Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T19:03:42.981Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Division of labour and dissenting voting behaviour of MPs in a ‘working parliament’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 June 2023

Philipp Mai*
Affiliation:
Institute of Political Science, Heidelberg University, Heidelberg, Germany and Department of Social Sciences, RPTU Kaiserslautern-Landau, Kaiserslautern, Germany
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In the literature on the determinants of party unity, one pathway has remained largely neglected: division of labour. Given their workload, members of parliament (MPs) are only thoroughly concerned with a subset of policies. We argue that this results in MPs casting fewer dissenting votes on matters within their area of specialization since they have had the opportunity to shape the party line there. Regression analyses using data for the German Bundestag support this hypothesis, including four important refinements: Not only the current but also past membership in the responsible committee reduces an MP’s defection probability. Additionally, this pattern is more pronounced for policy spokespersons and for less consequential, i.e., non-legislative votes as well as for issues less salient to the MP’s party. The results have implications for our understanding of MPs’ legislative behaviour, the functioning of parliaments as institutions and for the relationship between parties, MPs and voters.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of European Consortium for Political Research

Introduction

Party unity is an important prerequisite for much of what happens politically in parliamentary democracies (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011). Theories of party competition, e.g., on issue ownership and how parties make use of it in campaigns, treat parties as monolithic blocks that are bound to their party platforms (Budge, Reference Budge2015). In elections, citizens often identify with, but at least vote for parties whose relative strength usually decides on the composition of parliament. Thereby, voters expect party representatives to feel committed to the policy positions with which they ran for election (‘promissory representation’, Mansbridge, Reference Mansbridge2003). Party unity is thus considered a precondition for responsible party government (Bowler et al., Reference Bowler, Farrell, Katz and Bowler1999). A lack of party unity is punished at the ballot box (Lehrer et al., Reference Lehrer, Stöckle and Juhl2022) and, on the member of parliament (MP) level, with lower chances of career advancement (Schobess and de Vet, Reference Schobess and de Vet2022). Moreover, hypotheses on the formation of minimal winning coalitions would be meaningless if parties could not rely on the support of all their MPs. Finally, in order to exert measurable effects on public policies (Hibbs, Reference Hibbs1977; Wenzelburger and Zohlnhöfer, Reference Wenzelburger and Zohlnhöfer2021), parties have to act cohesively, both vis-à-vis coalition partners and the opposition. Therefore, exploring what drives or impedes the unified legislative behaviour of parties and their MPs points far beyond parliamentary research.

Division of labour has been described as one of several pathways to party unity, meaning a factor conducive to MPs of the same party overwhelmingly voting together in parliament (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011). On the individual level, division of labour means that MPs are not concerned with all policies in detail but specialize on certain issues which they work on in parliamentary committees and preparatory bodies of their party group. On the institutional level, committees are considered the ‘workhorses’ of the legislative process (Siefken, Reference Siefken, Siefken and Rommetvedt2021: 117). They fulfil various functions in representative democracies: For opposition parties, committees are a means of introducing new ideas, criticism or modifications of bills in the decision-making process that is, apart from that, dominated by governing parties (Strøm, Reference Strøm1990). Governing parties use committees for shadowing, monitoring and overriding their coalition partners and to modify government bills (Kim and Loewenberg, Reference Kim and Loewenberg2005; Fortunato, Reference Fortunato2019). In both respects, committee deliberations serve as a ‘test stage’ for the plenary debate and decision (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). Moreover, committees and their corresponding bodies within the party groups are targets of interest group influence (Cross et al., Reference Cross, Eising, Hermansson and Spohr2021). Finally, committees are concerned with scrutiny and oversight activities (Siefken, Reference Siefken2018; Norton, Reference Norton2019).

Division of labour and MPs’ issue specializations have implications for their roles within their party groups and for their legislative behaviour, including their varying propensity to toe the party line. However, empirical tests of this argument using observational data, i.e., measures of actual MP behaviour, are rare. In this paper, several behavioural manifestations of this argument are deducted and transferred into testable hypotheses. In a first step, we argue that MPs have lower defection rates when motions are on the floor which they were concerned with during their committee work (policy-shaping hypothesis). In a second step, several refinements are discussed: whether also past committee memberships are effective and whether the committee membership effect is conditioned by having a leadership position or by the importance of the vote for an MP’s party. After outlining the study design, the results of panel regression analyses using data for the German Bundestag (2017–2021) are presented. The article concludes with a discussion of the findings’ implications for the nexus between parties, MPs and voters.

State of the art: party unity and parliamentary committees

The question of why MPs overwhelmingly vote together in parliamentary democracies has been subject to empirical studies especially for the last two or three decades. Theoretically, the literature identified a set of ‘pathways to party unity’ (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011), among them (1) homogeneity of preferences, (2) loyalty and (3) discipline. Voting unity is not determined by preference similarity among the MPs alone (Willumsen, Reference Willumsen2022), although MPs’ own ideological stances demonstrably affect their voting behaviour in certain policy areas (e.g., Degner and Leuffen, Reference Degner and Leuffen2016). The loyalty path to unity has been conceptualized as the result of MPs’ party socialization (Rehmert, Reference Rehmert2022; Mai and Wenzelburger, Reference Mai and Wenzelburger2023). To capture the varying effectiveness of party discipline, the career-related dependence of MPs on their party, compared to other principals (e.g., voters), has been approximated. Empirically, holding or ambitions to reach powerful offices (Kernecker, Reference Kernecker2017; Bhattacharya and Papageorgiou, Reference Bhattacharya and Papageorgiou2019; Zittel and Nyhuis, Reference Zittel and Nyhuis2019) strengthen, whereas an MP’s need for personal votes in the general election (Sieberer, Reference Sieberer2010; Sieberer and Ohmura, Reference Sieberer and Ohmura2021) or in intra-party primaries (Sozzi, Reference Sozzi2023), personalized campaign styles (Zittel and Nyhuis, Reference Zittel and Nyhuis2021), local ties (Tavits, Reference Tavits2009), economic interests of an MP’s constituency (Stiller, Reference Stiller2023), outside earnings (Mai, Reference Mai2022), a low prospect of being promoted to higher office (Benedetto and Hix, Reference Benedetto and Hix2007), career ambitions at another political level (Meserve et al., Reference Meserve, Pemstein and Bernhard2009), party switching (Gherghina and Chiru, Reference Gherghina and Chiru2014), impending retirement (Mai et al., Reference Mai, Link and Engler2023, but Willumsen and Goetz, Reference Willumsen and Goetz2017 for non-results) or being a ‘career politician’ (Heuwieser, Reference Heuwieser2018) weakens an MP’s propensity to toe the party line, arguably due to a changed effectiveness of party discipline compared to the baseline MP.

In contrast, empirical implications of division of labour as a fourth pathway to unity have rarely been included in observational studies of vote defections (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011; van Vonno Reference van Vonno2019). The division of labour principle in parliaments can be observed most clearly in MPs’ committee work. MPs’ issue specialization has effects on their re-election chances (Frech, Reference Frech2016), bill co-sponsorship patterns (Baller, Reference Baller2017), participation in parliamentary debates (Fernandes et al., Reference Fernandes, Goplerud and Won2019), communication with voters (Meyer and Wagner, Reference Meyer and Wagner2021), further career advancement (Cirone and van Coppenolle, Reference Cirone and van Coppenolle2018), attention towards particular issues (Borghetto et al., Reference Borghetto, Santana-Pereira and Freire2020) and their overall level of activity (Louwerse and Otjes, Reference Louwerse and Otjes2016). However, few studies focus on a connection between committee work and party unity. Based on interviews with German and Dutch MPs, Mickler (Reference Mickler2019) describes how the intra-party working groups develop their positions and why the whole party group usually follows them. Fujimura (Reference Fujimura2012) illustrates, for the Japanese case, that committee assignments are used to reconcile the party’s need for unity and MPs’ electoral concerns. For the U.S. case, Kanthak (Reference Kanthak2009) shows that MPs having received plum committee assignments toe the party line more frequently than other MPs. Additionally, Grimmer and Powell (Reference Grimmer and Powell2013) find that legislators who were involuntarily removed from preferred committees have significantly higher defection rates. Conversely, MPs overwhelmingly toeing the party line receive more attractive committee seats or even chair positions, compared to more rebellious colleagues (Leighton and López, Reference Leighton and López2002; Cann, Reference Cann2008; Whitaker, Reference Whitaker2019; but see Chiru, Reference Chiru2020 and Fernandes et al., Reference Fernandes, Saalfeld and Schwemmer2022 for non-results).

Although those findings are related to division of labour, not the MPs’ specialization itself but a changed effectiveness of party discipline after having gained or lost desired committee seats seems responsible for the variation of party unity. Committee assignments are one of the ‘carrots and sticks’ the party leadership uses to enforce discipline (Bailer, Reference Bailer2018). Only Willumsen and Öhberg’s (Reference Willumsen and Öhberg2017) study of the Swedish case explicitly links MPs’ issue specialization to their voting behaviour and finds that MPs vote less frequently against the party line concerning issues that have been dealt with in the parliamentary committee they belong to. We will complement their argument in three crucial respects: First, we argue that not only the current but also past committee memberships are likely to affect individual legislative behaviour. Second, we expect behavioural differences between policy spokespersons and ordinary committee members. Third, we posit that the effect of committee membership is conditional on the importance of the vote. In the subsequent section, we theorize on those aspects and derive five falsifiable hypotheses.

Theory

In its 19th term (2017–2021), 870 draft bills and hundreds of other motions (e.g., amendments, resolutions) were introduced and (most of them) adopted or rejected during votes in the German Bundestag. The MPs were provided with more than 31,000 documents as a technical basis for their decisions. However, they are only able to take note of a small subset of those documents and to form their opinion on only some of the motions brought to the floor (Ismayr, Reference Ismayr2012). Most obviously, time constraints prevent them from doing so – as described by a leading MP cited in Searing (Reference Searing1995: 680): ‘The volume is so great that most of the time they would be completely lost, they wouldn’t know which way to vote’. In order to keep the amount of information to process manageable, MPs usually join one or two standing committees that, broadly, resemble the jurisdictions of the government departments and deal with bills and other motions related to them (Siefken, Reference Siefken, Siefken and Rommetvedt2021). Within each parliamentary party, the committee structure is reflected by working groups (Arbeitsgruppe) in which the MPs collaborate in defining their party’s position. In smaller parties, the working groups consist of MPs from multiple committees with similar topics, e.g., foreign, defence and development aid policy (Arbeitskreis; Mickler, Reference Mickler2019). The positions of the party’s working groups mark an important predecision for a motion’s prospect to be passed. Suppose MPs or party factions aim to modify a proposal: In that case, not the plenary, the committee or the party group meeting but the responsible working group of the parliamentary party is the suitable arena for such an undertaking (Schöne, Reference Schöne2010). If its members have agreed on a common position, a discussion in the whole party group is ‘preferably avoided’ (Mickler, Reference Mickler2019). Consequently, membership in those working groups is the most promising avenue for backbench MPs to pursue their policy-seeking goals.

There are several reasons why MPs do not often disagree with the other policy specialists of their party regarding their own topics. Besides other factors, committee assignments and, consequently, MPs’ ‘own’ topics often reflect their educational or occupational background (Mickler, Reference Mickler2018). In the German parliament, for example, members of the agricultural committee are to a disproportionately higher share farmers themselves; most of the members of the justice committee are lawyers (Ismayr, Reference Ismayr2012). Additionally, according to the distributive theory of legislative organization, MPs systematically join committees related to constituency characteristics: MPs from poor districts are often members of social policy committees, whereas members from constituencies with an increased demand for construction activity join infrastructure committees (Martin and Mickler, Reference Martin and Mickler2019 with further references). Both the personal and electoral reasons for their committee membership might favour a common understanding of problems and, possibly, even a rough homogeneity of preferences among the policy specialists of a party group. Within the cooperative structures of their working group, the single MPs are described as ‘busy, well-informed, often experienced, more or less knowledgeable policy workers who develop and evaluate parliamentary motions’ (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006: 256, own translation). Within their role, they are able to introduce their personal preferences into the decision-making process of their party group – in some cases, even proactively and not only related to substantiating, modifying or impeding government motions (Schöne, Reference Schöne2010). Consequently, because those policy specialists are involved in shaping their party’s position, they could reduce the policy distance between them and the responsible working group of the party and, finally, the whole party group. Since the MPs thus helped to shape the party line within their area of specialization, they have fewer reasons to vote against it (Willumsen and Öhberg, Reference Willumsen and Öhberg2017). Dingler and Ramstetter’s (Reference Dingler and Ramstetter2021) inverted finding whereby MPs have higher defection rates within their focus area might be rooted in that the authors measure MPs’ interest (by parliamentary questions) and not their capability of shaping policies.

The negative effect of committee membership on defection rates could be amplified by the fact that among the policy specialists who have often worked together for many years there is an increased expectation of mutual loyalty and not to distinguish oneself by dissent from the responsible working group (Schöne, Reference Schöne2010). After some Christian Democratic MPs had voted against measures to resolve the Eurozone crisis in 2015, the leader of the party group threatened them with their removal from the respective committees:

Those who voted ‘No’ cannot keep their seats in committees where it is essential to keep the majority, e.g., in the budget or the EU committee […]. The party group sends MPs into committees so that they represent their party’s position there. (Die Welt, 2015, own translation).

In the year before, another member of this party lost his rapporteur position after publicly proposing social policy reforms that were not coordinated with his working group (BILD, 2014). Both examples illustrate that the leadership expects MPs not to take deviating stances on topics which they work on in their respective committees.

Hence, most dissenting votes are likely to happen outside their areas of specialization. MPs not familiar with a policy field might lack the expertise to have their own view on a particular motion (van Vonno, Reference van Vonno2016). Besides that, MPs might also not have the same interest in every decision and may ignore certain topics (Schöne, Reference Schöne2010). If they do not have an opinion on an issue, MPs take voting cues from the policy specialists of their party. However, if MPs actually have an opinion and are not members of the respective committee and intra-party working group, they have a greater leeway to dissent. Additionally, there are more substantive reasons for defections, as these MPs were not involved in shaping the party line.

HYPOTHESIS 1 (policy-shaping hypothesis): MPs have a lower probability of voting against the party line in matters inside their area of specialization.

That said, we expect that not only the current committee membership but also which topics MPs have specialized on in the past influences their legislative behaviour. Former committee membership indicates interest in the policy area, and MPs keep at least parts of the expertise gained in the past. Therefore, if MPs have been committee members one or two legislative terms ago and, after that, turned to another policy area, they most likely still have an opinion on topics of their former committees. Additionally, during their former membership in a committee and the respective intra-party working group, a convergence might have taken place between the MPs’ preferences and the party line which those MPs used to shape in former times. Lastly, MPs might still feel a sense of loyalty towards their former working group and its members whom they know from their prior collaboration. To conclude, we expect the policy-shaping hypothesis to be valid not only for MPs’ current but also for their past committee memberships – which has not been empirically tested before.

HYPOTHESIS 2 (former specialist hypothesis): MPs have a lower probability of voting against the party line in matters which they were specialized on in former terms.

As insiders of the parliamentary business (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006), the main tasks of policy spokespersons are to lead the working group concerning a particular policy area and to express the working group’s position vis-à-vis the committee, the media and, secondarily, the policy spokesperson of the coalition partner (Ismayr, Reference Ismayr2012; Mickler, Reference Mickler2019). One of their primary duties is to advocate the position of their working group within the whole parliamentary party (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). In this respect, policy spokespersons have, compared to ordinary MPs, significantly better means to shape the party line. Acting as a first filter, they can push certain initiatives or delay others (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). Additionally, since they are members of the party group leadership, they have an informational advantage and a certain leeway in settling conflicts with other intra-party working groups. Their informational advantage is also rooted in the fact that they have privileged access to the parliamentary staff of their party and are able to use its expertise for their purposes (Petersen and Kaina, Reference Petersen and Kaina2007). If the working group is divided on an issue, the policy spokesperson most likely has the authority to resolve conflicts with their decisive vote. This is reflected by the MPs’ own perceptions: 68% of the German MPs who took part in the survey support the statement that the spokespersons define the position of the (whole) party group (van Vonno, Reference van Vonno2016). However, coalition agreements, the party platform or (rarely) a resolution of the whole party group constrain the spokesperson’s room for manoeuvre.

In addition to the power of significantly defining the party’s position, Schöne (Reference Schöne2010) describes that, in exchange for the privileges those policy speakers have (e.g., media attention), they are expected to strictly represent their party group’s position and not dissenting opinions of their own. A recent example illustrates possible role conflicts: Whereas his party group was sceptical, the Social Democratic spokesperson for defence policy, Fritz Felgentreu, supported the claim of its coalition partner to purchase armed drones for the German military. After his party had postponed a decision once again, he resigned from office in 2020 and explained his decision on Twitter as follows (own translation):

Either I could stick to the position [of my party] vis-à-vis the public and the military although everyone knows that I have another opinion […] or I could dissociate myself from the parliamentary group and my party. As a member of both, I expect more loyalty and more solidarity with the leadership and the majority. Therefore, I have resigned from my office as the spokesperson for defence policy.

Consequently, both the spokespersons’ greater influence on the decision-making process and their stronger attachment to the majority position leads to expect the following:

HYPOTHESIS 3 (spokesperson hypothesis): The unity-inducing effect of votes inside their area of specialization is stronger for policy spokespersons compared to ordinary committee members.

Many studies find that defection probabilities differ by policy issues (e.g., Skjæveland, Reference Skjæveland2001; Stecker, Reference Stecker2015; Bergmann et al., Reference Bergmann, Bailer, Ohmura, Saalfeld and Sieberer2016). However, this issue-based approach is only an approximation of where those differences actually stem from: a varying salience of the respective issue either for the party’s brand name (Traber et al., Reference Traber, Hug and Sciarini2014) or the electorate (Ohmura, Reference Ohmura2014). Accordingly, we expect that the importance of an issue conditions the explanatory power of division of labour as a pathway to unity. We focus on two dimensions of importance: the type of the vote and issue salience.

Not every vote is equally consequential. Owens (Reference Owens2003) argues that the politics of party unity is affected by the type of document which is put to the vote. In votes that are crucial for the functioning of the government (e.g., budget), party unity is expected to be higher than in less momentous votes (Rahat, Reference Rahat2007). According to Stecker (Reference Stecker2015), the vote type moderates also the determinants of unity, and he differentiates between legislative and non-legislative matters. Whereas the former exerted direct policy implications through changes in legal rules, the latter had a more symbolic value by being political expressions of intent without direct consequences – although the documents vary in importance within those categories as well.

Beyond vote type, the literature on issue ownership assumes that topics are not equally important to parties, their activists and voters (Budge, Reference Budge2015). This connection between parties and particular issues affects their strategies in election campaigns (Wagner and Meyer, Reference Wagner and Meyer2014), legislative agenda-setting (Green and Jennings, Reference Green and Jennings2019) and in government (Jensen and Seeberg, Reference Jensen and Seeberg2015). Since MPs are not only agents of their constituency but, primarily, of their parties whose success decides, for the most part, on their electoral and other career-related fortunes, the connection between parties and issues might also affect its MPs. Consequently, we expect a behavioural difference between high- and low-salience topics. The latter include those hardly covered in the election manifesto or technical issues difficult to grasp without specific policy knowledge (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011). Those topics are unlikely to be politicized since they do not relate to the party’s identity or the core interests and values of its voters. In such a setting, less constrained by the party manifesto and without creating facts by legislation, the policy-making process leaves enough room for parliamentary actors to substantially influence those policies. Accordingly, we expect division of labour to be particularly effective here, with lower defection rates of committee members.

In contrast, especially when consequential or salient issues are on the floor, parties must reckon with their actions being closely watched by voters. Electoral research has shown that voters indeed react to MPs’ legislative behaviour (Papp and Russo, Reference Papp and Russo2018; Wagner et al., Reference Wagner, Glinitzer and Vivyan2020; Duell et al., Reference Duell, Kaftan, Proksch, Slapin and Wratil2023). Disunity as a negative valence signal endangers the party’s issue ownership and, for government parties, their policy-making capability and will ultimately be punished by voters (Greene and Haber, Reference Greene and Haber2015; Lehrer et al., Reference Lehrer, Stöckle and Juhl2022). Accordingly, the party group leadership is inclined to use the whip to a stronger extent during consequential and salient votes in order to prevent harm to the party (Owens, Reference Owens2003). Consequently, for legislators, party unity hinges much more on a trade-off between their preferences, the interests of their constituency (Stiller, Reference Stiller2023) and the incentives of party discipline. In such a setting where parties and MPs have a clear opinion, taking voting cues from policy specialists becomes largely meaningless (Andeweg and Thomassen, Reference Andeweg and Thomassen2011; van Vonno, Reference van Vonno2016). Moreover, it is less necessary since intra-party preferences are more homogeneous than on less salient issues (Sieberer, Reference Sieberer2010). What is more, for legislative matters and salient issues, policy formulation transfers from the bottom-up process through committees more into a top-down process driven by top representatives of the coalition parties and the government bureaucracy (Schindler, Reference Schindler2019). Possible conflicts are then resolved elsewhere, which further limits the scope of committee members for shaping the party line. This leads to another two conditional hypotheses:

HYPOTHESIS 4 (vote type hypothesis): The unity-inducing effect of votes inside their area of specialization is stronger in non-legislative compared to legislative votes.

HYPOTHESIS 5 (issue salience hypothesis): The unity-inducing effect of votes inside their area of specialization is stronger for low-salient compared to highly salient issues.

Data and methods

The propositions are tested quantitatively using data from the German parliament. First, the Bundestag is regarded as a ‘party group parliament’ (Ismayr, Reference Ismayr2012), i.e., a parliament with powerful party groups which dominate parliamentary work. Second, it is considered a ‘working parliament’ with a high degree of issue specialization among the MPs (Steffani, Reference Steffani1979; Lord, Reference Lord2018) and with the most policy-influential committees in Western Europe (Zubek, Reference Zubek2021). Therefore, Germany is a suitable (and certainly a most-likely) case for an argument based on the nexus between parties and committees. However, the findings should be generalizable to other parliaments in Europe with strong parties and at least a moderate influence of committees (and preparatory bodies of the party groups) on parliamentary decisions.

We collected data on all roll-call votes in the most recent 19th parliamentary term (2017–2021). Despite the discussion on their representativeness and its consequences for the observed level of unity (Ainsley et al., Reference Ainsley, Carrubba, Crisp, Demirkaya, Gabel and Hadzic2020; Yordanova and Mühlböck, Reference Yordanova and Mühlböck2015), roll-call votes are the only source of individual-level voting behaviour for our case. Free votes, i.e., votes where MPs were released from party discipline, are, in principle, not restricted to morality policies but could be tactically imposed by the party group leadership if the party line is difficult to enforce (Ohmura and Willumsen, Reference Ohmura and Willumsen2022). In the legislative term under study, three unwhipped votes were held on a reform of the organ donation system and, thereby, a classical issue of conscience. Since the determinants of MPs’ behaviour systematically differ between whipped and unwhipped votes on morality policy issues, an exclusion of the latter from the sample is justified (see Mai et al., Reference Mai, Link and Engler2023 on MPs’ voting behaviour in those votes). Finally, the models consist of 241 roll-call votes on various kinds of documents (e.g., bills, amendments, motions or resolutions).

The unit of analysis is an MP’s voting decision in a single recorded vote. This highly disaggregated data structure is necessary given that the main independent variable, ‘own committee: at the time of the vote’, measures dichotomously whether an MP votes on a document that has been deliberated in a committee he/she belongs to. Consequently, this variable varies both on the MP and the vote level – such variance could not be explored if aggregated unity scores for MPs or votes were used. Initially, this variable is coded 0 for all votes on motions that were not assigned to at least one committee or, in the case of amendments, are not related to a bill assigned to a committee. This concerns about a quarter of all votes. For the remaining motions, on the vote level, we only consider the leading (federführend) committee since only in those committees, a thorough discussion takes place, possibly including expert hearings, and a voting recommendation for the plenary is resolved (§63 Bundestag rules of procedure). Other committees having only an advisory function in the deliberations are not considered in the main analysis. On the MP level, we only take ordinary committee memberships into consideration for our main models. Even though most MPs are deputy members of additional committees, they only attend their meetings when ordinary members are absent. More importantly, those deputy members are usually not involved in the discussions within the intra-party working groups. Consequently, our policy-shaping hypothesis does not apply to deputy members. In robustness checks, we will explore how the results change if those two restrictions are relaxed (Appendix A3). For now, at the descriptive level, 5.4% of the observations are cases where MPs vote on a document that has been dealt with in their committee(s).

For the variable ‘own committee: before the time of the vote’, the ordinary membership in the respective leading committee during the past two legislative terms, as well as in the current term until the day before the vote, is counted. We chose two past terms as a cut-off point because we assume that policy knowledge and connections to the former working group shrink the longer an MP is not a member anymore. In order to disentangle the effects of past and current membership, the variable is coded 0 if an MP is still a member of the respective committee. The dichotomous variable ‘policy spokesperson (all subjects)’ takes value 1 if an MP at the time of the vote leads a working group of the parliamentary party which is related to the work of one or more committee(s) – irrespective of whether the vote is pertaining to those issues. If the party has elected deputy group leaders who are responsible for certain (broader) topics, they are counted as spokespersons as well since they are actively involved in settling conflicts between different working groups and, as a connection between the leadership and working level of the parliamentary party, have significant powers in the decision-making process (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). To compare the spokespersons’ behaviour across votes, we interact this variable with the variable ‘own committee’ in model 3. For investigating the conditional hypothesis 4, we dichotomized the votes by the respective documents into legislative (bills and amendments) and non-legislative matters (various kinds of motions and resolutions), following Stecker (Reference Stecker2015). In order to test H5, we interacted committee membership with issue salience for the MP’s party. We draw on Manifesto Project data (Lehmann et al., Reference Lehmann, Burst, Matthieß, Regel, Volkens, Weßels and Zehnter2022) which quantifies the percentage of ‘quasi-sentences’ a party dedicates to one of several dozens of issues in its election programme. Its focus on relative issue emphasis aligns with the assumptions of saliency theory (Budge, Reference Budge2015) and thus renders it the most suitable data source for our purposes. For ‘issue salience’, we summed up all manifesto items that are linked to the committee’s jurisdiction (irrespective of the party’s position on the issue). For the main analysis, we accept the huge differences among the salience scores since they represent the overall importance of the topics for the parties. Another option, which we pursue in the robustness checks, is to z-standardize the salience scores among the parties. The result would indicate then which party emphasizes a topic to an above- or below-average extent – irrespective of whether it is generally an important topic. The salience variables were coded ‘missing’ if no manifesto items fit to the committee’s jurisdiction. This reduces the number of observations in model 5 compared to models 1–4.

In order to isolate the hypothesized effects, we control for other factors that affect MPs’ defection rates. Most of them are approximations of the varying effectiveness of party discipline – since the national-level party leadership is the major principal for progressively ambitious MPs (Sieberer and Müller, Reference Sieberer and Müller2017). To capture electoral incentives, we include whether an MP was elected in the nominal or list tier of Germany’s mixed-member electoral system (Sieberer, Reference Sieberer2010). Especially, list candidates are punished by party selectorates for dissenting votes through less promising list positions (Schmuck and Hohendorf, Reference Schmuck and Hohendorf2022), whereas MPs, as individual candidates, tend to profit from vote defections, especially if justified with representing voter concerns (Duell et al., Reference Duell, Kaftan, Proksch, Slapin and Wratil2023). We also include dichotomous variables measuring whether an MP holds an executive office (chancellor, minister, junior minister) or another important parliamentary office (party group leadership, whip, Bundestag presidency, committee chairFootnote 1 ) to account for higher disciplinary pressures (Zittel and Nyhuis, Reference Zittel and Nyhuis2019). Moreover, we consider parliamentary experience which was regarded as a proxy for MPs’ parliamentary socialization (Delius et al., Reference Delius, Koß and Stecker2013), policy influence (Tavits, Reference Tavits2009), policy convergence with one’s party group (Saalfeld, Reference Saalfeld1995) or expertise within ‘their’ policy area (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). MPs’ gender and age are also included especially since recent studies detect, under particular circumstances, lower defection rates for women MPs (Clayton and Zetterberg, Reference Clayton and Zetterberg2021; Dingler and Ramstetter, Reference Dingler and Ramstetter2021). Finally, parties differ in their defection rates – a pattern which is also reflected in our data. Whereas the Christian Democrats show an average defection rate of 0.58%, the Green MPs cast 2.86% of their votes against the party line (Appendix A2, figure 3). Those inter-party differences were attributed to, among others, party group size (Bergmann et al., Reference Bergmann, Bailer, Ohmura, Saalfeld and Sieberer2016), candidacy eligibility criteria (Rehmert, Reference Rehmert2020), intra-party democracy (Close et al., Reference Close, Gherghina and Sierens2019), party organizational strength (Tavits, Reference Tavits2012) or party family (Close, Reference Close2018). Since only one term is analysed and thus sufficient variance is lacking, we include party-fixed effects to account for possible party differences.

Our dichotomous dependent variable takes value 1 whenever an MP’s voting behaviour differs from the majority of their party group. We do not differentiate between different degrees of dissent (i.e., between voting ‘abstention’ or ‘no’ if the party votes ‘yes’) since, in both mentioned cases, the MP does not ultimately support the party line. If an MP does not attend a vote, we code this as a missing observation in the main analysis. Although some absences might be strategically motivated in order not to dissent visibly from the party line (Font, Reference Font2020), they probably mostly have non-political reasons (e.g., time constraints, illness). Due to the dichotomousness of our dependent variable and a data structure that is clustered into multiple voting occasions of MPs, we estimate logistic panel regressions with standard errors clustered by MP.

Details on the measurement, data sources and descriptive statistics of all variables are listed in Appendix A1 (Table 1). Distributional graphs show that the defection rates vary strongly both among MPs and votes (Appendix A2, figures 1+2). Whereas about 50% of the MPs and 22% of the votes do not exhibit a single defection, some MPs have a much higher propensity to defect (up to 27%). Among the 20 votes with the highest defection rates (up to 10%), there are numerous decisions on military missions, but also on measures against the pandemic and other domestic policies (Appendix A2, Table 3).

Table 1. Results of the logistic regression analysis

Logit coefficients are displayed, with standard errors in parentheses.

Levels of significance: *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001.

Results

To evaluate our hypotheses, we estimated five regression models (Table 1). According to model 1, MPs defect less frequently if policy matters are concerned which they dealt with during their committee and party group work. This effect is statistically highly significant and supports the policy-shaping hypothesis (H1). However, this does not imply that MPs do not take any cues from policy specialists on other topics. Actually, it shows that the effect of shaping a motion within their issue specialization or following the position of their own working group outweighs the cue-taking effect on other matters if tested against each other.

According to model 2, not only the current but also former memberships in a committee related to the vote affect MPs’ voting behaviour. Both exert a statistically significant negative effect on casting a dissenting vote. Whereas the coefficient is even larger for past membership, the statistical significance of the current membership is higher. This supports our former specialist hypothesis (H2).

In the third model, the defection probability is compared both between policy spokespersons and ordinary committee members as well as between subjects within/beyond MPs’ issue specialization. The interaction term is not statistically significant at conventional levels (p = 0.11). However, both constitutive variables, which were also included in the models (Brambor et al., Reference Brambor, Clark and Golder2006), exert statistically significant effects. To explore its substantial size, we plotted the effect of voting on a topic within one’s area of specialization both for all MPs and separately for MPs holding a spokesperson function and those who do not (Fig. 1). Overall, voting on a topic that an MP is familiar with reduces the defection probability by 37%. In addition to the lower baseline level, this pattern is considerably more pronounced for spokespersons: Their defection probability is 65% lower regarding issues which they are responsible for. The confidence intervals do not overlap in this comparison. For MPs without a spokesperson position, the difference between the defection probabilities is ‘only’ 30%. This substantial difference between spokespersons and ordinary committee members clearly supports H3.

Figure 1. Predicted probabilities for the conditional effect of policy spokespersons (model 3).

Model 4 tests whether the committee membership effect is conditional on the type of document which is voted on. Figure 2 shows that committee membership exerts an effect on MPs’ defection rates only in votes on motions which do not result in direct legal changes. Non-legislative matters include also votes on military missions abroad. Even if they do not have legal consequences for the citizens, they constitute meaningful decisions both for the soldiers’ lives and the federal budget. Regarding those votes, it has been reported that the leadership of at least some party groups relaxes party discipline for those who cannot support those missions for conscience reasons (Delius et al., Reference Delius, Koß and Stecker2013). On those non-legislative matters, MPs who are responsible committee members have statistically as well as substantially significant lower defection rates. In contrast, when bills and amendments are put to the vote, committee membership is no longer a statistically significant predictor of MPs’ behaviour. In those highly consequential votes, division of labour might be replaced by other pathways to unity, most likely discipline imposed by the party group leadership.

Figure 2. Predicted probabilities for the conditional effect of vote type (model 4).

A similar conditional effect is found for issue salience. Again, the interaction term is not statistically significant (model 5). However, a marginal effects plot shows that the effect of voting on an issue within the jurisdiction of one’s committee indeed varies with issue salience (Fig. 3): The unity-inducing effect of committee membership is strongest for topics which are hardly salient to the MP’s party. With increasing salience, the difference in the defection probabilities between committee members and non-members becomes weaker and, ultimately, statistically insignificant. Supporting H5, it appears that the division of labour principle applies mainly to issues of minor importance to the party, whereas parties monitor and guide the parliamentary behaviour of their MPs more closely on issues that are fundamental to the party’s identity – which, in turn, constrains the committee members’ ability of shaping policies and thus the major reason for toeing the party line.

Figure 3. Effect of committee membership, conditioned by issue salience (model 5).

Regarding the controls, we see that holding parliamentary and, even more, executive offices goes along with lower defection rates – which could be interpreted as a discipline effect. Both a longer parliamentary experience and a higher age correlate with a higher probability to defect. Additionally, we see significant party differences: All parties (except for the Social Democrats) show higher defection rates than the Christian Democrats, with the Greens and the right-wing populist AfD showing the highest defection probabilities. In contrast, whether the MP was elected via the district or the list tier and his/her gender do not matter.

Robustness checks show that the results do not depend on the operationalization of certain controls or the treatment of MPs’ non-participation in roll-call votes. Additionally, they reveal that the more the measurement of MPs’ issue specialization moves from active participation to mere formal consultation, the lower its explanatory power (Appendix A3). Although a correlative analysis cannot ultimately prove it, this substantiates our causal argument that shaping policies and, thus, potentially minimizing the policy distance to the party line is the plausible reason for lower defection rates of committee members.

Conclusion

We investigated how the issue specialization of MPs affects their probability of casting votes against the party line. Like other so-called ‘working parliaments’ (Lord, Reference Lord2018), the Bundestag delegates large parts of its work to standing committees. Since MPs are members of only one or two committees, they are concerned with a subset of all policies in detail. Consequently, there might be differences in MPs’ voting behaviour between issues which they are specialized on and others which they do not get in touch with before the party group meeting or the plenary vote. Empirically, the analysis of roll-call vote data for the German Bundestag (2017–2021) supports our policy-shaping hypothesis, i.e., that MPs have lower defection rates concerning issues inside their area of specialization, probably because they actively participate in determining what later becomes the party line (H1). Proceeding from this, four refining propositions were deducted that had not been empirically tested before and are now backed by the data: First, MPs who formerly were members of the responsible committee show lower defection rates as well (H2). Second, the negative effect on vote defections is stronger for policy spokespersons than for ordinary committee members since the former have enhanced possibilities to shape the party line (H3). Third, the explanatory power of the policy-shaping hypothesis is lower for important decisions, meaning for votes that have a direct effect on legislation (H4) or that are highly salient to the MP’s party (H5). The described effects support the understanding of division of labour as a powerful pathway to party-compliant behaviour, especially for MPs responsible for the given topic. Thus, the findings add to the more prominently featured discipline- and loyalty-related accounts of how parties reach unified action in parliament.

The results have several implications for the relationship between parties, voters and MPs. First, if votes against the party line become more unlikely for MPs who are concerned with a proposal, this might be used strategically by the party group leadership. Instead of denying an MP with diverging views a seat in the respective committee (which would resemble the partisan theory of legislative organization, Cox and McCubbins, Reference Cox and McCubbins1993), it is also conceivable to dissuade the MP from vote defections by involving him/her in the substantive policy work. This would provide an explanation for Mickler’s (Reference Mickler2018) finding that policy distance is not a predictor of committee assignments in the German case. However, disciplining by involvement only works for MPs ideologically not too far away from the party mean who occasionally use deviations to raise their own profile. In contrast, the involvement of staunch preference outliers in the committee work could weaken the overall party position more than just one dissenting voice on the floor. Second, the findings add to the literature on issue competition and issue ownership in that defection rates are not equal among all policy issues. The more salient an issue is for a party, the more centralized appears the policy-making process and the more party discipline restricts the policy-shaping possibilities of individual MPs. Third, that the behavioural differences between committee members and other MPs disappear in the highly consequential legislative votes points to the dominance of political parties and the executive in public policy-making within parliamentary systems like the German one. However, although they centralize policy-making on important matters, legislative parties might also take an independent stance towards their government from time to time and our results underlined that MPs are quite capable of shaping the party line on some issues (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). Fourth, our findings could be read as dissenting votes are reduced when the division of labour principle is invigorated. This carries two different implications for the major theoretical debate on representation. On the one hand, reducing votes against the party line mitigates an agency problem within the constitutional chain of delegation (Müller, Reference Müller2000) and strengthens promissory representation (Mansbridge, Reference Mansbridge2003), i.e., that MPs support the party on whose platform they were elected to parliament. It would also support the notion that parties increase the transparency and predictability of policy outcomes and are thus the best means of facilitating accountability between voters and their representatives (Kölln, Reference Kölln2015). On the other hand, citizens explicitly prefer constituency representation over partisan representation (Bøggild, Reference Bøggild2020), and the division of labour principle has been alleged to impair MPs’ responsiveness to their constituents (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). Their specialization on a few issues necessarily results in a lack of overview and knowledge on other issues. However, the inputs MPs receive from their constituency are not limited to their area of specialization. Since it is considered bad style to chime in when other topics are concerned (Schöne, Reference Schöne2010; Ismayr, Reference Ismayr2012), MPs’ responsiveness is restricted to ‘their’ topics. It is true that MPs can pass on concerns from the constituency to responsible committee members. However, the chances that these will be taken up are low. Therefore, the insufficient internal responsiveness of the specialized MPs to each other weakens the external responsiveness of parliament to society (von Oertzen, Reference von Oertzen2006). This problem gains additional weight in times of declining classical cleavages and partisan dealignment, because supporters and members of parties (including MPs) are increasingly less united on policy core beliefs and, at the same time, the parties’ policy specialists shield themselves from each other.

Our findings provide several avenues for future research. Because this study focused on the ‘division of labour’ path to unity, we conceptualized MPs’ connection to particular issues by their involvement in the committee and intra-party group deliberations. However, this might not be the only way in which MPs’ defection probabilities vary among issues. First, MPs might have an interest in topics not related to their committee membership, be that based on their former occupation or personal curiosity – without them joining the respective committee or despite being denied the assignment to those committees. Second, MPs might also connect to particular topics based on earlier stages of their political career, be that executive offices at the federal or subnational level, committee memberships in other parliaments or engagement in NGOs. Future studies ought to shed light on those possible advances or replicate our findings for further parliaments.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773923000152. The data that support the findings of this study are available from the author upon request.

Acknowledgements

A previous version of this article was presented at the 2022 ECPR General Conference in Innsbruck. I thank the discussants and participants as well as Reimut Zohlnhöfer and three anonymous reviewers of EPSR for their helpful comments. Further thanks to Moritz Link, Lukas Seibert and Henrik Wagner for their excellent research assistance.

Competing interest

The author(s) declare none.

Footnotes

1 Whereas committee chairs are said to hold the more prestigious office, compared to policy spokespersons, they do not exert any comparable influence on policies (Petersen and Kaina, Reference Petersen and Kaina2007). Sieberer and Höhmann (Reference Sieberer and Höhmann2017) report one of the lowest power scores for German committee chairs, compared to other Western democracies. Therefore, their office is only included in the controls instead of being equated with spokespersons.

References

Literature

Ainsley, C., Carrubba, C.J., Crisp, B.F., Demirkaya, B., Gabel, M.J. and Hadzic, D. (2020), ‘Roll-call vote selection: implications for the study of legislative politics’, American Political Science Review 114(3): 691706.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andeweg, R.B. and Thomassen, J. (2011), ‘Pathways to party unity: sanctions, loyalty, homogeneity and division of labour in the Dutch parliament’, Party Politics 17(5): 655672.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailer, S. (2018), ‘To use the whip or not: whether and when party group leaders use disciplinary measures to achieve voting unity’, International Political Science Review 39(2): 163177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baller, I. (2017), ‘Specialists, party members, or national representatives: patterns in co-sponsorship of amendments in the European Parliament’, European Union Politics 18(3): 469490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benedetto, G. and Hix, S. (2007), ‘The rejected, the ejected, and the dejected: explaining government rebels in the 2001–2005 British House of Commons’, Comparative Political Studies 40(7): 755781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergmann, H., Bailer, S., Ohmura, T., Saalfeld, T. and Sieberer, U. (2016), ‘Namentliche Abstimmungen im Bundestag 1949 bis 2013: Befunde aus einem neuen Datensatz’, Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 47(1): 2650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhattacharya, C. and Papageorgiou, A. (2019), ‘Are backbenchers fighting back? Intra-party contestation in German Parliament Debates on the Greek Crisis’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(2): 425444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bøggild, T. (2020), ‘Politicians as party hacks: party loyalty and public distrust in politicians’, The Journal of Politics 82(4): 15161529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borghetto, E., Santana-Pereira, J., and Freire, A. (2020), ‘Parliamentary questions as an instrument for geographic representation: the hard case of Portugal’, Swiss Political Science Review 26(1): 1030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowler, S., Farrell, D.M. and Katz, R.S. (1999), ‘Party cohesion, party discipline, and parliaments’, in Bowler, S. (ed.), Party Discipline and Parliamentary Government, Columbus: Ohio State University Press, pp. 322.Google Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W.R. and Golder, M. (2006), ‘Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses’, Political Analysis 14(1): 6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, I. (2015), ‘Issue emphases, saliency theory and issue ownership: a historical and conceptual analysis’, West European Politics 38(4): 761777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cann, D.M. (2008), ‘Modeling committee chair selection in the U.S. House of representatives’, Political Analysis 16(3): 274289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiru, M. (2020), ‘Loyal soldiers or seasoned leaders? The selection of committee chairs in the European Parliament’, Journal of European Public Policy 27(4): 612629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cirone, A. and van Coppenolle, B. (2018), ‘Cabinets, committees, and careers: the causal effect of committee service’, The Journal of Politics 80(3): 948963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clayton, A. and Zetterberg, P. (2021), ‘Gender and party discipline: evidence from Africa’s emerging party systems’, American Political Science Review 115(3): 869884.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Close, C. (2018), ‘Parliamentary party loyalty and party family: the missing link?’, Party Politics 24(2): 209219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Close, C., Gherghina, S. and Sierens, V. (2019), ‘Prompting legislative agreement and loyalty: what role for intra-party democracy?’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(2): 387405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, G.W. and McCubbins, M.D. (1993), Legislative Leviathan. Party Government in the House, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cross, J.P., Eising, R., Hermansson, H. and Spohr, F. (2021), ‘Business interests, public interests, and experts in parliamentary committees: their impact on legislative amendments in the German Bundestag’, West European Politics 44(2): 354377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Degner, H. and Leuffen, D. (2016), ‘Keynes, Friedman, or Monnet? Explaining parliamentary voting behaviour on fiscal aid for euro area member states’, West European Politics 39(6): 11391159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delius, M.F., Koß, M. and Stecker, C. (2013), ‘“Ich erkenne also Fraktionsdisziplin grundsätzlich auch an…” Innerfraktioneller Dissens in der SPD-Fraktion der Großen Koalition 2005 bis 2009’, Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 44(3): 546566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dingler, S.C. and Ramstetter, L. (2021), ‘When does she rebel? How gender affects deviating legislative behaviour’, Government and Opposition. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.40.Google Scholar
Duell, D., Kaftan, L., Proksch, S.-O., Slapin, J. and Wratil, C. (2023). ‘Communicating the rift: voter perceptions of intraparty dissent in parliaments’, The Journal of Politics 85(1): 7691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandes, J.M., Goplerud, M. and Won, M. (2019), ‘Legislative bellwethers: the role of committee membership in parliamentary debate’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 44(2): 307343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandes, J.M., Saalfeld, T. and Schwemmer, C. (2022), ‘The politics of select committee assignments in the British House of Commons’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 47(2): 329360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Font, N. (2020), ‘Competing principals and non-vote decisions in the European Parliament’, Parliamentary Affairs 73(1): 166185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortunato, D. (2019), ‘Legislative review and party differentiation in coalition governments’, American Political Science Review 113(1): 242247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frech, E. (2016), ‘Re-electing MEPs: the factors determining re-election probabilities’, European Union Politics 17(1): 6990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fujimura, N. (2012), ‘Electoral incentives, party discipline, and legislative organization: manipulating legislative committees to win elections and maintain party unity’, European Political Science Review 4(2): 147175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gherghina, S. and Chiru, M. (2014), ‘Determinants of legislative voting loyalty under different electoral systems: evidence from Romania’, International Political Science Review 35(5): 523541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J. and Jennings, W. (2019), ‘Party reputations and policy priorities: how issue ownership shapes executive and legislative agendas’, British Journal of Political Science 49(2): 443466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, Z.D. and Haber, M. (2015), ‘The consequences of appearing divided: an analysis of party evaluations and vote choice’, Electoral Studies 37: 1527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grimmer, J. and Powell, E.N. (2013), ‘Congressmen in exile: the politics and consequences of involuntary committee removal’, The Journal of Politics 75(4): 907920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heuwieser, R.J. (2018), ‘Submissive lobby fodder or assertive political actors? Party loyalty of career politicians in the UK House of Commons, 2005–15’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 43(2): 305341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, D.A. (1977), ‘Political parties and macroeconomic policy’, American Political Science Review 71(4): 14671487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ismayr, W. (2012), Der Deutsche Bundestag, Wiesbaden: Springer VS.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, C. and Seeberg, H.B. (2015), ‘The Power of talk and the welfare state: evidence from 23 countries on an asymmetric opposition-government response mechanism’, Socio-Economic Review 13(2): 215233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanthak, K. (2009), ‘U. S. State legislative committee assignments and encouragement of party loyalty: an exploratory analysis’, State Politics & Policy Quarterly 9(3): 284303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kernecker, T. (2017), ‘Ambition as a micro-foundation of party loyalty’, Party Politics 23(5): 538548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, D.-H. and Loewenberg, G. (2005), ‘The role of parliamentary committees in coalition governments: keeping tabs on coalition partners in the German Bundestag’, Comparative Political Studies 38(9): 11041129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kölln, A.-K. (2015), ‘The value of political parties to representative democracy’, European Political Science Review 7(4): 593613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehmann, P., Burst, T., Matthieß, T., Regel, S., Volkens, A., Weßels, B. and Zehnter, L. (2022), The Manifesto Data Collection. Manifesto Project (MRG/CMP/MARPOR). Version 2022a. Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (WZB). https://doi.org/10.25522/manifesto.mpds.2022a.Google Scholar
Lehrer, R., Stöckle, P. and Juhl, S. (2022), ‘Assessing the relative influence of party unity on vote choice: evidence from a conjoint experiment’, Political Science Research and Methods. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2022.45.Google Scholar
Leighton, W.A. and López, E.J. (2002), ‘Committee assignments and the cost of party loyalty’, Political Research Quarterly 55(1): 5990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lord, C. (2018), ‘The European Parliament: a working parliament without a public?’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 24(1): 3450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Louwerse, T. and Otjes, S. (2016), ‘Personalised parliamentary behaviour without electoral incentives: the case of the Netherlands’, West European Politics 39(4): 778799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mai, P. (2022), ‘Whose bread I don’t eat, his song I don’t sing? MPs’ outside earnings and dissenting voting behaviour’, Party Politics 28(2): 342353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mai, P., Link, M. and Engler, F. (2023), ‘Voting behaviour in the 19th German Bundestag and beyond: between the daily business of unity and a special vote of conscience’, German Politics. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644008.2023.2191317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mai, P. and Wenzelburger, G. (2023), ‘Loyal activists? Party socialization and dissenting voting behavior in parliament’, Legislative Studies Quarterly. https://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansbridge, J. (2003), ‘Rethinking representation’, American Political Science Review, 97(4): 515528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, S. and Mickler, T.A. (2019), ‘Committee assignments: theories, causes and consequences’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(1): 7798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meserve, S.A., Pemstein, D. and Bernhard, W.T. (2009), ‘Political ambition and legislative behavior in the European Parliament’, The Journal of Politics 71(3): 10151032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, T.M. and Wagner, M. (2021), ‘Issue engagement across members of parliament: the role of issue specialization and party leadership’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 46(3): 653678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mickler, T.A. (2018), ‘Who gets what and why? Committee assignments in the German Bundestag’, West European Politics 41(2): 517539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mickler, T.A. (2019), ‘What happens after assignments? The room for manoeuvre of committee members in the Bundestag and the Tweede Kamer’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(2): 445463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, W.C. (2000), ‘Political parties in parliamentary democracies: making delegation and accountability work’, European Journal of Political Research 37(3): 309333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, P. (2019), ‘Post-legislative scrutiny in the UK Parliament: adding value’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 25(3): 340357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ohmura, T. (2014), ‘When your name is on the list, it is time to party: the candidacy divide in a mixed-member proportional system’, Representation 50(1): 6982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ohmura, T. and Willumsen, D.M. (2022), ‘Free votes and the analysis of recorded votes: evidence from Germany (1949–2021)’, West European Politics. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2022.2114651.Google Scholar
Owens, J.E. (2003), ‘Explaining party cohesion and discipline in democratic legislatures: purposiveness and contexts’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 9(4): 1240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papp, Z. and Russo, F. (2018), ‘Parliamentary work, re-section and re-election: in search of the accountability link’, Parliamentary Affairs 71(4): 853867.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petersen, A.S. and Kaina, V. (2007), ‘“Die Fäden habe ich in der Hand”: Arbeitsgruppenvorsitzende der SPD- und CDU/CSU-Bundestagsfraktionen’, Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 38(2): 243260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rahat, G. (2007), ‘Determinants of party cohesion: evidence from the case of the Israeli parliament’, Parliamentary Affairs 60(2): 279296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rehmert, J. (2020), ‘Candidacy eligibility criteria and party unity’, Comparative Political Studies 53(8): 12981325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rehmert, J. (2022), ‘Party membership, pre-parliamentary socialization and party cohesion’, Party Politics 28(6): 10811093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saalfeld, T. (1995), Parteisoldaten und Rebellen. Eine Untersuchung zur Geschlossenheit der Fraktionen im Deutschen Bundestag (1949–1990). Opladen: Leske+Budrich.Google Scholar
Schindler, D. (2019), Politische Führung in Fraktionenparlament. Rolle und Steuerungsmöglichkeiten der Fraktionsvorsitzenden im Deutschen Bundestag, Baden-Baden: Nomos.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmuck, D. and Hohendorf, L. (2022), ‘Loyal lists, distinctive districts: how dissent-shirking and leisure-shirking affect mixed-candidate selection’, West European Politics. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2022.2137310.Google Scholar
Schobess, R. and de Vet, B. (2022), ‘The good, the loyal or the active? MPs’ parliamentary performance and the achievement of static and progressive career ambitions in parliament’, European Political Science Review 14(4): 600617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schöne, H. (2010), Alltag im Parlament. Parlamentskultur in Theorie und Empirie, Baden-Baden: Nomos.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Searing, D.D. (1995), ‘The psychology of political authority: a causal mechanism of political learning through persuasion and manipulation’, Political Psychology 16(4): 677696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sieberer, U. (2010), ‘Behavioral consequences of mixed electoral systems: deviating voting behavior of district and list MPs in the German Bundestag’, Electoral Studies 29(3): 484496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sieberer, U. and Höhmann, D. (2017), ‘Shadow chairs as monitoring device? A comparative analysis of committee chair powers in Western European parliaments’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 23(3): 301325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sieberer, U. and Ohmura, T. (2021), ‘Mandate type, electoral safety, and defections from the party line: the conditional mandate divide in the German Bundestag, 1949–2013’, Party Politics 27(4): 704715.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sieberer, U. and Müller, W.C. (2017), ‘Aiming higher: the consequences of progressive ambition among MPs in European parliaments’, European Political Science Review 9(1): 2750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siefken, S.T. (2018), Parlamentarische Kontrolle im Wandel: Theorie und Praxis des Deutschen Bundestages, Baden-Baden: Nomos.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siefken, S.T. (2021), ‘No paradise of policy-making. The role of parliamentary committees in the German Bundestag’, in Siefken, S.T. and Rommetvedt, H. (eds.), Parliamentary Committees in the Policy Process, London: Routledge, pp. 116136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skjæveland, A. (2001), ‘Party cohesion in the Danish parliament’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 7(2): 3556.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sozzi, F. (2023), ‘Rebels in parliament: the effects of candidate selection methods on legislative behaviours’, Parliamentary Affairs 76(2): 341359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stecker, C. (2015), ‘How effects on party unity vary across votes’, Party Politics 21(5): 791802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steffani, W. (1979), Parlamentarische und präsidentielle Demokratie. Strukturelle Aspekte westlicher Demokratien, Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiller, Y. (2023), ‘Why do legislators rebel on trade agreements? The effect of constituencies’ economic interests’, European Political Science Review 15(2): 272290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K. (1990), Minority Governments and Majority Rule, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tavits, M. (2009), ‘The making of mavericks: local loyalties and party defection’, Comparative Political Studies 42(6): 793815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavits, M. (2012), ‘Party organizational strength and party unity in post-communist Europe’, European Political Science Review 4(3): 409431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Traber, D., Hug, S. and Sciarini, P. (2014), ‘Party unity in the Swiss parliament: the electoral connection’, The Journal of Legislative Studies 20(2): 193215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Vonno, C.M.C. (2016), Achieving Party Unity. A Sequential Approach to Why MPs Act in Concert, Leiden: Leiden University Repository.Google Scholar
van Vonno, C.M.C. (2019), ‘Achieving party unity in the Netherlands: representatives’ sequential decision-making mechanisms at three levels of Dutch government’, Party Politics 25(5): 664678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Oertzen, J. (2006), Das Expertenparlament. Abgeordnetenrollen in den Fachstrukturen bundesdeutscher Parlamente, Baden-Baden: Nomos.Google Scholar
Wagner, M. and Meyer, T.M. (2014), ‘Which issues do parties emphasise? Salience strategies and party organisation in multiparty systems’, West European Politics 37(5): 10191045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagner, M., Glinitzer, K. and Vivyan, N. (2020), ‘Costly signals: voter responses to parliamentary dissent in Austria, Britain, and Germany’, Legislative Studies Quarterly 45(4): 645678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wenzelburger, G. and Zohlnhöfer, R. (2021), ‘Bringing agency back into the study of partisan politics: a note on recent developments in the literature on party politics’, Party Politics 27(5): 10551065.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitaker, R. (2019), ‘A case of ‘You can always get what you want’? Committee assignments in the European Parliament’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(1): 162181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willumsen, D.M. (2022), ‘Policy preferences, unity, and floor dissent in the European Parliament’, Journal of European Public Policy. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2022.2107047.Google Scholar
Willumsen, D.M. and Goetz, K.H. (2017), ‘Set free? Impending retirement and legislative behaviour in the UK’, Parliamentary Affairs 70(2): 254279.Google Scholar
Willumsen, D.M. and Öhberg, P. (2017), ‘Toe the line, break the whip: explaining floor dissent in parliamentary democracies’, West European Politics 40(4): 688716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yordanova, N. and Mühlböck, M. (2015), ‘Tracing the selection bias in roll call votes: party group cohesion in the European Parliament’, European Political Science Review 7(3): 373399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zittel, T. and Nyhuis, D. (2019), ‘Two faces of party unity: roll-call behavior and vote explanations in the German Bundestag’, Parliamentary Affairs 72(2): 406424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zittel, T. and Nyhuis, D. (2021), ‘The legislative effects of campaign personalization. An analysis on the legislative behavior of successful German constituency candidates’, Comparative Political Studies 54(2): 312338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zubek, R. (2021), ‘Committee strength in parliamentary democracies: a new index’, European Journal of Political Research 60(4): 10181031.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Results of the logistic regression analysis

Figure 1

Figure 1. Predicted probabilities for the conditional effect of policy spokespersons (model 3).

Figure 2

Figure 2. Predicted probabilities for the conditional effect of vote type (model 4).

Figure 3

Figure 3. Effect of committee membership, conditioned by issue salience (model 5).

Supplementary material: File

Mai supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Mai supplementary material(File)
File 93.4 KB