Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T06:58:36.212Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Partisan districting and the adoption of proportional representation: gerrymandering and its discontents

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 August 2023

Patrick Emmenegger*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of St. Gallen, St. Gallen, Switzerland
André Walter
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland
*
Corresponding author: Patrick Emmenegger; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Electoral engineering strategies in majoritarian electoral systems, in particular the possibility to contain insurgent parties by manipulating electoral districts for partisan gain, are key determinants of parties’ positions on the adoption of proportional representation (PR). Providing both qualitative and quantitative evidence, this paper demonstrates that partisan districting can be an effective strategy to protect incumbent parties’ dominant political positions. In addition, it shows how insurgent parties push for the adoption of PR to end the practice of partisan districting. Finally, it demonstrates that incumbents – in the face of increasing electoral threats – cling to the existing majoritarian system if partisan districting allows them to influence vote-seat distortions in their favor. Together, these findings suggest that the possibility to contain insurgent parties by means of partisan districting is an important but overlooked alternative to the adoption of PR. Moreover, by demonstrating that vote-seat distortions moderate the relationship between district-level electoral threats and legislators’ support for PR adoption, this paper offers an important corrective to Stein Rokkan’s influential electoral threat thesis.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of European Consortium for Political Research

Introduction

On June 6, 1884, three Swiss Conservatives submitted a parliamentary motion, demanding changes to the electoral district map or, alternatively, the adoption of proportional representation (PR) (Kölz, Reference Kölz2004: 639–640). The motion featured, at first sight, a surprising connection of reforms. For a long time already, the Conservatives had been accusing the politically dominant Liberals of resorting to partisan districting to obtain advantages in parliamentary representation at their expense. The demand to change the district map reflected this criticism. Should the Liberals refuse this demand, the Conservatives requested the adoption of an electoral system they believed to be less prone to manipulation, PR. Hence, for these Conservatives, there was a direct link between partisan districting and electoral system choice.

Existing research has overlooked this link. The literature on electoral system choice does not consider how districts in the old majoritarian representation (MR) systems are set and changed. Instead, the district map is treated as exogenous to parties’ preferences for electoral system choice. In these accounts, incumbent parties opt for the adoption of PR because insurgent parties endanger their future electoral viability (Boix, Reference Boix1999; Leemann and Mares, Reference Leemann and Mares2014) or because they are negatively affected by vote-seat distortions and uncertainty about election outcomes (Colomer, Reference Colomer2005; Calvo, Reference Calvo2009).

Similarly, for a long time, the literature on partisan districting ignored the link between district design and electoral system choice. Based on the USA case, this literature long questioned the effectiveness of partisan districting due to legal constraints or because effects cancel each other out at the aggregate level (Gelman and King, Reference Gelman and King1994; Engstrom, Reference Engstrom2013). The outcome of the 2010 redistricting cycle made scholars reconsider this conclusion, which has also triggered debates about PR adoption (McGhee, Reference McGhee2020; Keena et al., Reference Keena, Latner, McGann and Smith2021). Yet, before these recent developments, few scholars had explored the relationship between gerrymandering and electoral system choice.

In contrast, we argue that possibilities for partisan districting are key determinants of parties’ positions on PR. Partisan districting can be an effective containment strategy that allows incumbent parties to keep insurgent parties at bay. As we show, factors historically limiting the effectiveness of gerrymandering in the USA case do not necessarily apply to other cases. Accordingly, partisan districting was more widespread in first-wave democracies than is generally acknowledged (Handley, Reference Handley, Herron, Pekkanen and Shugart2018). This has important implications for parties’ positions on electoral system choice because partisan districting as a containment strategy is primarily effective in MR systems due to small district magnitude and the constant need to adapt district boundaries to accommodate population growth (Grofman, Reference Grofman2016). Consequently, if incumbent parties can resort to partisan districting to engineer parliamentary majorities, they have an alternative to PR when facing electorally strong insurgent parties.

This paper adds to the literature on electoral system choice. This literature has been dominated by Rokkan’s (Reference Rokkan1970) electoral threat thesis, according to which established parties facing an electorally strong insurgent party adopt PR to minimize seat losses. Taking partisan districting into account can turn this logic upside down. In the empirical analysis, we demonstrate that electoral disproportionalities resulting from partisan districting influence legislators’ voting behavior on the adoption of PR. In contrast to the traditional electoral threat thesis, we show that legislators of incumbent parties facing a district-level electoral threat favor MR if they have benefitted from partisan districting in the past. In addition, we add to the USA-centric literature on partisan districting. In line with more recent contributions on gerrymandering in the USA, we offer qualitative and quantitative evidence to demonstrate that partisan districting under MR can be an effective instrument to protect incumbent parties’ strong political positions. Finally, by showing that insurgent parties often suffered from partisan districting under MR, we can explain why insurgent parties often favor PR adoption – rather than oppose it, as the electoral threat thesis predicts.

Empirically, we explore gerrymandering and electoral reform in Switzerland, which relied on an MR system before it adopted – in line with other first-wave democracies – PR in 1918. The Swiss case allows us to take advantage of unique datasets based on parliamentary debates and several roll-call votes to demonstrate that partisan seat-maximization interests were decisive in district design and that gerrymandering influenced party positions on PR. At the same time, there is little reason to believe that this direct link between biases resulting from partisan districting and electoral system choice is specific to Switzerland. There is plenty of research highlighting the role of partisan districting in other first-wave democracies and beyond (Handley, Reference Handley, Herron, Pekkanen and Shugart2018). Similarly, the literature on electoral system choice has emphasized that vote-seat distortions are key determinants of preferences for electoral reform (Calvo, Reference Calvo2009). We simply add that gerrymandering can be deliberately used to contain insurgent parties, and that gerrymandering is thus intimately linked to questions of electoral system choice because it is primarily effective under MR.

This paper proceeds as follows. The next section develops our theoretical argument on the relationship between district design and electoral system choice. Subsequently, we provide empirical evidence on this relationship in chronological order. First, we show how partisan districting was used to contain insurgent parties. Second, we document how the resulting disproportionalities gave rise to demands for PR. Finally, we demonstrate that legislators benefiting from partisan districting opposed PR. The conclusion discusses the implications for research on partisan districting and electoral system choice.

Partisan districting and electoral system choice

Over the last decades, two sophisticated but surprisingly disconnected literatures have emerged. The literature on partisan districting mainly focuses on the USA case (Gelman and King, Reference Gelman and King1994; Cox and Katz, Reference Cox and Katz2002; Engstrom, Reference Engstrom2013; McGhee, Reference McGhee2020), where the term gerrymandering was coined to describe the manipulation of electoral districts for partisan goals (exceptions include Brady and Mo, Reference Brady and Mo1992; Pilet, Reference Pilet2007; Handley and Grofman, Reference Handley and Grofman2008; Wong, Reference Wong2017). In contrast, the literature on electoral system choice primarily focuses on Europe where during the early 20th century, several countries adopted PR (Boix, Reference Boix1999; Blais et al., Reference Blais, Dobrzynska and Indridason2005; Colomer, Reference Colomer2005; Calvo, Reference Calvo2009). This literature rarely explores the US case (exceptions include Ahmed, Reference Ahmed2013; Santucci, Reference Santucci2017; Rodden, Reference Rodden2019).

This disconnection is unfortunate because there are important points of contact. Consider the literature on electoral system choice, which has been dominated by Rokkan’s ‘two roads to electoral reform’ (Calvo, Reference Calvo2009: 267). According to one road, the electoral threat thesis, parties support PR adoption if insurgent parties endanger their future electoral viability. If insurgent parties gather enough support or have concentrated voter bases, the other parties might be better off under PR (Lijphart, Reference Lijphart1992; Boix, Reference Boix1999; Leemann and Mares, Reference Leemann and Mares2014). According to the other road, parties support PR if they are adversely affected by vote-seat distortions, i.e., they win a substantially lower percentage of seats than votes (Andrews and Jackman, Reference Andrews and Jackman2005; Calvo, Reference Calvo2009; Rodden, Reference Rodden2009).Footnote 1

There is great merit in both arguments. However, they both treat the district map as exogenous to parties’ preferences for electoral system choice. In these accounts, there is little incumbent parties can do to improve their situation. If they face an electorally strong insurgent party, if they do not benefit from the mechanical and psychological effects of MR, or if they are uncertain about electoral outcomes, their only response is to adopt PR. But why should incumbent parties not try to create favorable vote-seat distortions and thus contain insurgent parties?

Indeed, Ahmed (Reference Ahmed2013) points to the possibility of containment as an alternative to PR. However, she does not offer a systematic analysis of containment strategies. Leemann and Mares (Reference Leemann and Mares2014) show that both district-level electoral threats and vote-seat distortions influence legislators’ support for PR, but they do not consider the possibility of parties trying to influence electoral disproportionalities to contain insurgent parties. Finally, Emmenegger and Walter (Reference Emmenegger and Walter2021) find that vote-seat distortions affect the relationship between district-level electoral threats and legislators’ support for PR. However, they do not offer evidence on the strategic manipulation of electoral districts to create these vote-seat distortions, and they do not show that PR adoption was a strategic response to these manipulations.

This paper argues that incumbent parties may have means at their disposal to engineer more beneficial vote-seat distortions and lower levels of uncertainty about election outcomes. Incumbent parties, if in control of the relevant decision-making body and conditional on their electoral geography, can manipulate electoral districts to protect their parliamentary majority. In this process, incumbent parties may try to maximize the number of insurgent parties’ votes that do not contribute to the election of these parties’ candidates. For instance, minorities of insurgent parties’ voters can be moved into districts dominated by incumbent parties, thus wasting all the insurgent parties’ votes for the losing candidates. Alternatively, geographical boundaries can be adapted to create safe but inefficient districts, where the insurgent parties’ candidates win with overwhelming majorities, thus wasting a lot of votes on few seats.

Hence, under MR, incumbent parties may be able to use district design to contain insurgent parties. The observable implications are that incumbent parties engage in partisan districting and insurgent parties suffer from electoral disproportionalities. Moreover, having the means to keep insurgent parties at bay, incumbent parties have little incentive to adopt PR, which would not only put an end to their parliamentary majority but also remove their most powerful containment instrument, which is more effective under MR (Birch, Reference Birch2011; Grofman, Reference Grofman2016; Martinez i Coma and Lago, Reference Martinez i Coma and Lago2018). In fact, as the insurgent parties’ electoral strength increases, containment by means of partisan districting (and by implication the MR system) becomes more important. Thus, only if districting as a containment strategy is not available, should we expect incumbent parties facing strong insurgent parties to pin their hopes on PR (i.e., Rokkan’s electoral threat thesis).

Of course, there is an important caveat. This containment strategy is dependent on the effectiveness of partisan districting. Yet, the primarily US-based literature on gerrymandering has long suggested the opposite. Summarizing this literature, McGhee (Reference McGhee2020: 173) notes that ‘the conclusion was quite consistent: Partisan gerrymandering either was a minor factor in American elections or actually had the opposite of its intended result.’ Only the outcome of the 2010 redistricting cycle in the USA has made scholars reconsider this conclusion (Stephanopoulos and Warshaw, Reference Stephanopoulos and Warshaw2020; Keena et al., Reference Keena, Latner, McGann and Smith2021), which, tellingly, also triggered debates about the adoption of PR (Donovan, Reference Donovan2018).

The literature on the US case has discussed several limitations to effective gerrymandering (Cox and Katz, Reference Cox and Katz2002; Engstrom, Reference Engstrom2013; McGhee, Reference McGhee2020). First, gerrymandering requires control over the districting process and sufficient information on voters’ distribution. Second, disadvantages in one state might be compensated by advantages in another one, canceling each other out at aggregate level. Third, legal constraints and judicial review might limit possibilities for gerrymandering. Finally, gerrymandering might also be used to protect incumbent legislators rather than to maximize seat shares.Footnote 2

Research on gerrymandering has focused almost exclusively on the USA, making it ‘the most neglected topic in electoral and institutional design in terms of comparative research’ (Handley and Grofman, Reference Handley and Grofman2008: v). However, insights from the US case might not travel easily to other cases. Consider the Swiss case, where electoral districts were designed by the federal parliament, giving the politically dominant Liberals full control over the districting process, whereas minority parties had no possibility to compensate for these disadvantages. Regular subnational elections offered detailed and fine-grained data on voters’ distribution. Moreover, there was no possibility to challenge electoral districts in court. Still today, Swiss courts have limited jurisdiction in case of federal parliamentary acts. Finally, the protection of specific incumbent legislators was no concern because candidates could run in several districts simultaneously. This is not to say that partisan districting was effective, which is an empirical question, but the standard reasons given for its ineffectiveness do not apply to Switzerland.

Switzerland is no exception. There is considerable historical research pointing to partisan districting in a variety of first-wave democracies, often with the legislature in charge of district design (Handley and Grofman, Reference Handley and Grofman2008). In other countries, incumbent parties benefited from malapportionment due to the nonadaption of electoral districts (Elklit, Reference Elklit, Grofman and Lijphart2002; Reibel, Reference Reibel2007). In fact, ‘during the nineteenth century, in Europe and in self-governing European colonies around the world, redistricting was carried out by the legislature. Gerrymandering […] and other electoral abuses were not uncommon’ (Handley, Reference Handley, Herron, Pekkanen and Shugart2018: 516). Over time, these abuses led some countries to adopt reforms depoliticizing the redistricting process, thereby often explicitly excluding representatives of political parties from serving on such boundary commissions – the USA being a notable exception (Handley, Reference Handley, Herron, Pekkanen and Shugart2018: 517).

Other countries adopted PR systems whose large multimember districts are rarely redrawn. Rather, shifts in population are accommodated by adjusting the number of seats allocated to each of the multimember districts, whereas the boundaries can stay the same. Hence, under PR, the potential for partisan districting is limited (Grofman, Reference Grofman2016). With most European countries adopting PR in the early 20th century, partisan districting under the previous MR systems became an afterthought. Moreover, with the US-based literature traditionally (but no longer) emphasizing the ineffectiveness of partisan districting, electoral system choice scholars had little reason to reconsider this position.

Importantly, this unequal role of partisan districting in MR and PR systems is in line with the well-known argument in the electoral system choice literature that vote-seat distortions under MR are an important driver of support for PR (Calvo, Reference Calvo2009). However, this literature has not systematically linked the politics of partisan districting to questions of electoral system choice. Consequently, it has failed to see what partisan districting might truly be: a strategy parties deliberately use to contain insurgent parties. In contrast, we suggest that the widespread practice of partisan districting (leading to vote-seat distortions) and the regular occurrence of vote-seat distortions (widely considered a predictor of support for PR) are causally connected.

Figure 1 summarizes our argument. If partisan districting under MR is effective, parties can use it to contain insurgent parties, reduce uncertainty, and create advantageous vote-seat distortions. In this case, incumbent parties have little reason to push for PR, whereas insurgent parties, suffering from the resulting disproportionalities, push for PR to neutralize the incumbent parties’ containment strategy. In contrast, if partisan districting under MR is not effective, we expect incumbent parties facing strong insurgent parties to support PR adoption to minimize seat losses.

Figure 1. Partisan districting and electoral system choice.

What makes partisan districting – rather than PR adoption – more likely in the face of an electoral threat, and what specific form does partisan districting take? The choice of containment strategy is a function of several variables, most notably electoral geography, the rules shaping the (non)adaptation of districts, and data availability. For starters, to rely on districting as a containment strategy, parties must be in control of the relevant decision-making body. In this period, this was typically the legislature, with limited involvement by the courts (Handley, Reference Handley, Herron, Pekkanen and Shugart2018). In addition, the incumbent parties’ parliamentary representation must be such that insurgent parties – with the help of districting – can be relegated to a minority status for longer periods.

Second, parties’ electoral geography might favor different forms of districting. For instance, parties with electoral strongholds in rural areas might oppose reapportionment despite rural depopulation. The Danish Liberals and the German Conservatives relied on such malapportionment as a containment strategy (Elklit, Reference Elklit, Grofman and Lijphart2002; Reibel, Reference Reibel2007). In contrast, parties with electoral strongholds in urban areas, such as the Swiss Liberals, favor reapportionment. Yet, each redistricting cycle provides such parties with opportunities for gerrymandering, as district boundaries are adapted to accommodate differences in population growth. The Swiss Liberals thus relied on gerrymandering, rather than malapportionment, to contain insurgent parties (see below).

Third, partisan districting requires fine-grained data on electoral geography. Thanks to regular subnational elections, such data exist in most cases. In Switzerland, election results at municipality level were available since the mid-19th century, although in comparative perspective, the documentation of electoral results was rather underdeveloped (Caramani, Reference Caramani2000). Today, more information is typically available (Wong, Reference Wong2017).

Fourth, constitutional provisions might limit the potential for districting. For instance, the Belgian constitution requires regular reapportionment, which made it impossible for the Catholic Party to rely on malapportionment before the adoption of PR in 1899 (Emmenegger and Walter, Reference Emmenegger and Walter2019). In contrast, the Swiss Liberals benefited from regular reapportionment. However, the Swiss constitution did not allow electoral districts to cut across cantonal borders, which circumscribed gerrymandering’s potential for containment.

In sum, partisan districting as a containment strategy is influenced by several factors and can take different forms. In some cases, it might not even be available. If incumbent parties cannot manipulate district boundaries for partisan gain, or if its potential for containment is exhausted, we expect these parties, in line with Rokkan’s (Reference Rokkan1970) electoral threat thesis, to adopt PR when facing strong insurgent parties. In contrast, where partisan districting as a containment strategy is available, incumbent parties prefer to maintain MR because of the possibilities MR offers for partisan districting.

In the remainder of this paper, we provide, using the Swiss case, empirical evidence to support our argument. The next two sections offer qualitative and quantitative evidence on the importance of gerrymandering as a containment strategy. Subsequently, we demonstrate how vote-seat distortions moderated the effect of district-level electoral threats on legislators’ support for PR adoption.

Qualitative evidence of partisan districting

In the Swiss civil war of 1847, the Liberal proponents of a federal state and modern democracy faced the Conservative defenders of cantonal sovereignty and traditional authorities. After their decisive victory, the Liberals created a reform commission tasked with the drafting of the new constitution. Each of the 25 cantons had one representative in the commission. However, given that the Liberals had installed ‘puppet regimes’ (Altermatt, Reference Altermatt2020: 37) in the Conservative cantons, Liberals also represented the latter. Next to introducing direct voting and male universal suffrage, the reform commission defined the constitutional rules for district design. While the commission quickly settled on the principle of one member of parliament (MP) per 20,000 residents, district design proved to be controversial. Ultimately, the commission decided that districts were not allowed to cut across cantonal borders because representatives of non-German-speaking minorities and small cantons worried that their candidates would not find sufficient support in a nationwide district (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 538; Kölz, Reference Kölz1992: 567–568; Holenstein, Reference Holenstein2018: 302–303).Footnote 3 The task to specify further details was left to parliament. For the first election under the new constitution, in 1848, the cantons – all led by Liberal governments – were to set the rules. They were simply informed about their number of representatives and asked to respect democratic procedures (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 539).

But Switzerland was a country emerging from a civil war. In several cantons, the Liberal occupation regimes did not have broad popular support. Allowing the Conservatives to win the election might have jeopardized the Liberals’ democratization and modernization project. Drastic measures were therefore necessary to neutralize the ‘die-hard enemies of our reborn fatherland’ and ‘unpatriotic accomplices of the reactionaries’ (Jorio, Reference Jorio and Studer1998: 89–98). The Liberals thus faced a dilemma. If they upheld democracy, they would risk losing power to the ‘forces of darkness’ (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 315) whom they accused of trying to undermine the democracy from within. In contrast, if they wanted to secure political power, they were forced to resort to illicit means that risked undermining democracy.

Complaints about partisan districting accompanied federal elections from the beginning. Historical research suggests that these complaints were warranted. For instance, in the reform commission, the Liberals openly discussed the implications of district magnitude on election outcomes. If there was a Liberal majority, a single canton-wide district was preferable because it would allow the Liberals to win all seats. In contrast, if the Conservative opposition was strong, single-member districts were preferable to prevent a Conservative landslide win (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 322–323). Accordingly, Aargau opted for a single multimember district with nine seats, ultimately preventing the regionally concentrated Conservative vote from winning a single seat. In contrast, the predominantly Conservative cantons Fribourg and Luzern were divided into single-member districts.

Moreover, next to partisan districting, the Liberals relied on other forms of manipulation. For instance, in Fribourg, voters were required to swear an oath on the new constitution to prevent Conservatives from voting (Greyerz, Reference Greyerz, im Hof and Stahelin1977: 1022). Consequently, voter turnout in Fribourg was a paltry 21% (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978b: 345). Ultimately, in 1848, not a single Conservative was elected in Fribourg, whereas in Luzern, the Conservatives managed to win one district. Liberal newspapers publicly applauded this political exclusion (Neue Zürcher Zeitung, November 18, 1848, Nr. 323).

For the first election, the revision commission had left electoral district design to cantonal authorities. For subsequent elections, the federal parliament was to specify further rules. In 1850, the Federal Government suggested that multimember districts of three to four seats should be the rule but wanted to leave district design to cantonal authorities. The lower chamber, dominated by Liberals, agreed on district magnitude but insisted on having final authority over district design (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 539–540). The cantons’ role was limited to making suggestions. Alfred Escher, president of the lower chamber and later the chair of the parliamentary commission designing the districts, understood that district design had the potential to prevent a Conservative victory in the 1851 election (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 101). Referring to the possibility of a Conservative return to power in some cantons, he argued that it would be ‘naïve’ to leave district design to cantonal authorities (personal letter, cited in Gagliardi, Reference Gagliardi1919: 168).

In 1850, Escher, supported by an all-Liberal commission, embarked on district design. Detailed calculations made by the commission for all districts, preserved in Escher’s literary remains, document the commission’s gerrymandering (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 333–334). After the federal parliament had supported the commission’s district map, Escher was satisfied, arguing that ‘all liberal cantons are content, except Luzern. But the latter is hard to help if you do not want to leave the principled ground’ (personal letter, cited in Gagliardi, Reference Gagliardi1919: 168). To be clear, despite these inadequacies of Luzern’s district map, the Liberals still won five out of seven seats in this historically Conservative stronghold in the 1851 election. The Liberals were thus confident about the upcoming elections. The Liberal commission member Jakob Dubs, who would later join the Federal Government, argued that ‘districts are such that according to the worst scenario 40 […] Conservatives will be elected to the [120 seats strong] lower chamber’ (personal letter, cited in Gagliardi, Reference Gagliardi1919: 168).

In these years, partisan districting is hard to deny. The Liberals spoke openly about it. Referring to Aargau, the Liberal MP Keller argued that ‘even if they must make crooked strokes, …where there is not enough, a few Liberal municipalities will be added, so it cannot go wrong. Where there are too many black or red voters, the council will say: let us move them where they do not trouble us’ (cited in Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 323). Similarly, referring to St. Gallen, the Liberal MP Gmür argued that the very purpose of district design was to increase the likelihood that no Conservative candidate would be elected (Der Wahrheitsfreund, 1848: 40–41, cited in Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 328). In fact, the Liberals did not hesitate to resort to more open manipulation strategies in this early period of the federal state. For instance, after the Liberals had lost all six seats in the 1854 election in Ticino, the Liberal majority in the federal parliament simply declared the election illegal – ‘an obvious partisan decision’ (Tanner, Reference Tanner and Studer1998: 69). After the opposition leaders’ incarceration, the repeated election brought six Liberals back to power. However, for the Liberals, such blunt interventions were dangerous, as they undermined the Liberals’ claim to be the true defenders of democratization. Hence, over time, the Liberals preferred to rely on forms of electoral manipulation that are less visible and harder to prove, most notably gerrymandering. In the online Appendix B, we discuss three concrete instances of gerrymandering to show how the Liberals took advantage of partisan districting to protect their parliamentary majority.

Against this background, it is not surprising that Conservative complaints about partisan districting did not abate over the following decades (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967; Tanner, Reference Tanner and Studer1998). In the late 19th century, the emerging Socialists joined these allegations (Degen, Reference Degen and Studer1998). Gruner (Reference Gruner1978a: 352) argues that ‘the federal authorities were positively bombarded with petitions’ for more adequate districts. Yet, with an absolute majority in the lower chamber from 1848 to 1918, the Liberal groups were in control of district design for national elections from 1848 until the adoption of PR in 1918. Admittedly, these Liberal groups had grown increasingly heterogeneous: A ‘Radical left’ faced a ‘Liberal center’. Later, a democratic ‘extreme left’ would further fragment the Liberal camp (with the Socialists’ emergence, the use of ‘left’ for Radicals and ‘extreme left’ for Democrats was discontinued). However, all these groups were united in the opposition to the ‘Conservative right’ (Altermatt, Reference Altermatt2020: 81) and later also the Socialists (Degen, Reference Degen and Studer1998).Footnote 4

Consequently, the Liberals rejected most petitions for more adequate districts (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 352–361). Moreover, they rejected accusations of partisan districting. For instance, in an 1883 report commissioned by the Federal Government, Carl Hilty, a professor of public law and later Liberal MP (1890–1909), could not detect any biases in district design (Kölz, Reference Kölz2004: 693). Over time, Conservatives and Socialists increasingly relied on statistical means to demonstrate the role of gerrymandering (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978a: 58–64), but the Liberals would have none of it. As late as 1914, the Federal Government, controlled by Liberals, rejected accusations of partisan districting. Based on their own calculations, the government argued, there is no ‘serious imbalance’ between votes and seats (Bundesrat, 1914: 146).

Quantitative evidence of partisan districting

There is a sophisticated literature examining partisan districting in the USA. Yet, it is difficult to identify clear instances of gerrymandering because the process of redistricting is largely hidden from the public. Moreover, the system of single-member districts can generate natural biases if voters of a party are concentrated in few populous municipalities, thereby giving even impartial bureaucrats only limited options to design maps without partisan biases (Chen and Rodden, Reference Chen and Rodden2013). Consequently, researchers often draw on computational methods to generate a large set of possible district maps to investigate whether the implemented district plan displays an unusually high level of partisan bias.

The Swiss case does not suffer from such problems. The process of redistricting was openly discussed in parliament with proponents and opponents of the various plans clearly identifiable. Based on suggestions by cantonal governments but also other interest groups, and relying on detailed results from regular subnational elections, a parliamentary commission prepared a proposal, in which it also reviewed the different suggestions. The commission’s proposal was subsequently discussed in parliament, with votes on specific districting decisions and a final vote on the overall district plan. The publicly documented process of redistricting allows us to draw on comprehensive evidence to study gerrymandering. Moreover, in Switzerland, elections were held in multimember districts. Hence, the geographical scope of a district could be expanded by adding more seats, making electoral geography endogenous to party strategies. Although multimember districts of three or four seats were defined as the rule, there were plenty of exceptions.

As mentioned, there is a constitutional limit to partisan districting in Switzerland. Electoral districts were not allowed to cut across cantonal borders, which was an important limitation given the small size of many of the 25 cantons. Due to this restriction, only about ten cantons offered serious potential for partisan districting (Zürich, Bern, Luzern, Fribourg, St. Gallen, Graubünden, Aargau, Ticino, Vaud, and Valais). The other 15 cantons were either too small throughout the entire period or had enough seats only after population growth started to pick up in the late 19th century. However, the ten largest cantons had the most seats in parliament (74.8% in 1848 and 71.4% in 1917).Footnote 5

In the following, our quantitative analysis covers four different aspects of the redistricting process to provide evidence for gerrymandering. First, we employ roll-call vote data from Bolliger and Zürcher (Reference Bolliger and Zürcher2004), who have retrieved over 100 roll-call votes for the period 1874–1914, including two final votes on the districting plans in 1881 and 1890, respectively. We use these votes as descriptive evidence to demonstrate that the districting process was politicized along party lines.

Second, we have collected data from the parliamentary debates on redistricting in 1902 and 1911.Footnote 6 In particular, we focus on how legislators positioned themselves vis-à-vis specific district proposals in the debate. Our binary-dependent variable captures whether the proposal of a given MP was adopted or if in the parliamentary debate, the MP opposed a proposal that was not adopted eventually. In both cases, we assign the score of 1 to our dependent variable because the legislator’s preferences for district reform prevailed. In contrast, we assign the score of 0 if a MP proposed a district plan that was rejected or if he opposed a proposal that was adopted. As predictors, we include the legislator’s party affiliation and whether the proposal was originally made by a legislator or another political actor (cantonal governments or other nonparliamentary actors such as local party chapters).

Third, we draw on electoral data and all district reforms under MR. Our binary-dependent variable captures whether a district was merged with or split from another district or whether its borders were adjusted after a national census. In these cases, we assign the value of 1. In contrast, we assign the value of 0 if districts were not changed. For the estimation, we use changes in electoral strength of the main minority parties (Conservatives and Socialists) in a district to account for partisan biases in the redistricting process. Gruner (Reference Gruner1978b) provides estimates of the true but unobserved vote share of parties from 1848 to 1917 by accounting for strategic candidate entry and electoral alliances between parties (we provide a detailed explanation of Gruner’s approach in the online appendix C). In addition, we compute whether a canton received additional seats due to population growth (‘seat adjustment’), which could trigger redistricting by design. Lastly, we control for district magnitude because redistricting was more difficult in small cantons since districts were not allowed to cut across cantonal borders.

Fourth, we capture whether redistricting increasingly distorted the translation from votes to seats by using Gruner’s (Reference Gruner1978b) electoral strength data at cantonal level.Footnote 7 We use data on electoral strength along with information about the number of seats to compute the disproportionalities from which minority parties suffered. More specifically, we use the difference between electoral strength and the seat share of Conservatives and Socialists by canton.

Given that our analysis builds on different data sets with less than 500 observations, we employ a penalized Logit estimator for small samples with binary dependent variables (Firth, Reference Firth1993; Rainey and McCaskey, Reference Rainey and McCaskey2021) and outlier-robust linear regression for continuous dependent variables.Footnote 8 In addition, our observations are nested within cantons, which are constitutional barriers to partisan redistricting. Therefore, we assume that our observations within cantons are not independent and thus employ cluster-robust standard errors at cantonal level for all estimations. Summary statistics are provided in the online appendix A.

How did party competition in Switzerland evolve from 1848 to 1917? The upper panel in Fig. 2 shows that the Liberal camp, consisting of Liberals, Radicals, and Democrats (in the following called ‘Liberals’ for the sake of simplicity) enjoyed a comfortable majority in parliament throughout the period. While the Conservatives gained considerably in the first three decades, their seat share stagnated subsequently. The Socialists’ entry at the turn to the 20th century did not alter the relationship fundamentally even though they were able to snatch some seats from the Liberals.

Figure 2. Seat shares and electoral disproportionality, 1848-1917.

The lower panel in Fig. 2 shows that the Liberals’ dominance was, in part, built on vote-seat distortions.Footnote 9 Their seat bonus declined in the first decades from over 10% to 5%. This decline can be attributed to the Conservatives’ increasing electoral strength in small rural cantons, which limited the Liberals’ ability to influence the electoral outcome via redistricting. For instance, the electoral strength of the Conservatives in strongholds such as Luzern, Fribourg, and Valais grew between 1848 and 1875 from 24% to 68%, 8% to 80%, and 38% to 70%, respectively (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978b: 373–382). Despite various attempts to secure a strong Liberal representation in these cantons by adjusting district boundaries, the Conservatives’ overwhelming support made it increasingly difficult for the Liberals to introduce distortions to change the outcome in their favor. Still, thanks to careful district design, the Liberals won four seats in these overwhelmingly Conservative cantons in the 1875 election.

In contrast, the Socialists were unable to gain similar levels of electoral support to neutralize the adverse effects of partisan redistricting. By entering the electoral arena in the more urban and industrialized cantons, the Socialists challenged the Liberals in their heartlands. The Liberals resorted to redistricting, which resulted in considerable disproportionalities. For instance, in the last election under MR in 1917, the Socialists gained 44% and 39% of the vote in Zürich and Bern but only 28% and 24% of the seats (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978b: 396).

Given that redistricting was one of the most contentious issues, how did the process look like from a quantitative perspective? Between 1848 and 1917, the district design was adjusted seven times, each time following the national census. Table 1 provides an overview. The columns show the distribution of cantons along two dimensions: whether cantons’ number of seats changed and whether redistricting took place. Table 1 demonstrates that in a substantial number of cases, districts within cantons were adjusted without any change in the number of seats, especially in 1851, after the 1848 election had provided rich data on electoral geography. Such cases of ‘unprompted’ redistricting are clear signs that changes in district design follow partisan rather than just demographic considerations (Engstrom, Reference Engstrom2013).

Table 1 Redistricting in Switzerland, 1848–1917

Redistricting was highly contentious. Table 2 offers an overview of legislators’ voting behavior along party lines for the final district bills in 1881 and 1890 – the only two years for which roll-call data is available. In both cases, the Conservatives unanimously rejected the laws, while a large majority of Liberal MPs supported them. Note that some Liberal MPs opposed the new district maps because in some cantons, factions within the Liberal camp ran against each other (e.g., Neuchâtel, Vaud, and Bern). Nevertheless, the Liberals had enough supporters to overcome Conservative resistance against the new district maps.

Table 2 Parliamentary votes on redistricting, 1881 and 1890

Next, we turn to our multivariate analysis. As outlined above, we focus on parliamentary debates and the factors triggering redistricting. Models 1 and 2 in Table 3 present our results on the question of which proposals debated in parliament were ultimately incorporated into the final law. Despite controlling whether the proposal came from a cantonal government or an MP, the dummy variable for the Liberals is significant and positive. More specifically, the point estimate suggests that Liberal proposals were twice as likely to be adopted.

Table 3 Determinants of redistricting, 1848–1917

Notes: ***P < 0.001;

**P < 0.01;

*P < 0.05.

Models 3 to 6 of Table 3 contribute to this picture. They show that the probability of redistricting is higher when the minority parties’ electoral strength is growing before the design of the new district map. Importantly, the result holds despite accounting for whether a canton received (or lost) seats due to reapportionment as well as the log-transformed number of seats.

Finally, we turn to the question whether redistricting increased partisan biases. In Table 4, we estimate whether changes in district boundaries within cantons increased disproportionalities for minority parties (Conservatives and Socialists). We use a binary measure that captures whether districts have been adjusted prior to an election. In addition, we employ disproportionality at cantonal level (the difference between a party’s seat share and electoral strength at cantonal level) as a dependent variable. Negative values indicate a bias against the minority party. Using a range of specifications with lagged dependent and control variables, canton fixed effects, and nonlinear time trends, we find that redistricting increased disproportionalities by about 2.6 to 3.6 percentage points. Put differently, following the adjustment of electoral districts, minority parties lost between three to four percentage points of seat shares for the same vote share.Footnote 10

Table 4 Effectiveness of redistricting, 1848–1917

Notes: ***P < 0.001;

**P < 0.01;

*P < 0.05.

In sum, the quantitative evidence points to a considerable amount of partisan districting. Against the background of Liberal MPs openly admitting political manipulation, the use of partisan districting in Switzerland is hard to deny. However, did partisan districting matter for political majorities? There are good reasons to believe that it did.

As mentioned, factors limiting the effectiveness of gerrymandering did not apply to Switzerland. Minority parties had no possibilities to offset disadvantages or challenge districts in court. Throughout the entire period, the Liberals defined the district map against their opposition. Little surprise that the Liberals benefited from electoral disproportionalities throughout the entire period. Admittedly, the Conservatives’ disadvantages decreased over time, but this happened despite partisan districting. As the Conservatives reclaimed their traditional strongholds, removing the Liberal ‘puppet regimes’ (Altermatt, Reference Altermatt2020: 37), they benefited from these cantons’ small size. Moreover, over time, Liberal attention increasingly turned to the Socialists, which challenged the Liberals in their strongholds, whereas the Conservatives’ rural strongholds were plagued by depopulation (in 1848, the eight cantons losing the 1847 civil war had 19% of the seats in the federal parliament; in 1917, they had 15%). As Fig. 2 shows, the Socialists suffered from electoral disproportionalities that eclipsed even the ones from which Conservatives had suffered after 1848. Hence, while the Liberals had at first targeted the Conservatives, at the turn to the 20th century, their advantage came at the Socialists’ expense. This situation would only change with the adoption of PR in 1918, which allowed the Socialists to double their number of seats (from 22 in 1917 to 41 seats in 1919) despite a reduction in their electoral strength (from 30.8% to 23.5%). The next section examines the empirical relationship between partisan districting and PR adoption.

Partisan districting and the adoption of PR

Conservatives and Socialists regularly complained about partisan districting. The previous section has shown that the Conservatives unanimously rejected the district maps in 1881 and 1890 and that Conservative and Socialist suggestions for district reforms were significantly less likely to be accepted in 1902 and 1911. Seeing their requests for changes in electoral districts repeatedly ignored, the minority parties turned to electoral system reform. Already in 1872, the Conservative MP Herzog-Weber demanded the introduction of PR with cantons as electoral districts. However, there was considerable uncertainty about the specifics. Moreover, alternative reform proposals suggested the introduction of single-member districts or the adoption of limited voting (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 543). Yet, the Liberals remained steadfast in their opposition to electoral system reform. They rejected any accusations of partisan districting and praised the virtues of MR in multimember districts (Kölz, Reference Kölz2004: 693).

In the 1880s, the Conservatives increasingly pinned their hopes on PR. In an 1884 parliamentary motion, three leading Conservative MPs demanded a new district map or the adoption of PR – a clear sign that the Conservatives were converging on PR. Only three years later, the Conservative leader Zemp declared that fairer districts would not be sufficient because only the adoption of PR would satisfy the minority parties (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 551). In their efforts, the Conservatives were now joined by the Socialists. In the late 1880s, the two parties organized numerous joint rallies, yet the Liberals remained unimpressed (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967: 551). In the discussion of the districts for the 1890 election, Conservative and Socialist requests were mostly ignored. Summarizing the discussion, a Conservative MP argued that ‘instead of being a work of peace, the new district map will be the source of disunity and struggle’ (Der Bund, November 30, 1889, Nr. 330). Even the influential Liberal-leaning Neue Zürcher Zeitung acknowledged the use of gerrymandering: ‘It should be said openly: We have the majority, and we want to make sure that we do not lose it’ (November 28, 1889, Nr. 332).

While the Conservatives and the Socialists did not stop submitting parliamentary motions demanding electoral reform, they increasingly turned their attention to extra-parliamentary means. In 1891, Switzerland had introduced the instrument of popular initiatives, which required the support of at least 50,000 citizens and allowed suggesting constitutional articles that needed to be implemented by law if approved in a popular vote (parliament could not change the proposals). Conservatives and Socialists launched their first joint popular initiative in the late 1890s, demanding the adoption of PR with cantons as electoral districts. Relying on cantons as districts was an important Socialist concession because the Conservatives would benefit from the small size of most of their cantonal strongholds. In public discussions, the Liberals tried to take advantage of this concession to drive a wedge into the Conservative-Socialist coalition, but the Socialists did not take the bait (Natsch, Reference Natsch1967). Nevertheless, the first initiative was rejected in a popular vote in 1900 with a yes share of 40.9%. The second initiative was rejected more narrowly in 1910 (yes share of 47.5%). The third initiative was ultimately accepted in 1918, with a yes share of 66.8% (Linder et al. Reference Linder, Bollinger and Rielle2010). In each case, the proposals simply stated that elections to the lower chamber are direct, based on the principle of proportionality, and that cantons are the electoral districts.

In the following, we examine the relationship between partisan districting and support for the adoption of PR empirically. We follow the approach of Leemann and Mares (Reference Leemann and Mares2014) and analyze the voting behavior of MPs to explore the relationship between electoral threats, seat-vote distortions, and support for the adoption of PR. More concretely, we take advantage of the fact that popular initiatives are also voted upon in parliament.Footnote 11 Our dependent variable is the support for the adoption of PR by an MP in the lower chamber in 1900, 1910, 1914, and 1918 (the parliament voted twice on the third popular initiative). In all four votes, parliamentary majorities rejected the proposal, with yes/no ratios of 33/79 in 1900, 45/100 in 1910, 62/105 in 1914, and 71/78 in 1918 (Bulletin, 1900, 1910, 1914, 1918). The analysis is based on Emmenegger and Walter (Reference Emmenegger and Walter2021) who offer a more detailed discussion of the dataset.

As discussed, we expect that as the insurgent party’s electoral strength increases, containment by means of gerrymandering and by implication, the MR system, becomes more important. MPs benefiting from disproportionalities are particularly opposed to the adoption of PR because in the absence of MR and the potential it offers for containment, these MPs have little chance to beat strong insurgent candidates. Empirically, we are thus particularly interested in the interaction between an insurgent party’s electoral strength and the degree to which MPs are advantaged by partisan districting. Hence, if facing a strong electoral challenge, support for PR should be low if the MP benefits from electoral disproportionalities because this MP’s electoral success depends on the continued reliance on gerrymandering under MR.

By the time of the first popular initiative on the adoption of PR, Liberal gerrymandering was mainly focusing on the Socialists, whereas Conservatives were comparatively ‘safe’ in their rural strongholds (see Fig. 2). In the analysis below, we therefore focus on the Socialists’ electoral strength. We expect parties to evaluate the status quo against their vote-to-seat relation under PR. Given that cantonal borders constituted legal barriers to redistricting under MR and were the demanded districts under PR, we focus on the Socialists’ electoral strength at cantonal level. The electoral strength data are from Gruner (Reference Gruner1978b: 373–397). Based on this data, we also calculate the degree of disproportionality at cantonal level by party (seat share minus electoral strength). A substantial part of this disproportionality is likely to be the result of partisan districting.

Table 5 provides evidence for our argument using MP voting behavior on the four proposals.Footnote 12 Both estimators show that the interaction term of disproportionality and Socialist electoral strength is highly significant when added to models 2 and 5. The result remains unaffected in models 3 and 6 with the most restrictive specification, additionally controlling for the most important competing approaches. More precisely, we control for the presence of co-specific assets and trade exposure (Rogowski, Reference Rogowski1987; Cusack et al., Reference Cusack, Iversen and Soskice2007), run-off elections, and the vote margin of the two strongest non-Socialist parties (Boix, Reference Boix1999; Leemann and Mares, Reference Leemann and Mares2014), whether the MP is a member of the party elite (Cox et al., Reference Cox, Fiva and Smith2019; Schröder and Manow, Reference Schröder and Manow2020), and Socialist radicalization (Ahmed, Reference Ahmed2013; Gjerløw and Rasmussen, Reference Gjerløw and Rasmussen2022). Table A3 in the online appendix A provides detailed information on the operationalization of all variables.

Table 5 Disproportionality, socialist electoral threat, and support for PR, 1900–1918

Notes: Cluster robust standard errors in parentheses.

***P < 0.001;

**P < 0.01;

*P < 0.05.

What does the interaction term tell us about how incumbents respond to an increasing electoral threat? In Fig. 3, we plot the predicted probabilities for different levels of Socialist electoral strength on support for PR, depending on whether MPs benefit from the existing electoral system. In addition, we include a histogram of Socialist electoral strength at the bottom of Fig. 3 (see Figure A2 in the online appendix A for a histogram of disproportionalities). We differentiate two scenarios. A disproportionality score of 0.2 indicates that the legislator’s party received 20% more seats than votes in a canton. As Figure A2 shows, this value is rather common among MPs, especially Liberal ones, which were the primary beneficiaries of gerrymandering. In contrast, a disproportionality score of −0.2 indicates that the legislator’s party received 20% more votes than seats in a canton. As Figure A2 shows, this is a realistic value, especially for non-Liberal MPs, although there are fewer cases. This should not come as a surprise though, as parties are likely to struggle to get their candidates elected in such circumstances.Footnote 13

Figure 3. Effect of socialist electoral strength on support for PR conditional on disproportionality.

The dotted line in Fig. 3 shows that if MPs benefit from electoral disproportionalities, higher Socialist electoral strength is associated with stronger opposition to PR. This result supports our argument that if incumbents can influence vote-seat distortions in their favor, they cling to the existing MR system despite increasing electoral challenges because the MR system offers incumbents a powerful containment strategy. In the Swiss case, the use of gerrymandering under MR allowed the Liberals to contain the Socialist electoral threat and defend their absolute majority in parliament. A different picture emerges if MPs do not benefit from electoral disproportionalities. For this case, the solid line in Fig. 3 shows that Socialist electoral strength has a positive impact on MPs’ support of PR. This is the familiar electoral threat argument (Rokkan, Reference Rokkan1970; Leemann and Mares, Reference Leemann and Mares2014), according to which threatened MPs support the adoption of PR to increase their reelection chances. In the Swiss case, this scenario describes the situation of many Conservative and some Liberal MPs that, for whatever reasons, could not benefit from vote-seat distortions. Overall, Fig. 3 demonstrates that partisan districting and the resulting disproportionalities decisively moderate whether electoral threats increase or decrease support for PR among incumbent MPs.

Conclusion

Electoral threats are not set in stone. Depending on the processes shaping the (non-)adaption of electoral districts, incumbent parties can contain insurgent parties by means of partisan districting. However, this containment strategy is primarily effective under MR, which is why incumbent parties benefiting from partisan districting have little incentive to adopt PR in response to electoral threats. By adopting PR, powerful incumbents would put an end to their parliamentary majority and neutralize their most powerful containment instrument.

Using the Swiss case, this paper has demonstrated that the Liberals relied on partisan districting to contain insurgent parties. We have discussed how the districting rules were created in the period from 1847 to 1850. In addition, we have demonstrated that minority party suggestions for changes to the district map were significantly less likely to be accepted by parliament, that minority parties unanimously rejected the final electoral laws containing the district maps, that the probability of redistricting increased with the electoral strength of minority parties (even when the number of seats remained unchanged), and that redistricting increased electoral disproportionalities for minority parties.

For minority parties, the Conservatives and the Socialists, there was little chance to get a more adequate district map under MR. Consequently, from the 1870s onward, they began to cooperate and demand electoral system reform. From the late 1890s onward, they pursued electoral reform by means of direct democracy. Using four roll-call votes in parliament, this paper has shown that incumbent MPs benefiting from electoral disproportionalities opposed the adoption of PR in the face of an insurgent party electoral threat. Put differently, if incumbents can influence vote-seat distortions in their favor by means of districting, they cling to the existing MR system despite increasing electoral threats.

Together, these findings suggest that electoral engineering strategies under MR, and in particular the process of adapting electoral districts, are key determinants of parties’ positions on the desirability of PR. Clearly, Rokkan’s ‘two roads to electoral reform’ (Calvo, Reference Calvo2009) are not independent of each other. Whether electoral threats make incumbent parties support or oppose PR is decisively moderated by partisan districting. If partisan districting under MR is effective, incumbent parties can use it to contain insurgent parties. In contrast, if partisan districting under MR is not effective, incumbent parties facing strong insurgent parties adopt PR to minimize seat losses.

The literature on electoral system choice has repeatedly emphasized that vote-seat distortions are a key determinant of preferences for electoral reform. From this point of view, the adoption of PR could be a remedy against malapportionment and gerrymandering, as both are strongly tied to MR systems and low district magnitude. In this paper, our aim has simply been to demonstrate that the widespread practice of partisan districting and the regular occurrence of vote-seat distortions may be causally connected, and that contemporaries were aware of this link. In short, the discontents of partisan districting had good reasons to push for PR.

Clearly, partisan districting is not the only electoral manipulation strategy available to incumbents (Norris, Reference Norris2004; Birch, Reference Birch2011; Ahmed, Reference Ahmed2013). However, for two reasons, we believe partisan districting to be particularly important. First, as demonstrated above, partisan districting under MR could be highly effective. Moreover, its ineffectiveness as a containment strategy under PR creates a direct link to questions of electoral system choice. If partisan districting is an effective containment strategy under MR, there is little reason to adopt PR and thereby give up on partisan districting.

Second, partisan districting is also an option for parties that are openly supportive of democracy. Whereas some containment strategies are highly visible (e.g., plural voting) or risky (e.g., electoral fraud), partisan districting has the advantage that it is hard to prove (Wong, Reference Wong2017). In MR systems, districts must be regularly adapted to accommodate population shifts. Lacking objective benchmarks, deliberately created partisan biases are difficult to prove, as the USA debate demonstrates (Chen and Rodden, Reference Chen and Rodden2013). As late as 1914, the Swiss Government, dominated by Liberals, claimed to be unable to detect any ‘serious imbalance’ between seats and votes (Bundesrat, 1914: 146). Five years later, after the adoption of PR, the Socialists almost doubled their seat share despite losing 7.3 percentage points in their vote share. This credible deniability makes partisan districting less costly in terms of voters’ affect (Quintal, Reference Quintal1970).

Of course, partisan districting and other forms of electoral manipulation can be used simultaneously. However, in the other cases, credible denials of electoral manipulation are often more difficult. As a containment strategy, partisan districting thus offers significant advantages.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773923000267.

Acknowledgments

We thank Theresa Berz for her research assistance and Lukas Haffert, Patrick Kuhn, Lucas Leemann, Jonathan Slapin, Andreina Thoma, and the participants of the Comparative Institutions and Regimes research seminar at the University of Oslo, the Center for Comparative and International Studies research seminar at the University of Zurich, the Comparative Political Economy research seminar at the University of St. Gallen, the 2022 annual conference of the Swiss Political Science Association, and the 2022 annual conference of the European Political Science Association for most helpful feedback. We also want to thank the editors and the three anonymous reviewers for their constructive feedback. This research is being generously supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation (grant #:100017_184969).

Footnotes

1 New contributions also highlight within-party dynamics (Cox et al., Reference Cox, Fiva and Smith2019; Schröder and Manow, Reference Schröder and Manow2020), issues of legitimacy (Blais et al., Reference Blais, Dobrzynska and Indridason2005; Bol et al., Reference Bol, Pilet and Riera2015), and systemic threats (Ahmed, Reference Ahmed2013; Gjerløw and Rasmussen, Reference Gjerløw and Rasmussen2022).

2 Although scholars increasingly emphasize the effectiveness of gerrymandering, there is still evidence showing that the widespread gerrymandering mostly cancels nationally (Kenny et al., Reference Kenny, McCartan, Simko, Kuriwaki and Imai2023).

3 According to the 1850 census, the four largest cantons had 46.3% of the population. Roughly 70% of the population were German speaking.

4 The Democrats, Liberals, and Radicals relied on district-level electoral alliances to solve coordination problems. For instance, in the 1917 election, the three groups won 67 of their 122 seats based on such alliances (Gruner, Reference Gruner1978b: 325–340).

5 Changing this constitutional rule would have required a popular vote with majorities required among both voters and cantons. Hence, the prospects of removing this restriction were slim. For the same reason, the popular initiative right was, once introduced, difficult to remove again.

6 The parliamentary debates are officially recorded only since 1891.

7 In case of redistricting, the old districts often cease to exist, which makes an analysis at district-level impossible. All districts are nested in cantons. We therefore capture disproportionalities at cantonal level.

8 We provide linear probability models and logit models for all estimations with binary dependent variables.

9 The electoral disproportionality shown in Figure 2 need not imply bias. Figure A1 therefore shows the levels of partisan bias favoring the Liberals using the procedure suggested by Keena et al. (Reference Keena, Latner, McGann and Smith2021). The patterns are very similar, although the bias indicator does not fully capture the electoral manipulation in the first two elections. In general, the calculation of partisan bias scores is difficult for elections in multimember districts and in multiparty systems. Because there are only a few districts within cantons, partisan bias cannot be calculated due to lack of observations. However, in this paper, we only explore levels and changes of disproportionality within the same MR system. We are thus confident that disproportionalities approximate partisan biases.

10 Table A2 in the online appendix A replicates this analysis but excludes cantons with only one seat. The results are not affected by this change.

11 If supported by parliament, the proposal is typically implemented by law without a popular vote.

12 Table A5 in the online appendix A shows that the interaction term of disproportionality and Socialist electoral strength remains significant when excluding Socialist MPs.

13 Figure A3 in the in online appendix A shows that the same pattern can be observed with a disproportionality score of −0.1.

References

Ahmed, Amel. Democracy and the Politics of Electoral System Choice: Cambridge UP, 2013.Google Scholar
Altermatt, Urs. Vom Unruheherd zur stabilen Republik: NZZ, 2020.Google Scholar
Andrews, Josephine, and Jackman, Robert. “Strategic Fools: electoral Rule Choice under Extreme Uncertainty.” Electoral Studies 24.1 (2005): 6584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birch, Sarah. Electoral Malpractice: Oxford UP, 2011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André, Dobrzynska, Agnieszka, and Indridason, Indridi. “To Adopt or Not to Adopt Proportional Representation: the Politics of Institutional Choice.” British Journal of Political Science 35.1 (2005): 182–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. “Setting the Rules of the Game: the Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies.” American Political Science Review 93.3 (1999): 609–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bol, Damien, Pilet, Jean-Benoit, and Riera, Pedro. “The International Diffusion of Electoral Systems: the Spread of Mechanisms Tempering Proportional Representation across Europe.” European Journal of Political Research 54.2 (2015): 384410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolliger, Christian, and Zürcher, Regula. “Deblockierung durch Kooptation? Eine Fallstudie zur Aufnahme der Katholisch-Konservativen in die schweizerische Landesregierung 1891.” Swiss Political Science Review 10.4 (2004): 5992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brady, David, and Mo, Jongryn. “Electoral Systems and Institutional Choice: A Case Study of the 1988 Korean Elections.” Comparative Political Studies 24.4 (1992): 405–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulletin. “Initiativbegehren für die Proportionalwahl des Nationalrates und die Wahl des Bundesrates durch das Volk.” Bulletin der Bundesversammlung 2 (1900): 325–35.Google Scholar
Bulletin. “Initiativbegehren um Einführung des Verhältniswahlsystems für den schweizerischen Nationalrat.” Bulletin der Bundesversammlung 1 (1910): 95112.Google Scholar
Bulletin. “Volksbegehren um Einführung der Verhältniswahl für die Wahlen in den schweizerischen Nationalrat.” Bulletin der Bundesversammlung 3 (1914): 487–8.Google Scholar
Bulletin. “Verhältniswahl für die Nationalratswahlen. Volksbegehren.” Bulletin der Bundesversammlung 3 (1918): 198–9.Google Scholar
Bundesrat. “Botschaft des Bundesrates an die Bundesversammlung betreffend das Volksbegehren um Einführung der Verhältniswahl für die Wahlen in den schweizerischen Nationalrat.” Bundesblatt 2.12 (1914): 119–55.Google Scholar
Calvo, Ernesto. “The Competitive Road to Proportional Representation: Partisan Biases and Electoral Regime Change under Increasing Party Competition.” World Politics 61.2 (2009): 254–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caramani, Daniele. Elections in Western Europe, 1815–1996. London/New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Jowei, and Rodden, Jonathan. “Unintentional Gerrymandering: Political Geography and Electoral Bias in Legislatures.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 8.3 (2013): 239–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colomer, Josep. “It’s Parties that Choose Electoral Systems (or, Duverger’s Laws Upside Down).” Political Studies 53.1 (2005): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary, Fiva, Jan, and Smith, Daniel. “Parties, Legislators, and the Origins of Proportional Representation.” Comparative Political Studies 52.1 (2019): 102–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary, and Katz, Jonathan. Elbridge Gerry’s Salamander. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cusack, Thomas, Iversen, Torben, and Soskice, David. “Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems.” American Political Science Review 101.3 (2007): 373–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Degen, Bernard. “Wer darf mitregieren? Die Integration der Opposition als Gnadenakt.” In Etappen des Bundesstaates: Staats- und Nationsbildung der Schweiz, edited by Studer, Brigitte. Zurich: Chronos, 1998, pp. 145–58.Google Scholar
Donovan, Todd. Changing How America Votes. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 2018.Google Scholar
Elklit, Jorgen. “The Politics of Electoral System Development and Change: The Danish Case.” In The Evolution of Electoral and Party Systems in the Nordic Countries, edited by Grofman, Bernard and Lijphart, Arend. New York: Agathon Press, 2002, pp. 1566.Google Scholar
Emmenegger, Patrick, and Walter, André. “When Dominant Parties Adopt Proportional Representation: the Mysterious Case of Belgium.” European Political Science Review 11.4 (2019): 433–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emmenegger, Patrick, and Walter, André. “Disproportional Threat: Redistricting as an Alternative to Proportional Representation.” Journal of Politics 83.3 (2021): 917–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engstrom, Erik. Partisan Gerrymandering and the Construction of American Democracy. Ann Arbor: U of Michigan Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Firth, David. “Bias Reduction of Maximum Likelihood Estimates.” Biometrika 80.1 (1993): 2738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gagliardi, Ernst. Alfred Escher. Frauenfeld: Huber, 1919.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew, and King, Gary. “Enhancing Democracy through Legislative Redistricting.” American Political Science Review 88.3 (1994): 541–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gjerløw, Haakon, and Rasmussen, Magnus. “Revolution, Elite Fear and Electoral Institutions.” Comparative Politics 54.4 (2022): 595619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greyerz, Hans von. “Der Bundesstaat seit 1848.” In Handbuch der Schweizer Geschichte, edited im Hof, Ulrich and Stahelin, Andreas. Zurich: Berichthaus, 1977, pp. 10191268.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard. “Perspectives on the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems.” Annual Review of Political Science 19 (2016): 523–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruner, Erich. Die Wahlen in den schweizerischen Nationalrat, 1848–1919, Vol. 1. Bern: Francke, 1978a.Google Scholar
Gruner, Erich. Die Wahlen in den schweizerischen Nationalrat, 1848–1919, Vol. 3. Bern: Francke, 1978b.Google Scholar
Handley, Lisa. “Electoral Systems and Redistricting.” In The Oxford Handbook of Electoral Systems, edited Herron, Erik, Pekkanen, Robert, and Shugart, Matthew. Oxford: Oxford UP, 2018, pp. 513–32.Google Scholar
Handley, Lisa, and Grofman, Bernard. Redistricting in Comparative Perspective. Oxford: Oxford UP, 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holenstein, Rolf. Die Stunde Null. Basel: Echtzeit, 2018.Google Scholar
Jorio, Marco. “Zwischen Rückzug und Integration.” In Etappen des Bundesstaates: Staats- und Nationsbildung der Schweiz, edited by Studer, Brigitte. Zurich: Chronos, 1998, pp. 89143.Google Scholar
Keena, Alex, Latner, Michael, McGann, Anthony J., and Smith, Charles A.. Gerrymandering the States. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kenny, Christopher T., McCartan, Cory, Simko, Tyler, Kuriwaki, Shiro, and Imai, Kosuke. “Widespread Partisan Gerrymandering Mostly Cancels Nationally, But Reduces Electoral Competition.” PNAS 120.25 (2023): e2217322120.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kölz, Alfred. Neuere schweizerische Verfassungsgeschichte: Ihre Grundlinien vom Ende der Alten Eidgenossenschaft bis 1848. Bern: Stämpfli, 1992.Google Scholar
Kölz, Alfred. Neuere schweizerische Verfassungsgeschichte: Ihre Grundlinien in Bund und Kantonen seit 1848. Bern: Stämpfli, 2004.Google Scholar
Leemann, Lucas, and Mares, Isabela. “The Adoption of Proportional Representation.” Journal of Politics 76.2 (2014): 461–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. “Democratization and Constitutional Choices in Czecho-Slovakia, Hungary and Poland 1989–91.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 4.2 (1992): 207–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linder, Wolf, Bollinger, Christian, and Rielle, Yvan. Handbuch der eidgenössischen Volksabstimmungen 1848 bis 2007. Bern: Haupt, 2010.Google Scholar
Martinez i Coma, Ferran, and Lago, Ignacio. “Gerrymandering in Comparative Perspective.” Party Politics 24.2 (2018): 99104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGhee, Eric. “Partisan Gerrymandering and Political Science.” Annual Review of Political Science 23 (2020): 171–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Natsch, Rudolf. Die Auseinandersetzung um das gerechte Wahlverfahren im 19. Jahrhundert. Bern: Lang, 1967.Google Scholar
Norris, Pippa. Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pilet, Jean-Benoit.Strategies under the Surface: the Determinants of Redistricting in Belgium.” Comparative European Politics 5.2 (2007): 205–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quintal, David. “The Theory of Electoral Systems.” Western Political Quarterly 23.4 (1970): 752–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rainey, Carlisle, and McCaskey, Kelly. “Estimating Logit Models with Small Samples.” Political Science Research and Methods 9.3 (2021): 549–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reibel, Carl W. Handbuch der Reichstagswahlen 1890–1918, Vol. 1. Dusseldorf: Droste, 2007.Google Scholar
Rodden, Jonathan. “Why did Western Europe Adopt Proportional Representation? A Political Geography Explanation.” Working Paper, 2009.Google Scholar
Rodden, Jonathan. Why Cities Lose. New York: Basic Books, 2019.Google Scholar
Rogowski, Ronald. “Political Cleavages and Changing Exposure to Trade.” American Political Science Review 81.4 (1987): 1121–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rokkan, Stein. Citizens, Elections, Parties. Colchester: ECPR, 1970.Google Scholar
Santucci, Jack. “Party Splits, Not Progressives: the Origins of Proportional Representation in American Local Government.” American Politics Research 45.3 (2017): 494526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schröder, Valentin, and Manow, Philip. “An Intra-Party Account of Electoral System Choice.” Political Science Research and Methods 8.2 (2020): 251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephanopoulos, Nicholas, and Warshaw, Christopher. “The Impact of Partisan Gerrymandering on Political Parties.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 45.4 (2020): 609–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tanner, Albert. “Ein Staat nur für die Hablichen?” In Etappen des Bundesstaates: Staats- und Nationsbildung der Schweiz, edited by Studer, Brigitte. Zurich: Chronos, 1998, pp. 6388.Google Scholar
Wong, Stan H.-W.Gerrymandering in Electoral Autocracies: evidence from Hong Kong.” British Journal of Political Science 49.2 (2017): 579610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Partisan districting and electoral system choice.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Seat shares and electoral disproportionality, 1848-1917.

Figure 2

Table 1 Redistricting in Switzerland, 1848–1917

Figure 3

Table 2 Parliamentary votes on redistricting, 1881 and 1890

Figure 4

Table 3 Determinants of redistricting, 1848–1917

Figure 5

Table 4 Effectiveness of redistricting, 1848–1917

Figure 6

Table 5 Disproportionality, socialist electoral threat, and support for PR, 1900–1918

Figure 7

Figure 3. Effect of socialist electoral strength on support for PR conditional on disproportionality.

Supplementary material: File

Emmenegger and Walter supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Emmenegger and Walter supplementary material(File)
File 517.2 KB