Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T11:14:29.488Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Explaining the first Industrial Revolution: two views

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 December 2010

NICHOLAS CRAFTS*
Affiliation:
University of Warwick, [email protected]
Get access

Abstract

This review article looks at the recent books on the British Industrial Revolution by Robert Allen and Joel Mokyr. Both writers seek to explain Britain's primacy. This article offers a critical but sympathetic account of the main arguments of the two authors, considering both the economic logic and the empirical validity of their rival claims. In each case, the ideas are promising but the evidence base seems in need of further support. It may be that eventually these explanations for British economic leadership at the turn of the nineteenth century are recognized as complementary rather than competing.

Type
Review Article
Copyright
Copyright © European Historical Economics Society 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramovitz, M. and David, P. (2001). Two centuries of American macroeconomic growth: from exploitation of resource abundance to knowledge-driven development. Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper no. 01–05.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 69, pp. 781809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2009). When does labor scarcity encourage innovation? NBER Working Paper no. 14809.Google Scholar
Adams, D. R. (1970). Some evidence on English and American wage rates, 1790–1830. Journal of Economic History 30, pp. 499520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992). Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009a). The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009b). Engels’ pause: technical change, capital accumulation, and inequality in the British Industrial Revolution. Explorations in Economic History 46, pp. 418–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashton, T. S. (1948). The Industrial Revolution, 17601830. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Baten, J. and van Zanden, J.-L. (2008). Book production and the onset of modern economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 13, pp. 217–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bessen, J. (2003). Technology and learning by factory workers: the stretch-out at Lowell, 1842. Journal of Economic History 63, pp. 3364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bogart, D. and Richardson, G. (2008). Institutional adaptability and economic development: the property rights revolution in Britain, 1700–1830. NBER Working Paper no. 13757.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. and Gupta, B. (2009). Lancashire, India, and shifting competitive advantage in cotton textiles, 1700–1850: the neglected role of factor prices. Economic History Review 62, pp. 279305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cain, P. J. and Hopkins, A. G. (1993). British Imperialism: Innovation and Expansion 1688–1914. London: Longman.Google Scholar
Capie, F. (2004). Money and economic development in eighteenth-century England. In de la Escosura, L. Prados (ed.), Exceptionalism and Industrialisation: Britain and Its European Rivals, 1688–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carlin, W. and Soskice, D. (2006). Macroeconomics: Imperfections, Institutions and Policies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Casson, M. (2009). The World's First Railway System: Enterprise, Competition, and Regulation on the Railway Network in Victorian Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, G. (2007). A Farewell to Alms. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cottrell, P. L. (1980). Industrial Finance, 1830–1914. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Crouzet, F. (1990). Britain Ascendant: Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
David, P. A. (1975). Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Foreman-Peck, J. S. (1987). Natural monopoly and railway policy in the nineteenth century. Oxford Economic Papers 39, pp. 699718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2005). From stagnation to growth: Unified Growth Theory. In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Habakkuk, H. J. (1962). American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1932). The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jeremy, D. J. (1973). British textile technology transmission to the United States: the Philadelphia region experience, 1770–1820. Business History Review 47, pp. 2452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, W. and Brush, T. (1985). The ‘Horndal effect’ in early US manufacturing. Explorations in Economic History 22, pp. 5396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindert, P. H. (2009). Revealing failures in the history of school finance. NBER Working Paper no. 15491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macleod, C. (1988). Inventing the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathias, P. (1979). The Transformation of England. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
McKeown, T. J. (1989). The politics of Corn Law repeal and theories of commercial policy. British Journal of Political Science 19, pp. 353–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLean, I. and Bustani, C. (1999). Irish potatoes and British politics: interests, ideology, heresthetic and the repeal of the Corn Laws. Political Studies 47, pp. 817–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1990). The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2002). The Gifts of Athena. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2009). The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Musson, A. E. and Robinson, E. (1969). Science and Technology in the Industrial Revolution. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P. (1973). The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History 49, pp. 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1997). TFPG controversies, institutions and economic performance in East Asia. CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, W. D. (1992). The structure of wealth-holding in Britain, 1809–1839: a preliminary anatomy. Historical Research 65, pp. 7489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salter, W. E. G. (1960). Productivity and Technical Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schonhardt-Bailey, C. (2003). Ideology, party and interests in the British Parliament of 1841–47. British Journal of Political Science 33, pp. 581605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, P. (2001). How much did the Liberty shipbuilders learn? New evidence for an old case study. Journal of Political Economy 109, pp. 103–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zeira, J. (1998). Workers, machines and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, pp. 10911113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar