Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T10:06:11.409Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Origination and Distribution of Debt: Risks and Regulatory Solutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Abstract

This article focuses on misaligned incentives in the lending process caused by the shift from the traditional relationship banking model to a more transaction-oriented ‘originateto-distribute’ model of bank finance as one of the major factors contributing to the financial crisis of the years 2007–2009. Based on a theoretical analysis of banks as financial intermediaries and the agency costs involved if banks distribute assets they have created to other parties in the financial system, empirical studies are reviewed which demonstrate that market mechanisms apparently contain these agency costs in loan syndications and loan sales, but failed to do so in securitisations during the years before the onset of the financial crisis. The EU has already reacted to this breakdown of market mechanisms by an amendment to the Capital Requirements Directive with the purpose of aligning incentives in securitisation transactions by getting more securitiser ‘skin in the game’. Similar legislation has been adopted in the US. This article places the EU and US response to perceived shortcomings in securitisations in the context of the theoretical and empirical literature and discusses alternative regulatory solutions.

Type
Symposium on the Financial Crisis in the EU (Part 1)
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Diamond, Douglas W. and Rajan, Raghuram G., “The Credit Crisis: Conjectures about Causes and Remedies”, 99 American Economic Review (2009), pp. 606 et sqq., at p. 606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report. Market Developments and Issues (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, April 2006), at pp. 51 et sqq.Google Scholar

3 Cp. International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report. April 2006, supra note 2, at p. 71 and International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report. Navigating the Financial Challenges Ahead (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, October 2009), at pp. 77, 85 et sqq.Google Scholar

4 Cf. The High-Level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU, Chaired by Jacques de Larosière, Report (Brussels: European Commission, 25 February 2009), at para. 17; The Financial Services Authority, The Turner Review. A Regulatory Response to the Global Banking Crisis (London: The Financial Services Authority, March 2009), at p. 42 Google Scholar; Financial Stability Forum, Report of the Financial Stability Forum on Enhancing Market and Institutional Resilience (Basel: Financial Stability Forum, 7 April 2008), at pp. 5 et sqq.Google Scholar; Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions, Report on the Subprime Crisis. Final Report (Madrid: International Organization of Securities Commissions, May 2008), at pp. 6 et sqq.Google Scholar

5 See, for example, The High-Level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU, supra note 4, paras. 117 et sqq.

6 See on financial intermediation in general, e.g., Gorton, Gary and Winton, Andrew, “Financial Intermediation”, in Constantinides, George M., Harris, Milton and Schulz, René M. (eds), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Volume 1A, Corporate Finance (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2003), pp. 431 et sqq., at pp. 432–435Google Scholar and Boyd, John H., ‘financial intermediation’, in Durlauf, Steven N. and Blume, Lawrence E. (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008).Google Scholar

7 Cf. in particular Leland, Hayne E. and Pyle, David H., “Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation”, 32 Journal of Finance (1977), pp. 371 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Diamond, Douglas W., “Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring”, 51 Review of Economic Studies (1984), pp. 393 et sqq CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See for a comprehensive survey of the information-based literature on financial intermediation Bhattacharya, Sudipto and Thakor, Anjan V., “Contemporary Banking Theory”, 3 Journal of Financial Intermediation (1993), pp. 2 et sqq., at pp. 7–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 Leland/Pyle, supra note 7.

9 Diamond, supra note 7.

10 Diamond, supra note 7, at p. 393.

11 Leland/Pyle, supra note 7, at p. 383.

12 Diamond, supra note 7.

13 Berger, Allen N. and Udell, Gregory F., “Securitization, Risk, and the Liquidity Problem in Banking”, in Klausner, Michael and White, Lawrence J. (eds), Structural Change in Banking (New York: New York University Salomon Center, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, 1993), pp. 227 et sqq., at p. 232.Google Scholar

14 Allen, Franklin and Santomero, Anthony M., “The Theory of Financial Intermediation”, 21 Journal of Banking & Finance (1998), pp. 1461 et sqq., especially at p. 1473CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Scholtens, Bert and van Wensveen, Dick, “A Critique on the Theory of Financial Intermediation”, 24 Journal of Banking & Finance (2000), pp. 1243 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Cf. Keys, Benjamin J., Mukherjee, Tanmoy, Seru, Amit and Vig, Vikrant, “Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from Subprime Loans”, 125 Quarterly Journal of Economics (2010), pp. 307 et sqq., at p. 308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 See for an introduction to agency problems Reichelstein, Stefan, ‘agency’, in Newman, Peter, Milgate, Murray and Eatwell, John (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money & Finance, Volume 1 (New York: Stockton Press, 1992), pp. 23 et sqq.Google Scholar

17 Diamond, supra note 7, at p. 410; Gorton, Gary B. and Pennacchi, George G., “Banks and Loan Sales: Marketing Nonmarketable Assets”, 35 Journal of Monetary Economics (1995), pp. 389 et sqq., at p. 390CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Holmstrom, Bengt and Tirole, Jean, “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector”, 112 Quarterly Journal of Economics (1997), pp. 664 et sqq., at p. 669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18 See on the notion of illiquidity of bank loans Diamond, Douglas W. and Rajan, Raghuram G., “Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking”, 109 Journal of Political Economy (2001), pp. 287 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar, especially at pp. 288, 322 and on the trade-off between liquidity and control in equity securities markets Coffee, John C., “Liquidity Versus Control: The Institutional Investor as Corporate Monitor”, 91 Columbia Law Review (1991), pp. 1277 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bhide, Amar, “The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity”, 34 Journal of Financial Economics (1993), pp. 31 et sqq CrossRefGoogle Scholar. and Maug, Ernst, “Large Shareholders as Monitors: Is There a Trade-Off between Liquidity and Control?”, 53 Journal of Finance (1998), pp. 65 et sqq CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

19 Diamond, supra note 7, at p. 410.

20 See for an extensive list of reasons for loan transfers Wood, Philip R., International Loans, Bonds, Guarantees, Legal Opinions, The Law and Practice of International Finance Series, Volume 3, 2nd ed. (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2007)Google Scholar, at para. 9-002.

21 Pennacchi, George G., “Loan Sales and the Cost of Capital”, 43 Journal of Finance (1988), pp. 375 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Berger/Udell, supra note 13, at p. 229. See on the regulatory capital advantage of securitisation Benjamin, Joanna, Financial Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008), at para. 18.07Google ScholarPubMed; Wood, Philip R., “Project Finance, Securitisations, Subordinated Debt”, The Law and Practice of International Finance Series, Volume 5, 2nd ed. (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2007)Google Scholar, at para. 6-013.

22 Simons, Katerina, “Why Do Banks Syndicate Loans?”, New England Economic Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (1993), pp. 45 et sqq., at p. 46Google Scholar; Dennis, Steven A. and Mullineaux, Donald J., “Syndicated Loans”, 9 Journal of Financial Intermediation (2000), pp. 404 et sqq., at p. 408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 Simons, supra note 22, at p. 47.

24 See for a descriptive account of loan syndication, e.g., Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at paras. 1-003 et sqq.

25 See on the misrepresentation liability of lead arrangers Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at paras. 1-020 et sqq.

26 Simons, supra note 22, at pp. 46 et sqq.; Dennis/Mullineaux, supra note 22, at p. 409.

27 Simons, supra note 22, at pp. 51 et sqq.; Dennis/Mullineaux, supra note 22, at pp. 417 et sqq.; Kamphol Panyagometh and Gordon S. Roberts, “Agency Problems and Determinants of Loan Syndications: Evidence from 1987–1999”, 25 April 2002, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=310003> (last accessed on 25 July 2011); Jones, Jonathan D., Lang, William W. and Nigro, Peter J., “Agent Bank Behavior in Bank Loan Syndications”, 28 Journal of Financial Research (2005), pp. 385 et sqq., at pp. 399 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sufi, Amir, “Information Asymmetry and Financing Arrangements: Evidence from Syndicated Loans”, 62 Journal of Finance (2007), pp. 629 et sqq., at pp. 646 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ball, Ryan, Bushman, Robert M. and Vasvari, Florin P., “The Debt-Contracting Value of Accounting Information and Loan Syndicate Structure”, 46 Journal of Accounting Research (2008), pp. 247 et sqq., at pp. 264 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kamphol Panyagometh and Gordon S. Roberts, “Loan Syndicate Structure: Evidence from Ex Post Risk”, 14 January 2008, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1083707> (last accessed on 25 July 2011).

28 Lee, Sang Whi and Mullineaux, Donald J., “Monitoring, Financial Distress, and the Structure of Commercial Lending Syndicates”, 33 Financial Management (2004), pp. 107 et sqq., at pp. 118 et sqq.Google Scholar; Sufi, supra note 27, at pp. 646 et sqq.

29 Sufi, supra note 30, at pp. 658 et sqq.

30 François, Pascal and Missonier-Pieral, Franck, “The Agency Structure of Loan Syndicates”, 42 Financial Review (2007), pp. 227 et sqq., at p. 230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

31 Dennis/Mullineaux, supra note 22, at pp. 420 et sqq.; Panyagometh/Roberts, “Agency Problems and Determinants of Loan Syndications”, supra note 27; Lee/Mullineaux, supra note 28, at p. 121; Sufi, supra note 27, at pp. 650 et sqq.; Ball/Bushman/Vasvari, supra note 27, at pp. 267 et sqq.; Panyagometh/Roberts, “Loan Syndicate Structure”, supra note 27.

32 Radhakrishnan Gopalan, Vikram Nanda and Vijay Yerramilli, “Does Poor Performance Damage the Reputation of Financial Intermediaries? Evidence from the Loan Syndication Market”, Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

33 Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at para. 9-018.

34 Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at para. 9-026.

35 Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at paras. 9-038 et sqq.

36 Wood, International Loans, supra note 20, at para. 9-039.

37 Berndt, Antje and Gupta, Anurag, “Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection in the Originate-to-Distribute Model of Bank Credit”, 56 Journal of Monetary Economics (2009), at p. 727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

38 Duffee, Greg, “Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection in the Originate-to-Distribute Model of Bank Credit”, 56 Journal of Monetary Economics (2009), pp. 744 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

39 Gorton/Pennacchi, supra note 17, at pp. 408 et sqq.

40 Drucker, Steven and Puri, Manju, “On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships”, 22 Review of Financial Studies (2009), at pp. 2648 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

41 Drucker/Puri, supra note 40, at pp. 2651 et sqq.

42 Drucker/Puri, supra note 40, at p. 2640.

43 Robert M. Bushman and Regina Wittenberg-Moerman, “Does Secondary Loan Market Trading Destroy Lenders’ Incentives?”, 2 November 2009, University of Chicago Booth School of Business Working Paper No. 09-45, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1498738> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at pp. 5, 8 et sqq.

44 See for descriptions of securitisation transactions, e.g., Benjamin, supra note 21, at paras. 18.10 et sqq.; Wood, Project Finance, supra note 21, at paras. 6-001, 6-015 et sqq.

45 See on CDOs Gorton, Gary, “The Subprime Panic”, 15 European Financial Management (2009), pp. 10 et sqq., at pp. 23 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Engel, Kathleen C. and McCoy, Patricia A., “Turning a Blind Eye: Wall Street Finance of Predatory Lending”, 75 Fordham Law Review (2007), pp. 2039 et sqq.Google Scholar, at pp. 2048 et sqq.; Adam B. Ashcraft and Till Schuermann, “Understanding the Securitization of Subprime Mortgage Credit”, 11 March 2008, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 318, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1071189> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at p. 3.

47 See for descriptions of the parties involved in the securitisation of mortgage-backed loans and analyses of the various agency problems resulting from the division of the lending process Ashcraft/Schuermann, supra note 46, at pp. 5 et sqq.; Franke, Günther and Krahnen, Jan Pieter, “The Future of Securitization”, in Fuchita, Yasuyuki, Herring, Richard J. and Litan, Robert E. (eds), Prudent Lending Restored. Securitization after the Mortgage Meltdown (Tokyo/Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 2009), pp. 105 et sqq., at pp. 122 et sqq.Google Scholar; John Kiff and Paul Mills, “Money for Nothing and Checks for Free: Recent Developments in US Subprime Mortgage Markets”, 17 August 2007, IMF Working Paper No. 07/188, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1006316> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at pp. 11 et sqq.; Ingo Fender and Janet Mitchell, “The Future of Securitisation: How to Align Incentives?”, 14 September 2009, BIS Quarterly Review, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1472970> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), pp. 27 et sqq., at pp. 30 et sqq.

48 Ashcraft/Schuermann, supra note 46, at p. 5.

49 A credit score attempts to reduce a borrower's credit history to a single number indicating the borrower's probability of default by weighing various elements such as the borrower's payment history and any previous defaults of the borrower.

50 Keys/Mukherjee/Seru/Vig, supra note 15, at pp. 309, 317 et sqq.

51 Amiyatosh K. Purnanandam, “Originate-to-Distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis”, 20 May 2010, AFA 2010 Atlanta Meetings Papar, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1167786> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at p. 2.

52 Uday Rajan, Amit Seru and Vikrant Vig, “The Failure of Models that Predict Failure: Distance, Incentives and Defaults”, 2 August 2010, Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan Research Paper No. 1122, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1296982> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at p. 3; Diamond/Rajan, supra note 1, at pp. 606 et sqq.; Keys/Mukherjee/Seru/Vig, supra note 15, at pp. 309 et sqq., 318.

53 Franke/Krahnen, supra note 47, at pp. 117 et sqq.

54 Steven L. Schwarcz, “Private Ordering of Public Markets: The Rating Agency Paradox”, University of Illinois Law Review [2002], pp. 1 et sqq., at p. 12.

55 Schwarcz, supra note 54, at p. 15; Ashcraft/Schuermann, supra note 46, at pp. 10 et sqq.; Schwarcz, Steven L., “Protecting Financial Markets: Lessons from the Subprime Mortgage Meltdown”, 93 Minnesota Law Review (2008–2009), pp. 373 et sqq., at pp. 400 et sqq.Google Scholar; Eggert, Kurt, “The Great Collapse: How Securitization Caused the Subprime Meltdown”, 41 Connecticut Law Review (2009), pp. 1257 et sqq., at p. 1298.Google Scholar

56 See for example The Economist, “Securitisation: When it goes wrong…”, 20 September 2007; Frederic S. Mishkin, “Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage Meltdown”, Speech at the US Monetary Policy Forum, New York, New York, 29 February 2008, available on the Internet at <http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/mishkin20080229a.htm> (last accessed on 25 July 2011); Eggert, supra note 55, at pp. 1276 et sqq.

57 Gorton, supra note 45, at pp. 38 et sqq.; Schwarcz, Steven L., “The Future of Securitization”, 41 Connecticut Law Review (2009), pp. 1313 et sqq., at pp. 1319 et sqq.Google Scholar

58 Keys/Mukherjee/Seru/Vig, supra note 15.

59 Keys/Mukherjee/Seru/Vig, supra note 15, at pp. 310, 330 et sqq.

60 Keys/Mukherjee/Seru/Vig, supra note 15, at pp. 311, 338 et sqq. See for similar empirical findings Rajan/Seru/Vig, supra note 52, at pp. 1 et sqq., 13 et sqq.

61 Purnanandam, supra note 51.

62 Purnanandam, supra note 51, at pp. 12 et sqq.

63 Efraim Benmelech, Jennifer Dlugosz and Victoria Ivashina, “Securitization without Adverse Selection: The Case of CLOs”, 11 August 2010, AFA 2010 Atlanta Meetings Paper, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1344068> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at pp. 16 et sqq.

64 Benmelech/Dlugosz/Ivashina, supra note 53, at pp. 1 et sqq.

65 Schwarcz, Steven L., “Disclosure's Failure in the Subprime Mortgage Crisis”, Utah Law Review [2008], pp. 1109 et sqq., at pp. 1117 et sqq.Google Scholar

66 See in particular International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report October 2009, supra note 3, at pp. 78 et sqq. (Box 2.1. The Case for Restarting Securitization). See for some empirical evidence on the value creation in commercial mortgage loan securitisation, An, Xudong, Deng, Yongheng and Gabriel, Stuart A., “Value Creation through Securitization: Evidence from the CMBS Market”, 38 Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics (2009), pp. 302 et sqq.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

67 See for an overview of current regulatory proposals: International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report October 2009, supra note 3, at pp. 93 et sqq.

68 Related to the disclosure-based regulatory approach but addressing shortcomings exposed by the recent financial crisis going beyond incentive problems in the lending process is the regulation of credit rating agencies as gatekeepers in financial markets which would primarily process additional information provided pursuant to improved disclosure standards. New legislation has been recently introduced in the EU and the US marking a decisive move away from self-regulation in this area and trying to reduce conflicts of interests affecting credit rating agencies: See Regulation (EC) No. 1060/2009 on credit rating agencies, OJ 2009 L 302/1; sections 931–939H Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, P.L. No. 111–203.

69 See Financial Stability Forum, supra note 4, at pp. 30 et sqq.; Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions, Report on the Subprime Crisis, supra note 4, at pp.7 et sqq.; Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions, Unregulated Financial Markets and Product. Final Reports (Madrid: International Organization of Securities Commissions, September 2009), at paras. 60 et sqq.Google Scholar; US Department of the Treasury, Financial Regulatory Reform. A New Foundation: Rebuilding Financial Supervision and Regulation (Washington, D.C.: US Department of the Tresury, June 2009), at p. 45 Google Scholar; Treasury, HM, Reforming Financial Markets, CM 7667 (London: The Stationary Office, July 2009), at paras. 6.09 et sqq.Google Scholar

70 See the initiatives by the Securitisation Division of the Association for Financial Markets in Europe (formerly the European Securitisation Forum), available on the Internet at <http://www.afme.eu> (last accessed on 25 July 2011) which expressly include the “reduction of information asymmetries and improvement of alignment of incentives between originators, investors, and other market participants”. A joint effort of regional industry bodies exists further under the umbrella of the Global Joint Initiative to Restore Confidence in Securitization Markets which commissioned the report “Restoring Confidence in Securitization Markets” in December 2008 as an early stage of a practical, industry-led response to restore confidence in market practices. These projects seem not yet as developed as the American Securitization Forum's Project on Residential Securitization Transparency and Reporting (‘Project RESTART’), information available on the Internet at <http://www.americansecuritization.com/restart> (last accessed on 25 July 2011).

71 Franke/Krahnen, supra note 47, at p. 120; Darrell Duffie, “Innovations in Credit Risk Transfer: Implications for Financial Stability”, 1 July 2008, BIS Working Paper No. 255, available on the Internet at<http://ssrn.com/abstract=1165484> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at pp. 16 et sqq.

72 Engel/McCoy, supra note 46, at pp. 2065 et sqq.

73 Franke/Krahnen, supra note 47, at pp. 152 et sqq./157; Fender/Mitchell, supra note 47, at pp. 40, 42; US Department of the Treasury, supra note 59, at p. 45.

74 Franke/Krahnen, supra note 47, at p. 153.

75 Gorton, supra note 45, at p. 37; Schwarcz, supra note 57, at pp. 1113 et sqq.

76 International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report. Containing Systemic Risk and Restoring Financial Soundness (Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, April 2008), at p. 55 Google Scholar; Franke/Krahnen, supra note 47, at p. 146. Therefore, new legislation in the EU now requires credit rating agencies to introduce clearly differentiated rating categories for structured finance instruments using an additional symbol which distinguishes them from rating categories used for any other entities, financial instruments or financial obligations: Art. 10(3) Regulation (EC) No. 1060/2009 on credit rating agencies, OJ 2009 L 302/1. A similar proposal has been made in the US but has not yet found its way into legislation: US Department of the Treasury, supra note 59, at p. 46.

77 Schwarcz, supra note 55, at pp. 386, 399 et sqq.

78 See The High-Level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU, supra note 4, at para. 95; US Department of the Treasury, supra note 59, at p. 44; HM Treasury supra note 59, at para. 6.13 and in particular Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions, Unregulated Financial Markets and Product, supra note 59, at paras. 58 et sqq.

79 See on the main implications of this regulatory change Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer LLP, The Bank of the Future, (November 2009), available on the Internet at <http://www.freshfields.com/industries/reports/bank_of_the_future/26595.pdf> (last accessed on 25 July 2011), at pp. 68 et sqq.

80 Directive 2009/111/EC amending Directives 2006/48/EC, 2006/49/EC and 2007/64/EC as regards banks affiliated to central institutions, certain own funds items, large exposures, supervisory arrangements, and crisis management, OJ 2009 L 302/97.

81 Directive 2006/48/EC relating to the taking up and pursuit of the business of credit institutions (recast), OJ 2006 L 177/1.

82 Directive 2006/49/EC on the capital adequacy of investment firms and credit institutions (recast), OJ 2006 L 177/201.

83 Art. 122a(8) Banking Consolidation Directive (as amended).

84 Article 13 of the Commission Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on Alternative Investment Fund Managers and amending Directives 2004/39/EC and 2009/…/EC, COM(2009) 207 final.

85 Art. 122a(7) Banking Consolidation Directive (as amended).

86 Art. 122a(4) Banking Consolidation Directive (as amended).

87 Public Law No. 111-203.

88 15 USC. §78a et seqq.

89 Section 941 Dodd-Frank Act.

90 Sections 942, 943 Dodd-Frank Act.

91 Data provision used to be at pool-level: Fender/Mitchell, supra note 47, at p. 35.

92 Ingo Fender and Janet Mitchell, “Incentives and Tranche Retention in Securitization: A Screening Model”, 1 September 2009, BIS Working Paper No. 289, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1481663> (last accessed on 25 July 2011); John Kiff and Michael Kisser, “Asset Securitization and Optimal Retention”, 1 March 2010, IMF Working Paper No. 10/74, available on the Internet at <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1578672> (last accessed on 25 July 2011). See also International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report. October 2009, supra note 3, at pp. 101 et sqq. (Box 2.7. Optimal Retention Policies for Loan Securitization) and Fender/Mitchell, supra note 47, at pp. 37 et sqq.

93 The Economist, “Securitisation: Earthbound”, 25 March 2010.

94 Similarly Fender/Mitchell, supra note 47, at p. 41.