low, then variation in group identity does not imply variation in norms (i.e. the norms of the majority group may be adopted by newcomers to the majority area).

For this reason, the model of McElreath et al. (Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003) predicts that identity group will only be a salient feature for individuals when the costs to miscoordination are high, where norm variation is high, and where norms are tightly correlated with group identity. In such contexts, in-group biases are expected to emerge, as they minimise the frequency of conflicts resulting from norm disalignment (McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003; Moya & Boyd, Reference Moya and Boyd2015; Moffett, Reference Moffett2013). The McElreath et al. (Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003) model, however, is also limited in scope, as it assumes that individuals can be described as having, or deploying, only a single kind of norm in inter-personal interactions. In subsequent work (e.g. Bunce & McElreath, Reference Bunce and McElreath2017, Reference Bunce and McElreath2018; Bunce, Reference Bunce2021), many assumptions in McElreath et al. (Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003) are relaxed. Most notably, Bunce (Reference Bunce2021) explores how cross-cultural competency – the ability to understand and coordinate on multiple norms – allows for mutually beneficial inter-group relationships to be maintained, and miscoordination avoided.

Human groups, even those with very different norms, can benefit from cooperating with one another – especially via the mechanism of commerce/trade (e.g. Pinker, Reference Pinker2011; Jha, Reference Jha2013) – and so we may seek out such relationships, especially when they offer opportunities for mutual gain relative to parochial exclusion (Bowles & Gintis, Reference Bowles and Gintis2004). At an individual level, this might involve learning and appreciating different ways of doing things (Bunce, Reference Bunce2021). At a broader level, cultural institutions to protect beneficial inter-ethnic relationships can emerge. Jha (Reference Jha2013), for example, shows that medieval trading ports in South East Asia, despite being more ethnically mixed than other localities, were five times less prone to Hindu–Muslim riots between 1850 and 1950. Jha (Reference Jha2013) attributes this finding to the fact that trade and commerce carried significant benefits for members of both groups, and thus enduring cultural institutions and cosmopolitan norms for valuing and coordinating with one another emerged. Contrasting the empirical work of Jha (Reference Jha2013) with much of the literature on inter-group conflict suggests that it is not simply diversity that impacts socio-cultural outcomes: context, norms, and perceived costs and benefits matter.

1.3.2. Resource constraints, between-group inequality and inter-group dominance

To explain humans’ purported predisposition towards within-group favouritism and between-group animus, many evolutionary explanations focus on the problem of gaining and maintaining resource access, which may have acted as a strong selection pressure over long periods of human history (Choi & Bowles, Reference Choi and Bowles2007; Seabright, Reference Seabright2004; Wrangham & Glowacki, Reference Wrangham and Glowacki2012). If key resources – like potable water, arable land and productive fisheries – are heterogeneously distributed, then groups controlling resource-dense territories would benefit demographically (i.e. increase in size) if their individual members possessed adaptions to both (i) cooperate with fellow in-group members and (ii) compete with out-group members – either by simply denying out-group members access to resources, or more directly by violently competing with out-groups to expand in-group resource control (Bowles, Reference Bowles2008; Bell & Moya, Reference Bell and Moya2021). The coevolutionary mechanism in which between-group competition stabilises within-group cooperation, however, need not be genetically coded: cultural institutions for regulating within- and between-group behaviour are subject to similar coevolutionary dynamics (Zefferman & Mathew, Reference Zefferman and Mathew2015; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini and Bell2016). Similarly, the inequality in resource control that might drive between-group competition must be interpreted broadly. Beyond land, water, or material resources, inequality in social affordances, respect, prestige, political representation or a variety of other sociocultual factors may influence between-group relations (e.g. Fiske et al., Reference Fiske, Dupree and Nicolas2016; Sidanius & Protto, Reference Sidanius and Protto2001; Henrich & Gil-White, Reference Henrich and Gil-White2001).

At a proximate level, resource control means power (Fiske et al., Reference Fiske, Dupree and Nicolas2016): a group with resource control can selectively grant or withhold resource access (Balliet et al., Reference Balliet, Tybur and Van Lange2017), possibly increasing animus and conflict, especially as power becomes concentrated and used to benefit a restricted class of individuals (Montalvo & Reynal-Querol, Reference Montalvo and Reynal-Querol2005). Often, the most powerful group is the largest demographically. That said, resource control and power can lie in the hands of the few if their competitive ability is increased by other factors, like access to weapons (e.g. during the conquest of California; Madley, Reference Madley2016).

Group living has constituted a critical and enduring part of human evolutionary history, and we should thus expect humans to have adaptations for dealing with key problems associated with group living – especially fairness in resource division (Bøggild & Petersen, Reference Bøggild, Petersen, Shackelford and Hansen2016). If one sub-group in a given population uses its position of power to extract disproportionate benefit, this has the potential to trigger responses from other parties. Groups with less power can form alliances to improve their competitive ability (Redhead & von Rueden, Reference Redhead and von Rueden2021) – indicating some level of flexibility in how humans perceive and act on group identity. Militant groups, for example, often form alliances in the context of conflicts with powerful and repressive governments, and they find ways to enforce coordination, even if trust is initially low or shared norms absent (Bapat & Bond, Reference Bapat and Bond2012). Similar forms of alliances can also function within the political realm – e.g. inter-ethnic alliances in Bolivia led to the rise of the first Indigenous president in South America in 2005, and to the passing of a new Bolivian constitution in 2009 (Fontana, Reference Fontana2014). In sum, there is evidence to suggest that power and resource considerations might be a cause of both parochial behaviour and between-group relationships, depending on context.

Given that: (i) strong imbalances in group power, status or resource control have the potential to attenuate between-group cooperation (Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013) and even trigger between-group conflict (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Michalopoulos and Papaioannou2016); and (ii) conflict is normally costly for the parties involved, there is scope for selection on norms and institutions that reduce status differentiation and bridge group divides. For example, cultural norms for intermarriage between European royal families appear to have decreased European war frequency by extending kinship networks across group boundaries (Benzell & Cooke, Reference Benzell and Cooke2021). Similarly, there is scope for inter-group concessions from powerful groups towards disempowered groups in order to minimise conflicts. Classical models in foraging theory, like the tolerated theft model (Winterhalder, Reference Winterhalder1996), would predict that groups in positions of power should make concessions to outgroups, as long as the marginal benefit of the resources they are conceding to the outgroup exceed their own expected resource defence costs (see also Rusch, Reference Rusch2014). Under such a model, we might expect inter-group tolerance to be common when between-group inequality is low, but parochialism to emerge as between-group inequality becomes more extreme (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Michalopoulos and Papaioannou2016).

Other cogent models, however, complicate this explanation. Huber and Mayoral (Reference Huber and Mayoral2019), for example, make the case that one must also account for the structure of within-group inequality as well, arguing that – especially in modern-day nation-state contexts – the intensity of civil conflicts is likely to be highest when within-group inequality is high, as such inequality decreases the opportunity cost to poor group members of fighting, and increases the potential per capita spoils of war that can be reaped by the rich elite.

1.3.3. Demographic differences and perceptions of ‘out-group threat’

One of the most important characteristics affecting a group's resource holding potential is its population size relative to other groups, as this predicts its ability to win an altercation with another group (Wrangham & Glowacki, Reference Wrangham and Glowacki2012; Turchin & Gavrilets, Reference Turchin and Gavrilets2009), even if altercations are not violent (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999; Posner, Reference Posner2004). Because group size confers a hegemonic group power in inter-group interactions, political scientists have found that inter-group relationships tend towards parochialism when demographic processes threaten the predominance of the majority group (Slack & Doyon, Reference Slack and Doyon2001; Advani & Reich, Reference Advani and Reich2015). Social psychologists have likewise found that individuals are more likely to apply a negative valuation to out-group members when they are perceived as a ‘realistic threat’ to power (see Riek et al., Reference Riek, Mania and Gaertner2006; Brewer, Reference Brewer, Baumeister and Finkel2010; Stulp et al., Reference Stulp, Kordsmeyer and Buunk2012, for reviews). In the domain of demography, ‘out-group threat’ is highest when the difference in size between in-group and out-group is small, especially if the size of that difference is shrinking (Hewstone et al., Reference Hewstone, Rubin and Willis2002; Slack & Doyon, Reference Slack and Doyon2001).

Demographic structure may directly influence violent competition between groups: Slack and Doyon (Reference Slack and Doyon2001), for example, apply event history analysis to war crimes data from the former Yugoslavia (1990–1993) and find that civilian-involved acts of violence – mostly Bosnian Serbs harming Bosniak Muslims – were more likely to occur in areas with higher ‘indices of ethnic competition’ – i.e. in areas where Serbs and Muslims had similar population sizes, and in areas where the Muslim population was experiencing higher growth relative to the Serb population. Demographic changes can also lead to indirect competition, or a biased legal structure that favours in-group members, which then leads to further hostilities. White and Zoabi (Reference White and Zoabi2012), for instance, argue that right-wing Israelis speak transparently of ‘the demographic problem’, or ‘the fear that an Arab population in the country will become bigger than the Jewish population’ (Lustick, Reference Lustick2013: 185), and that demography has thus exerted a powerful influence on Israeli policies – e.g. where obtainment of nationality is facilitated only for people of specific ethno-religious backgrounds. In contrast, members of a high-status or demographically prominent group may often show magnanimity towards minority group members (Hewstone et al., Reference Hewstone, Rubin and Willis2002), when the status gap is very wide and when the minority group is small enough to not pose a threat to power relations.

In sum, we might expect parochial altruism to occur most notably in situations where: (i) behaviour is conditioned on group-level valuations, rather than individual-level characteristics; and (ii) contextual factors (e.g. norm differences, wealth/power differences, or demographic patterns) lead to negatively valenced group-level valuations.

1.4. A case study of inter-group relations in rural Colombia

In the present paper, we draw on a case study of two rural Colombian communities to elucidate how parochial altruism may be modulated by contextual factors, especially perceptions of between-group wealth differences – which may affect the extent to which out-group members are held as competitors to the in-group or as brethren in need of generosity. Both communities studied here are composed of Afrocolombian and Indigenous Emberá residents. While one community (the inland community) lies on the Afrocolombian–Emberá ethnic boundary, the other (the coastal community) is located where Afrocolombians are demographically predominant. At the district-level, Afrocolombians and Emberá at the inland site have similar group sizes, resource holdings, and power. In contrast, in the coastal district, the Emberá have a smaller group size, smaller resource holdings, and less power. These differences in the locally salient cultural context of between-group interactions allow us to explore contingency in the expression of parochial altruism.

We explore inter-group relationships in Colombia using a combination of ethnographic, social network, and economic game data. Our mixed-method approach allows us to measure expression of in-group favouritism, out-group exploitation, and out-group animus at an individual and community level. We discuss how perceptions of inequality affect whether individuals respond to out-group need with beneficence rather than contempt. Finally, we comment on the implications of our findings to the literatures linking identity-group diversity and socio-cultural outcomes via the mechanism of parochial altruism.

2. Inter-ethnic relationships in rural Colombia

2.1. Historical context of inter-ethnic relationships

The contemporary ethnic make-up of Colombia is heavily influenced by colonisation and the slave trade (Cantor, Reference Cantor2000; Wade, Reference Wade2002; Castillo & Abril, Reference Castillo, Abril and van Dijk2009). During the late 1500s through the 1800s, Spanish colonisers transported hundreds of thousands of enslaved Africans to Colombia in order to replace the labour being performed by the (rapidly declining) enslaved Indigenous populations (Benson Latin American Collection 1779–1852; Murillo Urrutia, Reference Murillo Urrutia2015). These enslaved individuals laboured primarily in gold and emerald mines, plantations, and cattle ranches – most notably on the Pacific coast in the states of Chocó and Cauca, which today remain areas with a strong demographic prominence of Afrocolombians (Murillo Urrutia, Reference Murillo Urrutia2015; Wade, Reference Wade2002).

After the cessation of slavery in Colombia, the relationship between the descendants of enslaved Africans and Indigenous peoples of the Pacific coast could be generally characterised as one of tolerance (Ross et al., Reference Ross, Campino and Winterhalder2015) – and sometimes even one of explicit cooperation and inter-dependence through institutions like compadrazgo or godparenthood (Cayón, Reference Cayón1973). At the national level, there remains an overarching sense of solidarity between these groups, as they have jointly fought for greater representation, visibility, and institutional support inside of Colombia (Castillo & Abril, Reference Castillo, Abril and van Dijk2009; Iglesias, Reference Iglesias2018). However, the nature of this inter-ethnic relationship appears sensitive to local contexts, especially in recent times as competing claims over resource access and land titling have led to disagreements between some Afrocolombian and Indigenous groups (Ng'weno, Reference Ng'weno2000; Davis, Reference Davis2002; García, Reference García2009; Velasco, Reference Velasco2011).

Inter-ethnic relations can also be quite variable within communities: ethnographic accounts from Cayón (Reference Cayón1973) – writing almost 50 years ago about inter-ethnic relations at the inland community described in Section 2.2 – indicate both that Afrocolombians and Emberá have long lived in a simbiosis cultural (with Afrocolombians, for example, commonly giving food and lodging to Emberá) and that it was also common to hear derogatory cross-group stereotypes voiced by members of both groups. He even notes cases of mistrust boiling over into inter-ethnic homicide. Ethnographic observations at the present time remain remarkably consistent with those of Cayón (Reference Cayón1973); inter-ethnic food sharing and lodging are still daily occurrences among some – but not all – members of the community, and derogatory cross-group stereotypes are still voiced by some. These discrepant ethnographic accounts of inter-group relations raise the question as to how one can more formally assess the overall extent of inter-group cooperation and/or animus within and between communities.

2.2. Collaborating communities

In the coastal and inland communities considered here, a large proportion of residents – Afrocolombian and Emberá alike – are internally displaced persons (Oyola, Reference Oyola2015; Escobar, Reference Escobar2003), forced from their natal communities by guerilla and paramilitary groups, mostly in the 1990s and 2000s (Ibáñez, Reference Ibáñez2009). The coastal community is located in the Pacific region of western Colombia and relies on a mixture of artisanal fishing and local wage labour. The inland community is located in the rainforest of western Colombia and relies on a mixture of horticulture and local wage labour.

The socio-economic situation of the in-sample Emberá is similar in both communities: they are a demographically smaller group that resides on more marginal land than the in-sample Afrocolombians, and they have comparably less access to resources like electricity, clean water, and sanitation services. However, out-of-sample, at the larger administrative-district scale, the inland Emberá community is – in contrast to the coastal Emberá community – comparably well off. The inland Emberá community has a large population size, access to markets for selling hand-crafted artisanal jewelry, and key organisational connections; additionally, most individuals (though not those in sample) reside on a sovereign resguardo. The general status of the inland Emberá at the district level has led many inland Afrocolombians to think that the Emberá are generally well off compared with Afrocolombians, even though this is not necessarily true of the in-sample Emberá respondents, who report not having the same level of economic stability as the resguardo community. The perception that the Emberá are well off is virtually absent from the coastal community, however, where the Emberá population is, and is perceived to be, living under tougher socio-economic circumstances – on the border of a landfill, after a series of displacements.

At the district level, the coastal study area is predominately Afrocolombian (0.84 Afrocolombian, 0.09 Emberá and 0.07 Mestizo), while the inland study area rests along a three-way ethnic boundary with a less discrepant distribution of ethnic groups (0.14 Afrocolombian, 0.34 Emberá and 0.52 Mestizo) (DANE, Reference DANE2005). The demographic composition of each sample, however, is somewhat different from that of the larger district. In both study communities, the sample is composed of one comparatively large Afrocolombian sub-community (n = 88 adults coastal, n = 130 adults inland) and one comparatively small Emberá sub-community (n = 28 adults coastal, n = 21 adults inland). In both coastal and inland communities, in-sample Afrocolombians have higher material wealth (average household-level wealth is about 3.7 times higher for Afrocolombians relative to Emberá in both communities), higher incomes (self-reported monthly income is about 1.8 and 3.9 times higher for Afrocolombians relative to Emberá in the coastal and inland communities, respectively), and stronger political influence at the local level. See Figure 1 for group-specific log-wealth distributions.

Figure 1. Mirror-histograms of log wealth by site and ethnic group (Afrocolombians in blue, Emberá in goldenrod). In both sites, Afrocolombians have higher average wealth than Emberá. However, even though there is less wealth overlap at the inland site, it is common for Afrocolombians there to perceive Emberá as being comparably well off, largely because they overgeneralise based on the economic status of Emberá living in the nearby resguardo.

2.3. Research goals

To address the open theoretical and methodological questions outlined in the introduction, we ask:

Q1: To what extent does ethnic identity structure social relationships, and behaviour in network-structured economic games measuring altruistic giving, taking/exploitation, and costly reduction.

While both communities are characterised by ethnic diversity, the ethnographic account discussed above (Cayón, Reference Cayón1973) suggests that such boundaries may not actually limit cooperative giving, at least among a subset of the population. This being said, the same ethnographer notes anecdotal evidence of inter-group conflict and negative inter-group stereotypes (Cayón, Reference Cayón1973). To resolve these conflicting verbal accounts, we use economic games, self-reports, and ethnographic data to study the extent to which ethnic identity acts as a container for cooperation and animus. We evaluate this question both at the level of community – by contrasting network-level characterisations of inter-ethnic relations at the coastal and inland sites – and at the level of the individual – by visualising individual-level variation in preferences for in-group vs. out-group exploitation.

Q2: How responsive is parochial altruism to varying cultural contexts?

Specifically, if parochial altruism is indeed flexible across sites, the literature suggests that within-group cooperation and between-group animus should be more pronounced: (i) in areas, such as the geographic boundaries between groups, where norm differences, the social salience of ethnicity, and preferences for identity-group-based assortment tend to be higher (McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003); (ii) in areas where the relative population size of interacting groups is more balanced (Slack & Doyon, Reference Slack and Doyon2001; Posner, Reference Posner2004; Advani & Reich, Reference Advani and Reich2015); and (iii) in areas where wealth and power differences map onto ethnic identity groups (Waring, Reference Waring2012; Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013; Bell & Moya, Reference Bell and Moya2021). Comparing the coastal and inland communities, we investigate if differences in the expression of parochial altruism can be attributed to these mechanisms. If such differences cannot be explained with extant models, we will consider other explanations.

Q3: To what extent can apparent parochial altruism be explained by individual and dyadic covariates?

Across real-world populations, inter-personal relationships are influenced by many variables – e.g. kinship and relative socio-economic status – that have the potential to covary with markers of ethnicity. For example, if individuals are more likely to give to kin than to non-kin, and kin are of the same ethnicity, then apparent in-group biases may be epiphenomenal, i.e. it may appear that giving is directed toward co-ethnics even if ethnic identity per se affords no special consideration in resource transfers. As such, in the Colombian context, we ask if estimates of parochial altruism are robust to controls for individual-level characteristics (e.g. wealth and food security), as well dyad-level characteristics (e.g. kinship and marriage).

3. Methods

Dyadic data were first collected on self-reported friendships and resource transfers using ‘name-generator’ interviews (Redhead et al., Reference Redhead, Dalla Ragione and Ross2023). Data on friendship ties were elicited by asking respondents to name the people that they had spent the most time socializing with in the 30 day period prior to the interview. Data on food/money transfers were elicited by asking respondents to name: (i) the people that they had given food/money to; and (ii) the people they had received food/money from in the 30 day period prior to the interview. Dyadic ties in giving, taking/exploitation, and costly reduction were assessed using the ‘RICH games’ of Gervais (Reference Gervais2017), explained in Section 3.1. Network data are visualised in Figure 2.

Figure 2. Network data. Afrocolombians are plotted in blue and Emberá in goldenrod. Quantitative estimates of assortment metrics can be found in Figure 3. The exploitation/taking game data are dense; ties represent coins left for alters, i.e. non-exploitative ties.

In both sites, informed consent was obtained from each respondent prior to data collection, and from the community leader or local community council, when appropriate. Owing to limited literacy rates, informed consent was obtained verbally after providing respondents with a verbal description (in Spanish) of the research process and explaining how their data will be used (anonymously, for research purposes); in addition, participants were provided with a written consent document for their own reference. All field protocols were approved by the Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology in Leipzig Germany. See SI, Section 2 for details on data and permissions.

3.1. Network-structured economic games

To measure inclinations towards parochial altruism, we used three network-structured economic games (Gervais, Reference Gervais2017): a giving game, a taking game and a costly reduction game. For each of these games, we presented individuals with a photo array containing 7 × 10 cm photographs of all male and female adults residing their respective communities. In total there were 115 and 151 targets/alters (in each site, respectively) to whom focal players could allocate coins or tokens. Photographs were organised onto four boards. The order of the boards was randomised between respondents, and the order of the photographs on the boards was randomised on four separate occasions over the course of data collection at each site. In total, 93 of 115 (coastal) and 137 of 151 respondents (inland) completed the economic games. All three games were played in sequence – in the same order – during the same interview. After all interviews were complete, all game participants were given the currency allocated to them by themselves and other community members during the games. The total stakes per person amounted to 83,000 (coastal) and 110,500 (inland) Colombian pesos (average of ~35 USD) at the time of data collection.

In the giving game, the stakes were set at 15,000 and 20,000 Colombian pesos in the coastal and inland sites, respectively. Individuals could allocate any number of 1,000 peso coins to any cell in the photo array, including their own. Individuals varied widely in how much was kept and how much was given, with mean giving rates of 11,760 (78.4%, coastal) and 14,870 pesos (74.3%, inland), medians of 13,000 (86.6%) and 17,000 pesos (85%), standard deviations of 3,500 and 5,000 pesos, minima of 0 and 0 pesos, and maxima of 15,000 and 20,000 pesos.

In the taking game, the stakes were set at 57,500 and 75,500 Colombian pesos. Individuals could take or leave the single 500 peso coin that was pre-allocated to each photo in the photo array. Again, individuals varied widely in how much was taken and how much was left, with mean leaving rates of 39,800 (69.2%, coastal) and 36,300 (48%, inland) pesos, medians of 47,000 (81.7%) and 34,000 (45%) pesos, standard deviations of 17,600 and 24,900 pesos, minima of 0 and 0 pesos, and maxima of 57,500 and 75,500 pesos.

In the costly reduction game, the stakes were set at 10,000 and 15,000 Colombian pesos. Individuals could keep the coins or use them purchase red tokens to punish/reduce other community members. Each token cost 1,000 pesos, and led to a reduction of the target's income by 4,000 pesos – the same multiplier used elsewhere (Gervais, Reference Gervais2017). Reduction was fairly infrequent, with mean payment rates for reducing of 1,600 (16%, coastal) and 1,400 (9%, inland) pesos, medians of 0 and 0 pesos, standard deviations of 2,800 and 3,400 pesos, minima of 0 and 0 pesos, and maxima of 10,000 and 15,000 pesos.

3.2. Statistical analysis and software

Network data collection and entry was managed using a custom R package (Ross & Redhead, Reference Ross and Redhead2021, Reference Ross and Redhead2023) and data analysis was handled entirely in R (version 4.0.5, R Core Team, 2021). Statistical models were coded in Stan and fit using the rstan package (version 2.21.2, Stan Development Team, 2020). We checked model fit and Markov Chain Monte Carlo performance using trace plots, $\hat{R}$, reported effective samples, and a variety of other visualisations (Gabry et al., Reference Gabry, Simpson and Vehtari2019). Our statistical models, outcome and control variables, and data collection protocols are defined precisely in the SI. To model network data, we use a generalisation of the Social Relations Model (Kenny & La Voie, Reference Kenny and La Voie1984; Koster et al., Reference Koster, Leckie and Aven2019; McElreath, Reference McElreath2016) to multinomial outcome data (see SI, Section 3).

4. Results

4.1. Quantitative findings

The results of model fitting are visualised in Figure 3. Within each column, blocks show the standardised effects of focal, alter, and dyadic characteristics on the likeliness of a tie. Of principal interest to our research questions are the effects in the Parochial block (row 4). Parameter estimates are blue for the coastal community and goldenrod for the inland community. Light goldenrod and light blue bars plot estimates from models without control variables – i.e. models that included the ethnicity of the focal and alter, with no other covariates. Dark goldenrod and dark blue bars give the same estimates while accounting for the full set of controls – that is, all of the predictors listed in the figure. The effects of control variables are similar to those described in Pisor et al. (Reference Pisor, Gervais and Purzycki2020) and are largely similar between communities (see SI, Section 4 for additional details).

Q1: To what extent does ethnic identity structure social relationships, and behaviour in network-structured economic games measuring altruistic giving, taking/exploitation, and costly reduction

Figure 3. Multinomial regression results (standardised coefficients) from the Social Relations Model. Points and line-ranges show the standardised effects of predictor variables on outcomes (as medians and 90% credible intervals). When the credible intervals exclude the value of zero (plotted as a dashed vertical line), there is evidence of a reliable effect. Each column indicates an independently modeled outcome variable: (i) friendship/socialising ties, (ii) food/money transfers; (iii) coin allocations in the allocation game; (iv) coin deductions in the taking game (coded so that positive parameter estimates reflect leaving coins); and (v) coins paid to reduce alters in the costly reduction game. For each of these outcomes in each community, we fit two models: both included the predictors directly related to parochial altruism (e.g. as in row 4), but the first (NC; no controls) excluded control variables – that is, the predictors in all other rows – and the second included all controls. The key estimates of interest are shown in the ‘Parochial’ row. For example, in the allocation game, both Afrocolombian and Emberá individuals (in both sites) showed a reliably positive tendency to give more to co-ethnics. Likewise, in the taking game, Emberá individuals, as well as inland Afrocolombian individuals, showed a reliably positive tendency to leave more for co-ethnics. However, coastal Afrocolombian individuals showed a reliable tendency to leave more for the ethnic out-group (model with no controls; light blue) or no tendency for preferential out-group exploitation (model with controls; dark blue).

Friendship ties suggest a high degree of social assortment on the basis of ethnic group identity; this parallels similar findings in other countries (e.g. Power, Reference Power2017; Baerveldt et al., Reference Baerveldt, Zijlstra and De Wolf2007). Despite Afrocolombians and Emberá living in close proximity to each other in both communities, socialising is primarily confined to within-ethnicity interactions. These data correspond to historic accounts of a paucity of inter-ethnic marriages despite a long history of social contact (Cayón, Reference Cayón1973), and genetic evidence that shows a high degree of population substructure in the Pacific region of Colombia, in contrast to the Caribbean region where genetic admixture is higher (Ossa et al., Reference Ossa, Aquino and Pereira2016).

From the perspective of Emberá individuals in both communities, positive ties – be they friendships, transfers of food or money, or transfers of coins in the RICH allocation and taking games – are more likely to be directed towards other Emberá than towards Afrocolombians. This social assortment is easily seen in Figure 2. Afrocolombians at the inland community also preferentially form friendships with and give to other Afrocolombians; however, this effect only partially holds in the coastal community, where food and money transfers (Figure 3, column 2), as well as behaviour in the taking game (Figure 3, column 4), show no reliable evidence of parochial preferences.

Although ethnic group membership clearly structures positive social relationships and allocation game play at both sites, there is less evidence of structure in networks reflecting negatively valanced relations. There is no clear ethnic pattern of costly reduction (Figure 3, column 5) directed at either in-group or out-group members in either community. Additionally, play in the taking game varied substantially across sites (Figure 3, column 4). Figure 4 explores this finding in more detail, and illustrates that there is substantial variation in exploitation behaviour, both across sites and ethnic identity groups, and between individuals of a given ethnic identity group within sites.

Q2: How responsive is parochial altruism to varying cultural contexts?

Figure 4. Scatterplots of the raw taking game data by site. Each point represents an individual, with the x-coordinate reflecting the in-group coin leaving rate and the y-coordinate reflecting the out-group coin leaving rate. Individuals in the upper-right corner of the plot showed indiscriminate charity, and refused to exploit others. Individuals in the lower-left indiscriminately took from all others. Individuals above the diagonal line showed a preference for leaving coins for the ethnic out-group at higher rates than the ethnic in-group, and vice versa for the individuals below the diagonal line. Extensive individual-level heterogeneity is apparent. At the coastal site, most Afrocolombians exhibit a preference to avoid taking from the out-group at a higher rate than the in-group. In contrast, at the inland site, the majority of individuals took from the ethnic out-group at higher rates.

When comparing measured parochial altruism at the coastal and inland communities (Figure 3, row 4), the effects in the taking game (Figure 3, column 4) and self-reported food/money sharing networks (Figure 3, column 2) stand out. In the taking game, where coins taken benefit the focal at the expense of an alter, both Afrocolombians and Emberá at the inland community are more likely to take coins from out-group members than in-group-members; however, on the coast, model estimates suggest that Afrocolombians are either just as likely to leave coins for Emberá as for Afrocolombians (model with controls) or are more likely to leave coins for Emberá than for Afrocolombians (model without controls). This effect can also be noted in Figure 4, as the majority of coastal Afrocolombian individuals cluster in the upper triangle of the plot, where the rate of leaving coins for out-group members exceeds the rate of leaving coins for in-group members. Similarly, Afrocolombians in the inland community appear to show parochialism in the food/money sharing network – a fact that may reflect a common (although not universal, Cayón, Reference Cayón1973) rejection of inter-ethnic food-sharing requests – while Afrocolombians in the coastal community show no such parochial preference and commonly engage in inter-ethnic food transfers. We discuss further qualitative evidence concerning these key findings, and provide more details about the relevant differences in cultural context, in Section 4.2.

Q3: To what extent can apparent parochial altruism be explained by individual and dyadic covariates?

We find that estimates of parochialism (Figure 3, row 4) are surprisingly robust to the inclusion of controls for material wealth, food security, marriage ties, and genetic relatedness – covariates that could otherwise generate epiphenomenal parochialism, especially in contexts like the RICH allocation game, where the set of resources that can be distributed is much smaller than the set of possible recipients. In one case to the contrary, the taking game model without controls appears to suggest a case of ‘anti-parochialism’, where Afrocolombians in the coastal community preferentially leave coins for Emberá alters. This effect, however, is attenuated in the model that includes control variables. As these control variables include the material wealth and food insecurity of the alter, the reduction in the effect size of anti-parochialism might indicate a mediating role of economic need at the coastal site in driving transfers from Afrocolombians toward Emberá.

4.2. Qualitative accounts

When asked in post-game interviews to explain their rationales for taking from whom they did, it was common for coastal Emberá respondents to emphasise taking from ‘those who already have money to live on’ or ‘those who have jobs’ and leaving for ‘people in similar or worse situations to [themselves]’ and ‘[their] neighbours who are also poor’. Some coastal Afrocolombians also specifically mentioned out-group ethnicity as a motivation for not taking coins: ‘[I left coins for] the Indigenous, the sick, and people of old age’, grouping Emberá residents into the class of people deserving special consideration. Afrocolombians and Emberá at the coastal site both agree on whose relative need is greater; accordingly, Afrocolombians did not show evidence of parochialism in real-world food/money transfers or in experimental exploitation decisions in the RICH taking game. Qualitative responses at the coastal community focused on objective need and carried little emotional valence.

Similarly, in the inland community, Emberá participants agreed that Emberá alters were more in need than Afrocolombians and biased giving towards other Emberá accordingly. In stark contrast to the coastal community, however, it was very common in post-game interviews for inland Emberá respondents to describe taking from alters (normally Afrocolombians) specifically because those alters had not cooperated in the past, and there was clearly more social friction and negative emotional valence than in the coastal community. Inland Emberá respondents would state that they took coins ‘because those people don't cooperate with you when you ask for help’ or because ‘you are hungry and ask for a favour and they do nothing’. Though not recorded explicitly in post-game interviews, informal conversations with Afrocolombians in the inland community suggested that inland Afrocolombians frequently viewed Emberá alters from their community as being as well off as the Emberá living in the nearby resguardo, causing them to engage in fewer inter-ethnic need-based transfers, as is clear in both the taking game and real-world food/money transfer data.

5. Discussion

The findings presented here, both quantitative and qualitative, contrast in some ways with the simbiosis cultural reported by Cayón (Reference Cayón1973). By integrating community-wide self-report and economic game data, along with qualitative debriefing interviews and standard ethnography, we have been able to build a more representative understanding of inter-group relationships in these communities. On the one hand, the characterisation of inter-group relationships as a simbiosis cultural remains valid, as direct hostilities between groups are quite rare, costly reduction was not influenced by group identity, and inter-group cooperation occurs between specific individuals on an almost daily basis. However, on the other hand, social relationship and experimental transfers do exhibit signs of within-group favouritism. Lastly, the context of inter-group interactions seems to matter, as there is evidence of preferential out-group exploitation in only one of two sites.

5.1. The cultural context of interactions: resource competition, norm differences, and demographics

In the coastal community, Afrocolombians have a larger population size, more stable land tenure, stronger local political institutions, and greater control of the means of production (i.e. fishing boats, refrigeration) than Emberá. In contrast, in the inland community on the ethnic boundary, Afrocolombians and Emberá both have substantial population sizes, stable land tenure, and more comparable bargaining power.

Although between-group resource competition is thought to be an important driver of parochialism (Bell & Moya, Reference Bell and Moya2021), direct between-group resource competition is not a central feature of the cultural context at either of these two sites. This being said, resource competition has been cited for the breakdown of inter-ethnic cooperation between these same two ethnic groups in other regions of Colombia (e.g. Ng'weno, Reference Ng'weno2000; Davis, Reference Davis2002; García, Reference García2009; Velasco, Reference Velasco2011), and there is much greater scope for such competition at the inland site where population size and institutional power are more balanced (Slack & Doyon, Reference Slack and Doyon2001; Posner, Reference Posner2004).

Likewise, the contrasting inter-group relationships at the coastal and inland sites is concordant with the predictions of some models of inter-ethnic coordination games (e.g. McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003; Advani & Reich, Reference Advani and Reich2015). These models suggest that when each group has a large enough population size, within-group interactions will occur frequently enough to maintain distinct sub-populations with their own behavioural norms (Bunce & McElreath, Reference Bunce and McElreath2017, Reference Bunce and McElreath2018). If there are greater benefits to interacting with others who share the same norms (McElreath et al., Reference McElreath, Boyd and Richerson2003), then social and resources transfer networks should appear more ethnically differentiated at the inland site. However, there is no direct ethnographic indication that norm coordination is more difficult at the inland site; in fact, across study sites and ethnic groups, there is a single widely shared norm that resource transfers should be based on relative need. What appears to differ across sites is simply who is perceived to have more need.

5.2. Perceived inequality, perceived need and inter-group relations

In both communities, formal statistical analysis and qualitative post-experiment interviews identified a key norm governing transfers: take from those who are better off and can afford it, and leave for those who are worse off and need the money more. This is a classic need-based heuristic found across a variety of cultural groups (e.g. Peterson, Reference Peterson1993; Hooper et al., Reference Hooper, Gurven and Winking2015; Aktipis et al., Reference Aktipis, De Aguiar and Flaherty2016; Hao et al., Reference Hao, Armbruster and Cronk2015; Gervais, Reference Gervais2017; Cronk et al., Reference Cronk, Berbesque and Conte2019). This need-based norm appears more salient to Colombian respondents than a norm for simply favouring in-group members.

We do note, however, that our full results are not consistent with any single norm driving transfers. First, although log-wealth and food security affected behaviour in the taking and costly reduction games in a way that was consistent with qualitative accounts (i.e. wealthier individuals were more likely to be taken from and reduced, while food insecure individuals were less likely to be taken from or reduced), behaviour in the positively valanced networks was somewhat different, with wealthier individuals being more likely to be nominated as friends and targets of resource transfers. Although need-based sharing is common, reciprocation among people with higher wealth is also common, especially in the coastal fishing community, where sharing helps to buffer stochastic fluctuations in fishing returns. In such contexts, establishment of social connections with wealthy and high-status individuals can be beneficial to a focal individual, as such connections are better able to buffer risk and improve one's socio-economic standing over long time-scales (e.g. von Rueden et al., Reference von Rueden, Redhead and O'Gorman2019).

Although the emic perspective on need-based transfers may, at first, appear to conflict with evolutionary explanations for cooperative behaviour, need-based transfers are consistent with both individual-level models of tolerated theft (Winterhalder, Reference Winterhalder1997) and group-level models of risk-pooling (Hao et al., Reference Hao, Armbruster and Cronk2015). Imbalance in the marginal fitness benefits of some unit of food, money, or other resource has the potential to lead to conflict, as a resource-poor individual may be willing to escalate their demands for a unit of resource from a resource-rich individual; at an individual-level, this dynamic can lead to need-based transfers, whereby a well-off giver shares a resource whose benefit to an impoverished receiver exceeds the cost to the giver of defending that resource (Jones, Reference Jones1984; Winterhalder, Reference Winterhalder1996, Reference Winterhalder1997; Rusch, Reference Rusch2014). At a larger scale, cultural institutions based around need-based transfers may lead to more optimal risk pooling and more resilient groups (Hao et al., Reference Hao, Armbruster and Cronk2015).

In contexts of ethnically structured inequality in wealth or power, individuals in underprivileged groups may be especially likely to direct aid to coethnics (Waring, Reference Waring2012; Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013). Although not true across all ethnic boundaries, if ethnicity and need are perceived to covary, then members of a relatively well-off ethnic group may use ethnicity as a heuristic to direct need-based transfers, attenuating the overt expression of parochialism (see also Rusch, Reference Rusch2014). In the coastal community, Emberá are a small proportion of the population and there is large between-group, but little within-group variation in wealth; ethnicity thus covaries strongly with perceived need. Coastal Afrocolombians and Emberá both recognise that the social obligation to help the needy means that resources should flow towards Emberá. In the inland community, however, district-level population sizes are more balanced, and within-group variation in wealth and status (e.g. comparing in-sample Emberá with those living on the resguardo) is higher. Here, ethnicity does not covary with perceived need and thus fails serve as an indicator that can be used to guide transfers. As such, both inland Afrocolombians and Emberá see themselves as needier, and are likely to cite need when directing resources towards members of their own groups. Our findings here echo Hewstone et al. (Reference Hewstone, Rubin and Willis2002): members of a high-status group may be likely to show magnanimity when the status gap is very wide (i.e. when it is clear to all members of both groups who is most in-need).

5.3. Rethinking the theoretical linkages between diversity and socio-cultural outcomes

Perhaps influenced by a rash of inter-ethnic and sectarian conflicts (McGarry & O'leary, Reference McGarry and O'leary2013), some social scientists in the 1990s and 2000s came to speculate that identity-group diversity might drive many adverse socio-cultural outcomes (see Patsiurko et al., Reference Patsiurko, Campbell and Hall2012, for an overview). Such arguments relied – either implicitly or explicitly – on assumptions of parochial altruism, i.e. that individuals in a particular group will cooperate amongst themselves, while competing with other groups, in turn causing more internal discord in territories where identity-group diversity is high.

Reviewing the economics and political science literature, Patsiurko et al. (Reference Patsiurko, Campbell and Hall2012), found that the effects of cultural homogeneity vs. diversity on socio-cultural outcomes were explored in studies of national economic success (Easterly & Levine, Reference Easterly and Levine1997), provisioning of public goods (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Baqir and Easterly1999; Habyarimana et al., Reference Habyarimana, Humphreys and Posner2009), nationalist insurgencies (Cederman & Girardin, Reference Cederman and Girardin2007), civil wars (Fearon et al., Reference Fearon, Kasara and Laitin2007; Wimmer et al., Reference Wimmer, Cederman and Min2009; Cederman et al., Reference Cederman, Wimmer and Min2010), and war crimes (Slack & Doyon, Reference Slack and Doyon2001), among other topics. In these studies, diversity is indeed frequently found to be correlated with adverse socio-cultural outcomes (e.g. higher conflict rates, lower public goods provisioning, or more frequent war crimes) in aggregate-level data, but such findings are not universal (e.g. see Ottaviano & Peri, Reference Ottaviano and Peri2006).

In a similar review of the organisational studies literature, Waring and Bell (Reference Waring and Bell2013) found that ethnic diversity was frequently associated with reduced cooperation at both a community (e.g. Banerjee et al., Reference Banerjee, Iyer and Somanathan2005; Miguel & Gugerty, Reference Miguel and Gugerty2005; Ruttan, Reference Ruttan2006; Bardhan et al., Reference Bardhan, Baland, Bowles and et al2007) and interpersonal level (e.g. Williams & O'Reilly III, Reference Williams and O'Reilly1998; Pitts & Jarry, Reference Pitts and Jarry2007; Hur, Reference Hur2013; Pelled et al., Reference Pelled, Eisenhardt and Xin1999; Watson et al., Reference Watson, Kumar and Michaelsen1993). Waring and Bell (Reference Waring and Bell2013) note, however, that this literature is also not monolithic, and that evidence is often mixed or varied, with diversity sometimes having positive effects on socio-cultural outcomes (e.g. informational diversity can improve group performance in complex tasks; Jehn et al., Reference Jehn, Northcraft and Neale1999).

Increasingly, researchers (e.g. Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013; Wimmer et al., Reference Wimmer, Cederman and Min2009) are beginning to argue that one must be careful to distinguish correlations between diversity and socio-cultural outcomes, from causal effects of diversity on such outcomes – especially in cases where studies are based on non-experimental, ecological regression designs. Analyses of aggregate-level variables are often subject to confounding (Wakefield, Reference Wakefield2004; Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013) and spurious associations have been used as rhetorical justification for everything from arcane legal policies to direct violence (Patsiurko et al., Reference Patsiurko, Campbell and Hall2012; McGarry & O'leary, Reference McGarry and O'leary2013). Our finer-scale findings, much like those of Waring and Bell (Reference Waring and Bell2013), serve to question the idea that parochialism is ubiquitous; instead it appears to be context dependent and linked to perceptions of between-group differences in socio-economic status.

In addition to the potential validity concerns inherent in ecological regression designs, there are also potential issues related to sample selection bias. Fearon and Laitin (Reference Fearon and Laitin1996: 716), for example, note that much of the research on intergroup relations focuses on cases of between-group conflict, essentially selecting on the dependent variable and making such conflict seem ubiquitous: ‘violence is assumed to follow ethnic tensions as night follows day’. Moreover, ‘the salience and extremity of intergroup hostility’ to researchers can lead to a literature in which ‘the study of intergroup relations is equivalent to the study of intergroup conflict’ (Brewer, Reference Brewer, Baumeister and Finkel2010: 535). Our methods, if deployed broadly across a representative sample of cultural groups (e.g. study sites not selected on the basis of inter-group conflict), would permit a more accurate estimate of the prevalence of parochial altruism. While there are many between-group boundaries at which conflict could take place, the fraction of boundaries where conflict actually does take place appears to be much smaller (Fearon & Laitin, Reference Fearon and Laitin1996).

In light of such issues, we argue that more precision is needed when discussing the mechanisms through which identity-group diversity may be linked to adverse socio-cultural outcomes. Alesina and Ferrara (Reference Alesina and Ferrara2005: 762), for example, frame their work as exploring the costs and benefits of diversity on socio-cultural outcomes, stating:

The potential costs of diversity are fairly evident. Conflict of preferences, racism, and prejudices often lead to policies that are at the same time odious and counterproductive for society as a whole. The oppression of minorities may lead to political unrest or even civil wars. But a diverse ethnic mix also brings about variety in abilities, experiences, and cultures that may be productive and may lead to innovation and creativity.

However, it is notable that while conflicting preferences, racism, prejudice, and oppression of minorities might all serve as causes of adverse socio-cultural outcomes, none of these variables are essential characteristics of a diverse society. Thus, it is important that when researchers consider the policy implications of their work, they focus attention on the relevant variables – that is, if researchers believe racial biases or unfair social structures that oppress minorities to be fundamental causes of political unrest, then they should focus precisely on those variables, rather that referencing ‘diversity’ more broadly.

The fact that there might be more scope for prejudice in more diverse locations does not imply that diversity per se has costs, and – in fact – if diversity carries positively externalities (as Alesina and Ferrara, Reference Alesina and Ferrara2005 suggest), then diverse societies may be especially successful when formal and informal structures of racism, prejudice and oppression are attenuated – e.g., see Jha (Reference Jha2013) on the mutual benefits conferred by inter-group trade. Beheim and Bell (Reference Beheim and Bell2024) formalise this idea, and show that diversity can increase group-beneficial outcomes over a range of interaction payoff structures, especially interactions featuring complementarities between actors.

5.3.1. The value of social networks and network-structured economic games for studying human behaviour cross-culturally

By deploying robust, mixed-methods research protocols that integrate social network data, an informative set of dyadic economic games, and qualitative post-game interviews, we were able to measure in-group favouritism separately from out-group exploitation or animus (Pisor & Ross, Reference Pisor and Ross2023). This methodologically pluralistic approach has allowed us to cross-check our inferences and show that our findings are not reducible to artefacts of a single method of data collection. Likewise, our methods allow us to control for a suite of important focal, alter, and dyadic covariates that might confound estimates of the effects of ethnicity on in-group favouritism; we show that our statistical findings are robust to such controls. Within sites, triangulation across methods and consideration of confounding factors helps to establish internal validity (Pisor & Ross, Reference Pisor and Ross2022; Pisor et al., Reference Pisor, Gervais and Purzycki2020).

Additionally, our methods facilitate standardised comparisons between sites, opening the door to tests of generalisability (Tiokhin et al., Reference Tiokhin, Hackman and Munira2019) and assessments of the site-level drivers of parochial altruism. By replicating our study design across two ethnic groups at two sites, we are able to comment on the (lack of) generalisability in expression of parochial altruism (especially the out-group animus component) within the Pacific region of rural Colombia. The paucity of out-group exploitation by coastal Afrocolombians appears to be driven by perceptions of need and by norms for basing transfers on need. However, wider-scale, standardised, cross-cultural assessments are still needed to assess the extent of variation in parochial altruism, as well its causes and consequences.

In this study, we have been limited to studying average, site-level, differences in expression of parochial altruism. However, Figure 4 suggests that there are also substantial individual-level differences in expression of parochial altruism within sites. For example, even at the inland site – where parochialism was higher on average – we found that a substantial fraction of the Afrocolombian population left coins for the ethnic out-group at higher rates than the ethnic in-group. We hypothesise that this variation will be related to individual heterogeneity in residential patterns, rates of between-group social network connections, and ultimately dyad-level perceptions of economic need. That is, we expect Afrocolombians with social network ties to Emberá individuals, and even Afrocolombians living near Emberá households, to have better awareness of the true economic need of in-sample Emberá families, and thus be less parochial. In future work, we aim to measure perceptions of socio-economic status at the dyad level in order to test this idea.

5.4. Conclusions

In this paper, we sought to explore the extent to which parochial altruism may vary as a function of local socio-ecological context. Our findings are consistent with a growing body of literature suggesting that parochial altruism is not ubiquitous (e.g. see Purzycki & Lang, Reference Purzycki and Lang2019; Hruschka & Henrich, Reference Hruschka and Henrich2013; Yamagishi & Mifune, Reference Yamagishi and Mifune2016; Brewer & Caporael, Reference Brewer and Caporael2006; Schaub, Reference Schaub2017; Cashdan, Reference Cashdan2001; de Dreu et al., Reference de Dreu, Balliet and Halevy2014; Böhm et al., Reference Böhm, Rusch and Baron2020; Balliet et al., Reference Balliet, Wu and De Dreu2014; Abbink et al., Reference Abbink, Brandts and Herrmann2012; Pisor & Ross, Reference Pisor and Ross2023), and that the context of between-group interaction can strongly impact whether cooperation breaks down in more diverse communities (Waring & Bell, Reference Waring and Bell2013; Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Michalopoulos and Papaioannou2016) or whether norms and institutions emerge in order to reap the potential benefits of between-group connections (Jha, Reference Jha2013; Bunce, Reference Bunce2021; Glowacki, Reference Glowacki2022). While there is certainly scope for conflict in diverse societies, such adverse outcomes can probably be attenuated by minimising the structural biases that trigger perceptions of unequal status or unfair treatment.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2024.43.

Acknowledgements

We thank both communities for their time and continued collaboration, Arlenys Hurtado Manyoma for assistance with data collection and Ronny Barr for assistance with preparation of the photograph rosters for the RICH games. Sam Bowles, Patrick Barclay, and several anonymous reviewers provided helpful feedback on this manuscript. The research project benefited from outstanding secretarial support from the Department of Human, Behavior, Ecology and Cultural at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology.

Author contributions

C.T.R. conceived and designed the study. C.T.R. conducted fieldwork and performed statistical analyses. C.T.R. and A.P. wrote the article.

Financial support

This research was made possible by financial support from the Department of Human Behavior, Ecology and Culture at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary Anthropology.

Conflicts of interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Research transparency, reproducibility and data availability

Code and data for diagnostics and analysis replication are provided in the Supplementary Materials and will be maintained on GitHub at: www.github.com/ctross/parochialism_and_inequality

References

Abbink, K., Brandts, J., Herrmann, B. et al. (2012). Parochial altruism in inter-group conflicts. Economics Letters, 117, 4548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Advani, A. & Reich, B. (2015). Melting pot or salad bowl: The formation of heterogeneous communities. IFS Working Papers.Google Scholar
Aktipis, A., De Aguiar, R., Flaherty, A. et al. (2016). Cooperation in an uncertain world. Human Ecology, 44, 353364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. & Ferrara, E. L. (2005). Ethnic diversity and economic performance. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 762800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Baqir, R. & Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 12431284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Michalopoulos, S. & Papaioannou, E. (2016). Ethnic inequality. Journal of Political Economy, 124, 428488.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baerveldt, C., Zijlstra, B., De Wolf, M. et al. (2007). Ethnic boundaries in high school students’ networks in Flanders and the Netherlands. International Sociology, 22, 701720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balliet, D., Wu, J. & De Dreu, C. K. W. (2014). Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 140, 15561581.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Balliet, D., Tybur, J. M. & Van Lange, P. A. (2017). Functional interdependence theory: An Evolutionary account of social situations. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 21, 361388.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Banerjee, A., Iyer, L. & Somanathan, R. (2005). History, social divisions, and public goods in rural India. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3, 639647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bapat, N. A. & Bond, K. D. (2012). Alliances between militant groups. British Journal of Political Science, 42, 793824.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, P. K., Baland, J.-M., Bowles, S., et al, . (2007). Inequality, cooperation, and environmental sustainability. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Beheim, B. A. & Bell, A. V. (2024). Why cultural distance can promote – or impede – group-beneficial outcomes. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 6, e14.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bell, A. & Moya, C. (2021). Evolution of outgroup aversion within and across territories. Working paper: University of Utah.Google Scholar
Bell, A. V., Richerson, P. J. & McElreath, R. (2009). Culture rather than genes provides greater scope for the evolution of large-scale human prosociality. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106, 1767117674.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benson Latin American Collection (1779–1852). Collection of manuscripts relating to slavery in Colombia, 1779–1852. University of Texas Libraries.Google Scholar
Benzell, S. G. & Cooke, K. (2021). A network of thrones: Kinship and conflict in Europe, 1495–1918. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 13, 102–33.Google Scholar
Bøggild, T. & Petersen, M. B. (2016). The evolved functions of procedural fairness: An adaptation for politics. In Shackelford, T. K., & Hansen, R. D. (Eds.), The evolution of morality (pp. 247276). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhm, R., Rusch, H. & Baron, J. (2020). The psychology of intergroup conflict. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 178, 947962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. (2008). Conflict: Altruism's midwife. Nature, 456, 326327.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bowles, S. & Gintis, H. (2004). Persistent parochialism: Trust and exclusion in ethnic networks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55, 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, M. B. (2010). Intergroup Relations. In Baumeister, R. F., & Finkel, E. J. (Eds.), Advanced social psychology: The state of the science (pp. 535571). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Brewer, M. B. & Caporael, L. R. (2006). An evolutionary perspective on social identity. Evolution and Social Psychology, 143, 161.Google Scholar
Brustein, W. I. & King, R. D. (2004). Anti-semitism in Europe before the Holocaust. International Political Science Review, 25, 3553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunce, J. A. (2021). Cultural diversity in unequal societies sustained through cross-cultural competence and identity valuation. Humanities and Social Sciences Communications, 8, 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunce, J. A. & McElreath, R. (2017). Interethnic interaction, strategic bargaining power, and the dynamics of cultural norms. Human Nature, 28, 434456.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bunce, J. A. & McElreath, R. (2018). Sustainability of minority culture when inter-ethnic interaction is profitable. Nature Human Behaviour, 2, 205212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantor, E. (2000). Ni Aniquilados, Ni Vencidos. Bogota: Instituto Colombiano de Antropología e Historia.Google Scholar
Cashdan, E. (2001). Ethnocentrism and xenophobia: A cross-cultural study. Current anthropology, 42, 760764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castillo, S. S. & Abril, N. G. P. (2009). Discourse and racism in Colombia. In van Dijk, T. A. (Ed.), Racism and discourse in Latin America (pp. 131170). New York: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Cayón, E. (1973). Estudios Sobre El Groupo Indigena Chamí (volume 2). Bogota: Biblioteca Banco de la Republica.Google Scholar
Cederman, L.-E. & Girardin, L. (2007). Beyond fractionalization: Mapping ethnicity onto nationalist insurgencies. American Political Science Review, 101, 173185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cederman, L.-E., Wimmer, A. & Min, B. (2010). Why do ethnic groups rebel? New data and analysis. World Politics, 62, 87119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, J.-K. & Bowles, S. (2007). The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science, 318, 636640.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clark, N. & Worger, W. (2013). South Africa: The rise and fall of apartheid. Routledge.Google Scholar
Clark, C. J., Liu, B. S., Winegard, B. M. et al. (2019). Tribalism is human nature. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 28, 587592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cronk, L., Berbesque, C., Conte, T. et al. (2019). Managing risk through cooperation. In Global perspectives on long term community resource management (pp. 4175). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dagdelen, S., Hänsel, H., Nastic, Z. et al. (2021). Keine reparationszahlungen durch die bundesregierung an Namibia für völkermord im rahmen des versöhnungsabkommens. Deutscher Bundestag.Google Scholar
DANE, (2005). Census de Colombia. https://www.dane.gov.coGoogle Scholar
Davis, S. H. (2002). Indigenous peoples, poverty and participatory development. In Multiculturalism in Latin America (pp. 227251). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Dreu, C. K., Balliet, D. & Halevy, N. (2014). Parochial cooperation in humans. In Advances in motivation science (volume 1, pp. 147). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Dunbar, R. I. M. (2008). Cognitive constraints on the structure and dynamics of social networks. Group Dynamics: Theory, Research, and Practice, 12, 716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W. & Levine, R. (1997). Africa's growth tragedy: Policies and ethnic divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, (pp. 12031250).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eberhard, D. M., Simons, G. F. & Fennig, C. D. (2021). How many languages are there in the world? Ethnologue: Languages of the world (24th ed.). Dallas, TX: SIL International.Google Scholar
Erichsen, C. & Olusoga, D. (2010). The Kaiser's Holocaust: Germany's forgotten genocide and the colonial roots of Nazism. Faber & Faber.Google Scholar
Escobar, A. (2003). Displacement, development, and modernity in the Colombian Pacific. International Social Science Journal, 55, 157167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. (2003). Ethnic and cultural diversity by country. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 195222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D. & Laitin, D. D. (1996). Explaining interethnic cooperation. American Political Science Review, 90, 715735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, J. D., Kasara, K. & Laitin, D. D. (2007). Ethnic minority rule and civil war onset. American Political Science Review, 101, 187193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiske, S. T., Dupree, C. H., Nicolas, G. et al. (2016). Status, power, and intergroup relations: The personal is the societal. Current Opinion in Psychology, 11, 4448.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fogelman, E. (2011). Conscience and courage: Rescuers of Jews during the Holocaust. Anchor.Google Scholar
Fontana, L. (2014). The ‘indigenous native peasant’ trinity. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 32, 518534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabry, J., Simpson, D., Vehtari, A. et al. (2019). Visualization in Bayesian workflow. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A, 182, 389402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galston, W. A. (1993). Cosmopolitan altruism. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10, 118134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García, J. J. R. (2009). Diversos y comunes. Análisis Político, 22, 5393.Google Scholar
Geertz, C. (1973). The interpretation of cultures. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Gervais, M. M. (2017). RICH economic games for networked relationships and communities. Field Methods, 29, 113129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gervais, M. M. & Fessler, D. M. (2017). On the deep structure of social affect: Attitudes, emotions, sentiments, and the case of ‘contempt’. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 40, e225.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Glowacki, L. (2022). The evolution of peace. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 47, e1.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Habyarimana, J., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. N. et al. (2009). Coethnicity: Diversity and the dilemmas of collective action. Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Hao, Y., Armbruster, D., Cronk, L. et al. (2015). Need-based transfers on a network. Evolution and Human Behavior, 36, 265273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haslam, N. (2006). Dehumanization: An integrative review. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 10, 252264.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J. & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige: freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior, 22, 165196.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hewstone, M., Rubin, M. & Willis, H. (2002). Intergroup bias. Annual Review in Psychology, 53, 575604.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hooper, P. L., Gurven, M., Winking, J. et al. (2015). Inclusive fitness and differential productivity across the life course determine intergenerational transfers in a small-scale human society. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 282, 20142808.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hruschka, D. J. & Henrich, J. (2013). Economic and evolutionary hypotheses for cross-population variation in parochialism. Frontiers in Human Neuroscience, 7, 559.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Huber, J. D. & Mayoral, L. (2019). Group inequality and the severity of civil conflict. Journal of Economic Growth, 24, pp. 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunter, P. (2014). A growing collection of over 43,870 adherent statistics and religious geography citations. Adherents.com, National & World Religion Statistics.Google Scholar
Hur, Y. (2013). Racial diversity, is it a blessing to an organization? Examining its organizational consequences in municipal police departments. International Review of Administrative Sciences, 79, 149164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ibáñez, A. M. (2009). Forced displacement in Colombia. The Economics of Peace and Security Journal, 4(1), 4854.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iglesias, A. I. R. (2018). Las voces étnicas en el Acuerdo de Paz de Colombia. Relaciones Internacionales, 39, 165183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jehn, K. A., Northcraft, G. B. & Neale, M. A. (1999). Why differences make a difference: A field study of diversity, conflict and performance in workgroups. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44, 741763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jha, S. (2013). Trade, institutions, and ethnic tolerance: Evidence from South Asia. American Political Science Review, 107, 806832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, N. B. (1984). A selfish origin for human food sharing: Tolerated theft. Ethology and Sociobiology, 5, 13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenny, D. A. & La Voie, L. (1984). The social relations model. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 18, 142182.Google Scholar
Koster, J. M. & Leckie, G. (2014). Food sharing networks in lowland Nicaragua: An application of the social relations model to count data. Social Networks, 38, 100110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koster, J., Leckie, G. & Aven, B. (2019). Statistical methods and software for the multilevel social relations model. Field Methods, 1525822X19889011.Google Scholar
Lawson, D. W., James, S., Ngadaya, E. et al. (2015). No evidence that polygynous marriage is a harmful cultural practice in northern Tanzania. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112, 1382713832.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lindsay, B. C. (2012). Murder state: California's Native American genocide, 1846–1873. University of Nebraska Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lustick, I. S. (2013). What counts is the counting: Statistical manipulation as a solution to Israel's ‘demographic problem’. The Middle East Journal, 67, 185205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madley, B. (2016). An American genocide. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Magnarella, P. J. (2005). The background and causes of the genocide in Rwanda. Journal of International Criminal Justice, 3, 801822.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElreath, R. (2016). Statistical rethinking. CRC Press.Google Scholar
McElreath, R., Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. (2003). Shared norms and the evolution of ethnic markers. Current Anthropology, 44, 122130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGarry, J. & O'leary, B. (2013). The politics of ethnic conflict regulation: Case studies of protracted ethnic conflicts. Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miguel, E. & Gugerty, M. K. (2005). Ethnic diversity, social sanctions, and public goods in Kenya. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 23252368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moffett, M. W. (2013). Human identity and the evolution of societies. Human Nature, 24, 219267.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Montalvo, J. G. & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005). Ethnic polarization, potential conflict, and civil wars. American Economic Review, 95, 796816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moya, C. & Boyd, R. (2015). Different selection pressures give rise to distinct ethnic phenomena. Human Nature, 26, 127.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Murillo Urrutia, L. G. (2015). El Chocó: The African heart of Colombia. Journal of Pan African Studies, 8, 256260.Google Scholar
Ng'weno, B. (2000). On titling collective property, participation, and natural resource management. Working paper: World Bank, pp 183.Google Scholar
Ossa, H., Aquino, J., Pereira, R. et al. (2016). Outlining the ancestry landscape of Colombian admixed populations. PLoS One, 11, e0164414.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ottaviano, G. I. & Peri, G. (2006). The economic value of cultural diversity: Evidence from US cities. Journal of Economic Geography, 6, 944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oyola, S. M. R. (2015). Religion, social memory and conflict: The massacre of Bojayá in Colombia. Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patsiurko, N., Campbell, J. L. & Hall, J. A. (2012). Measuring cultural diversity: Ethnic, linguistic and religious fractionalization in the OECD. Ethnic and Racial Studies, 35, 195217.Google Scholar
Pelled, L. H., Eisenhardt, K. M. & Xin, K. R. (1999). Exploring the black box: An analysis of work group diversity, conflict and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44, 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, N. (1993). Demand sharing: Reciprocity and the pressure for generosity among foragers. American Anthropologist, 95, 860874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piantadosi, S., Byar, D. P. & Green, S. B. (1988). The ecological fallacy. American Journal of Epidemiology, 127, 893904.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pietraszewski, D. (2021). Towards a computational theory of social groups: A finite set of cognitive primitives for representing any and all social groups in the context of conflict. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 45, e97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinker, S. (2011). The better angels of our nature: The decline of violence in history and its causes. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Pisor, A. C. & Ross, C. T. (2022). Distinguishing intergroup and long-distance relationships. Human Nature, 33, 280303.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pisor, A. C. & Ross, C. T. (2023). Parochial altruism: What it is and why it varies. Evolution and Human Behavior, 45(1), 212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pisor, A. C., Gervais, M. M., Purzycki, B. et al. (2020). Preferences and constraints. Royal Society Open Science, 7, 192090.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pitts, D. & Jarry, E. (2007). Ethnic diversity and organizational performance: Assessing diversity effects at the managerial and street levels. International Public Management Journal, 10, 233254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, D. N. (2004). The political salience of cultural difference. American Political Science Review, 98(4), 529545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Power, E. A. (2017). Social support networks and religiosity in rural South India. Nature Human Behaviour, 1, 0057.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Purzycki, B. G. & Lang, M. (2019). Identity fusion, outgroup relations, and sacrifice: A cross-cultural test. Cognition, 186, 16.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
R Core Team (2021). R: A language and environment for statistical computing. V. 4.0.5. R Foundation for Statistical Computing Vienna.Google Scholar
Redhead, D. & von Rueden, C. R. (2021). Coalitions and conflict: A longitudinal analysis of men's politics. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 3, e31.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Redhead, D., Dalla Ragione, A. & Ross, C. T. (2023). Friendship and partner choice in rural colombia. Evolution and Human Behavior, 44, 430441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richerson, P., Baldini, R., Bell, A. V. et al. (2016). Cultural group selection plays an essential role in explaining human cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 39, e30.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Riek, B. M., Mania, E. W. & Gaertner, S. L. (2006). Intergroup threat and outgroup attitudes: A meta-analytic review. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 10, 336353.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ross, C. T. & Redhead, D.. (2021). DieTryin: An R package for data collection, automated data entry, and post-processing of network-structured economic games, social networks, and other roster-based dyadic data. Behavior Research Methods, 54, 121.Google Scholar
Ross, C. T. & Redhead, D. (2023). Automatic entry and coding of social networks and dyadic peer ratings. Methodological Innovations, 20597991231160281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, C. T. & Winterhalder, B. (2016). A hierarchical Bayesian analysis of parasite prevalence and sociocultural outcomes: The role of structural racism and sanitation infrastructure. American Journal of Human Biology, 28, 7489.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ross, C. T., Campino, P.J. & Winterhalder, B. (2015). Frequency-dependent social transmission and the interethnic transfer of female genital modification in the African diaspora and indigenous populations of Colombia. Human Nature, 26, 351377.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rothbart, D. & Cooley, J. (2016). Hutus aiding Tutsis during the Rwandan genocide: Motives, meanings and morals. Genocide Studies and Prevention, 10, 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rusch, H. (2014). The two sides of warfare: An extended model of altruistic behavior in ancestral human intergroup conflict. Human Nature, 25, 359377.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ruttan, L. M. (2006). Sociocultural heterogeneity and the commons. Current Anthropology, 47, 843853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarkin, J. & Fowler, C. (2008). Reparations for historical human rights violations: The international and historical dimensions of the Alien Torts Claims Act genocide case of the Herero of Namibia. Human Rights Review, 9, 331360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schaub, M. (2017). Threat and parochialism in intergroup relations: Lab-in-the-field evidence from rural Georgia. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 284, 20171560.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seabright, P. (2004). The company of strangers. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Shimoni, G.. (1988). South African Jews and the Apartheid Crisis. The American Jewish Year Book, 88, 358.Google Scholar
Sidanius, J. & Protto, F. (2001). Social dominance: An intergroup theory of social hierarchy and oppression. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Slack, J. A. & Doyon, R. R. (2001). Population dynamics and susceptibility for ethnic conflict: The case of bosnia and herzegovina. Journal of Peace Research, 38, 139161.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stan Development Team (2020). RStan: The R interface to Stan. R package version 2.21.2.Google Scholar
Stulp, G., Kordsmeyer, T., Buunk, A. P. et al. (2012). Increased aggression during human group contests when competitive ability is more similar. Biology Letters, 8, 921923.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tiokhin, L., Hackman, J., Munira, S. et al. (2019). Generalizability is not optional: Insights from a cross-cultural study of social discounting. Royal Society Open Science, 6, 181386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turchin, P. & Gavrilets, S. (2009). Evolution of complex hierarchical societies. Social Evolution and History, 8, 167198.Google Scholar
Velasco, M. (2011). Contested territoriality. Bulletin of Latin American Research, 30, 213228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Rueden, C. R., Redhead, D., O'Gorman, R. et al. (2019). The dynamics of men's cooperation and social status in a small-scale society. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 286, 20191367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, P. (2002). The Colombian Pacific in perspective. Journal of Latin American Anthropology, 7, 233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wakefield, J. (2003). Sensitivity analyses for ecological regression. Biometrics, 59, 917.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wakefield, J. (2004). A critique of statistical aspects of ecological studies in spatial epidemiology. Environmental and Ecological Statistics, 11, 3154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waring, T. M. (2012). Cooperation dynamics in a multiethnic society. Current Anthropology, 53, 642649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waring, T. M. & Bell, A. V. (2013). Ethnic dominance damages cooperation more than ethnic diversity. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34, 398404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watson, W. E., Kumar, K. & Michaelsen, L. K. (1993). Cultural diversity's impact on interaction process and performance: Comparing homogeneous and diverse task groups. Academy of Management Journal, 36, 590602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, D. J. & Strogatz, S. H. (1998). Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature, 393, 440442.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
White, B. & Zoabi, H. (2012). Palestinians in Israel: Segregation, discrimination and democracy. London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
Williams, K. Y. & O'Reilly, C. A. III (1998). Demography and diversity in organizations: A review of 40 years of research. Research in Organizational Behavior, 20, 77140.Google Scholar
Wimmer, A., Cederman, L.-E. & Min, B. (2009). Ethnic politics and armed conflict: A configurational analysis of a new global data set. American Sociological Review, 74, 316337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winterhalder, B. (1996). A marginal model of tolerated theft. Ethology and Sociobiology, 17, 3753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winterhalder, B. (1997). Gifts given, gifts taken. Journal of Archaeological Research, 5, 121168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wrangham, R. W. & Glowacki, L. (2012). Intergroup aggression in chimpanzees and war in nomadic hunter–gatherers. Human Nature, 23, 529.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yamagishi, T. & Mifune, N. (2016). Parochial altruism. Current Opinion in Psychology, 7, 3943.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zefferman, M. R. & Mathew, S. (2015). An evolutionary theory of large-scale human warfare: Group-structured cultural selection. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 24, 5061.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Figure 1. Mirror-histograms of log wealth by site and ethnic group (Afrocolombians in blue, Emberá in goldenrod). In both sites, Afrocolombians have higher average wealth than Emberá. However, even though there is less wealth overlap at the inland site, it is common for Afrocolombians there to perceive Emberá as being comparably well off, largely because they overgeneralise based on the economic status of Emberá living in the nearby resguardo.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Network data. Afrocolombians are plotted in blue and Emberá in goldenrod. Quantitative estimates of assortment metrics can be found in Figure 3. The exploitation/taking game data are dense; ties represent coins left for alters, i.e. non-exploitative ties.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Multinomial regression results (standardised coefficients) from the Social Relations Model. Points and line-ranges show the standardised effects of predictor variables on outcomes (as medians and 90% credible intervals). When the credible intervals exclude the value of zero (plotted as a dashed vertical line), there is evidence of a reliable effect. Each column indicates an independently modeled outcome variable: (i) friendship/socialising ties, (ii) food/money transfers; (iii) coin allocations in the allocation game; (iv) coin deductions in the taking game (coded so that positive parameter estimates reflect leaving coins); and (v) coins paid to reduce alters in the costly reduction game. For each of these outcomes in each community, we fit two models: both included the predictors directly related to parochial altruism (e.g. as in row 4), but the first (NC; no controls) excluded control variables – that is, the predictors in all other rows – and the second included all controls. The key estimates of interest are shown in the ‘Parochial’ row. For example, in the allocation game, both Afrocolombian and Emberá individuals (in both sites) showed a reliably positive tendency to give more to co-ethnics. Likewise, in the taking game, Emberá individuals, as well as inland Afrocolombian individuals, showed a reliably positive tendency to leave more for co-ethnics. However, coastal Afrocolombian individuals showed a reliable tendency to leave more for the ethnic out-group (model with no controls; light blue) or no tendency for preferential out-group exploitation (model with controls; dark blue).

Figure 3

Figure 4. Scatterplots of the raw taking game data by site. Each point represents an individual, with the x-coordinate reflecting the in-group coin leaving rate and the y-coordinate reflecting the out-group coin leaving rate. Individuals in the upper-right corner of the plot showed indiscriminate charity, and refused to exploit others. Individuals in the lower-left indiscriminately took from all others. Individuals above the diagonal line showed a preference for leaving coins for the ethnic out-group at higher rates than the ethnic in-group, and vice versa for the individuals below the diagonal line. Extensive individual-level heterogeneity is apparent. At the coastal site, most Afrocolombians exhibit a preference to avoid taking from the out-group at a higher rate than the in-group. In contrast, at the inland site, the majority of individuals took from the ethnic out-group at higher rates.

Supplementary material: File

Ross and Pisor supplementary material

Ross and Pisor supplementary material
Download Ross and Pisor supplementary material(File)
File 1.8 MB