Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-08T02:26:48.917Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Popular sovereignty, State autonomy, and private property

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2009

Get access

Extract

The legitimacy of modern democratic institutions rests on the ideal of popular sovereignty. The purpose of this paper is to examine the contemporary status of this ideal.

Since space limitations do not permit discussion that would place the concept of popular sovereignty in its historical and intellectual context, we simply postulate a definition. People, by whom we mean individuals acting on the bases of their current preferences, are collectively sovereign if the alternatives open to them as a collectivity are constrained only by conditions independent of anyone's will. Specifically, people are sovereign to the extent that they can alter the existing institutions, including the state and property, and if they can allocate available resources to all feasible uses.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Archives Européenes de Sociology 1986

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alessi, Louis de, 1969. Implication of property rights for government investment choices, American Economic Review, 591, xx–xx.Google Scholar
Almon, Copper and Barabera, Anthony J., 1980. Investment in producer durable equipment 1976–1990, in Furstenberg, George Van (ed.), Capital Efficiency and Growth (Cambridge, Ma., Ballinger).Google Scholar
Alt, James and Chrystal, K. Alec, 1983. Political Economics (Berkeley, University of California Press).Google Scholar
Ames, Edward and Rapp, Richard T., 1977. The birth and death of taxes: a hypothesis, Journal of Economic History, 37: 161178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Perry, 1977. The antinomies of Antonio Gramsci, New Left Review, 100: 578.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth A., 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values (New York, Wiley; revised edition, 1963).Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth A. 1971. Political and economic evaluation of social effects and externalities, in Intriligator, M. D. (ed.), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics (Amsterdam, North-Holland).Google Scholar
Auerbach, Alan J., 1982. Tax neutrality and the social discount rate, Journal of Public Economics, 17: 355372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, Alan J. 1983. Taxation, corporate financial policy and the cost of capital, Journal of Economic Literature, 21: 905940.Google Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. and Kurz, Mordecai, 1977. Power and taxes, Econometrica, 45: 11371161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bator, Francis M., 1958. The anatomy of market failure, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 457476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, 1978. Social choice and economic growth, Public Choice, 3348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S., 1958. Competition and democracy, Journal of Law and Economics, 1: 105109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1983. A theory of competition among pressure groups of political influence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 48: 371400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, Jagdish N., 1980. Lobbying and welfare, Journal of Public Economics, 14: 355356. With a Comment by Gordon Tullock (1981), 16: 391–394, and a Response (1982) 19: 395–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birnbaum, Pierre, 1985. L'action de l'État, in Leca, Jean (ed.), Traité de science politique (Paris, Presses Universitaires de France), tome III.Google Scholar
Bischoff, Charles W., 1971. Business investment in the 1970s: a comparison of models, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 1363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Block, Fred, 1977. The ruling class does not rule: notes on the Marxist theory of the state, Socialist Revolution, 33: 627.Google Scholar
Broadway, Robin and Bruce, Neil, 1984. A general proposition on the design of a neutral business tax, Journal of Public Economics, 24: 231239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bobbio, Norberto, 1984. Il Futuro della Democrazia (Torino, Einaudi).Google Scholar
Borooah, V.K. and der Ploeg, Frederic Van, 1983. Political Aspects of the Economy (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Bowen, H.R., 1943. The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58: 2748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert, 1984. The Mosaic of Domination and the Future of Democracy (forthcoming).Google Scholar
Bracewell-Milnes, Barry, 1980. The Economics of International Tax Avoidance (Boston, Kluwer).Google Scholar
Breton, Albert and Wintrobe, Ronald, 1975. The equilibrium size of a budgetmaximizing bureau. A note on Niskanen's theory of bureaucracy, Journal of Political Economy, 83: 195207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D. and Tullock, Gordon (eds), 1980. Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station, Texas A & M University Press).Google Scholar
Burke, Edmund, 1984. Thoughts and details on scarcity, in Butler, Marilyn (ed.); Burke, Pain, Godwin, and the Revolution Controversy (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Bush, Winston C., and Mackay, Robert J., 1977. Private versus public sector growth: a collective choice approach, in Borchercing, Thomas E. (ed.), Budgets and Bureaucrats (Durham, Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Cameron, David, 1984. Social democracy, corporatism, and labor quiescence. The representation of economic interest in advanced capitalist society, in Goldthorpe, J.H. (ed.), Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism (Oxford, Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Castles, Francis G. (ed.), 1982. The Impact of Parties: politics and policy in democratic capitalist states (Beverly Hills, Sage).Google Scholar
Cawson, Alan and Ballard, John, 1984. A Bibliography- of Corporatism (Florence, European University Institute, Working Paper n° 84/115).Google Scholar
Coase, R.H., 1960. The problem of social cost, The Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Jules, 1982 a. The normative basis of economic analysis: a critical review of Richard Posner's The Economics of Justice, Stanford Law Review, 34: 11041131.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules 1982 b. The economic analysis of law, in Pennock, Roland and Chapman, John (eds), Ethics, Economics and the Law (New York, New York University Press).Google Scholar
Davis, Lance E., 1980. It's a long, long road to Tipperary, or Reflections on organized violence, protection rates, and related topics: the new political history, Journal of Economic History, 60: 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash and Grossman, Gene, 1984. Directly unproductive prophet-seeking activities, American Economic Review, 74: 10871089.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony, 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York, Harper and Row).Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John A., 1974. Pork Barrel Politics (Stanford, Stanford University Press).Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris, 1977. Congress: Keystone of the Washington Establishment (New Haven, Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris and Noll, R.G., 1978. Voters, bureaucrats, and legislators: a rational choice perspective on the growth of bureaucracy, Journal of Public Economics, 9: 239253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foley, Duncan, 1967. Resource allocation and the public sector, Yale Economic Essays, 7: 4598.Google Scholar
Frey, B.S., 1978. Modern Political Economy (New York, Wiley).Google Scholar
Frey, B.S. and Schneider, F., 1982. Politico-economic models in competition with alternative models: which predict better? European Journal of Political Research, 10: 240254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furubotn, Eirik G. and Peiovich, Svetozar, 1972. Property rights and economic theory: a survey of literature, Journal of Economic Literature, 10: 11371161.Google Scholar
Habernas, Jurgen, 1975. Legitimation Crisis (Boston, Beacon Press), p. 329.Google Scholar
Hamada, K., 1973. A simple majority rule on the distribution of income, Journal of Economic Theory, 6: 243264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C., 1954. Monopoly and resource allocation, American Economic Review, 44: 7787.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1971. Three basic postulates for applied welfare economics: an interpretative essay, Journal of Economic Literature, 9: 785797Google Scholar
Hendershott, Parick H. and Shengcheng, Hu, 1981. Investment in producer's equipment, in Aron, Henry J. and Pechman, Joseph A. (eds), How Taxes Affect Economic Behavior (Washington, D.C., Brookings).Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. Jr, 1977. Political parties and macroeconomic policy, American Political Science Review, 71: 14671487.Google Scholar
Hibbs, D.A. and Fassbender, Hans (eds), 1981. Contemporary Political Economy (Amsterdam, North-Holland).Google Scholar
Jorgenson, Dale W., 1967. The theory of investment behavior, in Ferber, Robert (ed.), Determinants of Investment Behavior (New York, N.B.E.R.).Google Scholar
Katz, Claudio J., Mahler, Vincent A. and Franz, Michael G., 1983. The impact of taxes on growth and distribution in developed capitalist countries: a cross-national study, American Political Science Review, 77: 871887).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keghane, Nannerl O., 1980. Philosophy and the State in France (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
King, Mervyn A. and Fullerton, Don, 1984. The Taxation of Income from Capital. A comparative study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden, and West Germany (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleiman, Ephraim, 1983. Fear of confiscation and redistribution. Unpublished paper (Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm).Google Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe, 1977. La transition socialiste (Paris, Cerf).Google Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. and Snyder, James M., 1983. Fairness, self-interest, and the politics of the progressive income tax. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting Political Science Association, Chicago.Google Scholar
Krashner, Stephen D., 1978. Defending the National Interest: raw materials investments and U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Krueger, Anne O., 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society, American Economic Review, 64: 291303.Google Scholar
Lane, Frederic C., 1979. Neo-corpoiatism and the function of representative institutions. Paper presented at the Conference on Representation and the State, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret, 1981. The predatory theory of rule, Politics and Society, X: 431465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, Charles E., 1977. Politics and Markets. The world's political-economic systems (New York, Basic Books).Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert R., 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique, in Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan (eds), The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets (Amsterdam, North-Holland).Google Scholar
Luxemburg, Rosa, 1970. Reform or Revolution (New York, Pathfinder Press).Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., 1976. Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control, Journal of Economic Theory, 12: 472482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maravall, José M., 1979. The limits of reformism: parliamentary socialism and the Marxist theory of the state, British Journal of Sociology, 30: 267287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meltzer, Allan and Richard, Scott F., 1981. A rational theory of the size of government, Journal of Political Economy, 89: 914927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Migué, Jean-Luc and Bélanger, Gérard, 1975. Toward a general theory of managerial discretion, Public Choice, 17: 2747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miliband, Ralph, 1969. The State in Capitalist Society (New York, Basic Books).Google Scholar
Miller, Gary, 1977. Bureaucratic compliance as a game on a unit square, Public Choice, 29: 3752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Gary and Moe, Terry M., 1983. Bureaucrats, legislators, and the size of government, American Political Science Review, 77: 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Nicolas R., 1983. Pluralism and social choice, American Political Science Review, 77: 737747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A., 1971. Provision for social goods in the market system, Public Finance, 26: 304320.Google Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A. 1980. Theories of fiscal crises: an essay in fiscal sociology, in Aaron, Henry J. and Boskin, Michael J. (eds), The Economics of Taxation (Washington, The Brookings Institution), pp. 361391.Google Scholar
Nettl, Peter J., 1968. The state as a conceptual variable, World Politics, 29: 559592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
New York Stock Exchange, 1981. U.S. Economic Performance in a Global Perspective (New York).Google Scholar
Niskanen, William A., 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Nordlinger, Eric, 1981. On the Autonomy of the Democratic State (Cambridge, Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
North, Douglas C., 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History (New York, W.W. Norton).Google Scholar
OECD, 1983 a. Positive Adjustment Policies. Managing structural change (Paris, OECD).Google Scholar
OECD 1983 b. International Investment and the Multinational Enterprises. Investment incentives and disincentives and the international investment process (Paris, OECD).Google Scholar
OECD 1984. Tax Expenditures. A review of the issues and country practices (Paris, OECD).Google Scholar
O'Donnell, Guillermo, 1977. Apuntes para una Teoria del Estado (Buenos Aires, Cedex).Google Scholar
Offe, Claus, 1975. The capitalist state and the problem of policy formulation, in Lindberg, Leon (ed.), Stress and Contradiction in Contemporary Capitalism (Lexington, Lexington Books).Google Scholar
Offe, Claus and Runge, Volker, 1984. Theses on the theory of the state, in Offe, Claus, Contradictions of the Welfare State, edited by John Keane (London, Hutchinson).Google Scholar
Okun, Arthur M., 1975. Equality and Efficiency: the big tradeoff (Washington, D.C., Brookings Institution).Google Scholar
Orzechowski, William, 1977. Economic models of bureaucracy: survey, extensions, and evidence, in Borcherding, T.E. (ed.), Budgets and Bureaucrats: the sources of government growth (Durham, Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Panitch, Leo, 1980. Recent theorizations of corporatism: reflections on a growth industry, British Journal of Sociology, 159187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parkinson, C. Northcote, 1957. Parkinson's Law and Other Studies in Administration (New York, Ballantine Books).Google Scholar
Pashukanis, Eugene, 1951. General theory of law and Marxism, in Soviet Legal Philosophy by V.I. Lenin et al. Translated by Rabb, Hugh W., with an Introduction by John N. Hazard (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam, 1976. Toward a more general theory. of regulation. With Comments by Hirsleifer, Jack and Becker, Gary, Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 211240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam 1980. The growth of government, Journal of Law and Economics, 22: 209289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poggi, Gianfranco, 1978. The Development of the Modern State. A sociological introduction (Stanford, Stanford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A., 1974. Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5: 335358.Google Scholar
Poulantzas, Nicos, 1973. Political Power and Social Classes (London, New Left Books).Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, 1985. Capitalism and Social Democracy (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael, 1982. The structure of class conflict in democratic capitalist societies, American Political Science Review, 76: 215236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael 1985. A comment on Katz, Mahler, and Franz, American Political Science Review, 80.Google Scholar
Rae, Douglas W., 1971. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws2 (New Haven, Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Riker, William H., 1982. Liberalism against Populism: a confrontation between the theory of democracy and the theory of social choice (San Francisco, W.H. Freeman).Google Scholar
Roberts, Kevin W.S., 1977. Voting over income tax schedules, Journal of Public Economics, 8: 329340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roemer, John E., 1982. A General Theory of Exploitation and Class (Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roemer, John E. 1984. Public ownership and the private property externalities (Department of Economics, University of California, Davis, Working Paper n° 252).Google Scholar
Romer, T. 1975. Individual welfare, majority voting, and the properties of a linear income tax, Journal of Public Economics, 4: 163185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, Thomas and Rosenthal, Howard, 1979. The elusive median voter, Journal of Public Economics, 12: 143170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., 1966. The pure theory of public expenditure, in Stieglitz, Joseph E. (ed.), The Collective Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson (Cambridge, Mass.MIT Press).Google Scholar
Saunders, Peter and Klau, Friedrich, 1985. The Role of the Public Sector. Causes and consequences of the growth of government (OECD Economic Studies, Special Issue: 4).Google Scholar
Schmidt, Manfred G., 1982. Does corporatism matter? Economic crisis, politics and rates of unemployment in capitalist democracies in the 1970s, in Lehmbruch, G. and Schmitter, P.C. (eds), Patterns of Corporatism Policy-Making (London, Sage Publications).Google Scholar
Sohmitter, , Philippe, C., 1974. Still the century of corporatism? in Pike, Frederick and Stritch, Thomas (eds), The New Corporatism (Notre Dame, University of Notre Dame Press).Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman, 1978. Instability of simple dynamic games, Review of Economic Studies, 45: 575594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schofield, Norman 1982. Instability and development in the political economy, in Ordershook, E.A. and Shepsle, K.A. (eds), Political Equilibrium (Boston, Kluwer-Nijhoff).Google Scholar
Schott, Kerry, 1984. Policy, Power and Order. The persistence of economic problems in capitalist states (New Haven, Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (New York, Harper).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. The crisis of the tax state, International Economic Papers, 4: 151.Google Scholar
Shalev, Michael, 1983. The social democratic model and beyond: two generations of comparative research on the welfare state, Comparative Social Research, 6 (Greenwich, JAI Press).Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., 1979 a. The Private Use of the Public Interest (Center for the Study of American Business, Washington University, St. Louis, Working Paper n° 46).Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979 b. Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models, American Journal of Political Science, 23: 2459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R., 1981. Political preferences for the pork barrel: a generalization, American Journal of Political Science, 25: 96111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R., 1984. Political solutions to market problems, American Political Science Review, 78: 417434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silberberg, Eugene, 1978. The Structure of Economics. A mathematical analysis (New York, McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda, 1985. Bringing the state back in: false leads and promising starts in current theories and research, in Evans, Peter, Skocpol, Theda and Rueschemeyer, Dietrich (eds), Bringing the State Back In (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Stepan, Alfred, 1978. The State and Society: Peru in comparative perspective (Princeton, Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Stigler, George, 1975. The Citizen and the State. Essays on regulation (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Thurow, Lester, 1971. The income distribution as a pure public good, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85: 327336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles, 1985. Warmaking and statemaking as organized crime, in Evans Skocpol and Rueschemeyer, (eds), op. cit.Google Scholar